Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T15:07:00.915Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Tugan-Baranovsky as a Pioneer of Trade Cycle Analysis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Vincent Barnett
Affiliation:
CREES, Birmingham University, UK.

Extract

Mikhail Ivanovich Tugan-Baranovsky (1865–1919) has not unjustly been calle the greatest Russian economist of all time (Jasny 1972, p. 159). This neglecte the fact that he was born near Kharkov and towards the end of his life came to see the Ukraine as his homeland, but the evaluation itself is not so far from the truth. However, opinion about the precise importance of Tugan-Baranovsky work to the development of trade cycle analysis has varied widely. J. M. Keynes and A. H. Hansen were both highly respectful of Tugan's contribution. For example, in the Treatise on Money, Keynes wrote in regards to business cycle theory that he was “in strong sympathy with the school of writers … of which Tugan-Baranovski was the first and most original” (Keynes 1930, vol. 2, p. 100 In his 1951 work, Business Cycles and National Income, Hansen was enthusiastic describing Tugan as “cutting his way though the jungle to a new outlook” (Hansen 1951, p. 281). This suggests that some aspects of both British an American Keynesianism might have originated in Tugan's work, or at least bee influenced by it. W. W. Rostow was also impressed by Tugan's approach, statin that it “took business cycle analysis some distance beyond Juglar and Marx” (Rostow 1990, p. 261).

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2001

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Keynes Papers, King's College, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Robertson Papers, Trinity College, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Mitchell Papers, Columbia University Special Manuscript Collection, Columbia University, New York.Google Scholar
Rossiiskii Gosudarstvennye Istoricheskii Arkhiv, St. Petersburg.Google Scholar
Ayres, Clarence. 19341935. “Moral Confusion in Economics.” In Samuels, Warren J., ed., Institutional Economics vol. 2. Aldershot Edward Elgar, 1988.Google Scholar
Bagehot, Walter. 1873. Lombard Street. London: Kegan Paul, 1892.Google Scholar
Barnett, Vincent. 1995. “Soviet Commodity Markets During NEP.” Economic History Review XLVIII (05): 329–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, Vincent. 1996. “Trading Cycles for Change: S.A. Pervushin as an Economist of the Business Cycle.” Europe-Asia Studies 48 (09): 1007–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, Vincent. 1997. “The People's Commissariat of Supply and the People's Commissariat of Internal Trade.” In Rees, E. A., ed., Decision-Making in the Stalinist Command Economy, 1932–37. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Barnett, Vincent. 1998. Kondratiev and the Dynamics of Economic Development: Long Cycles and Industrial Growth in Historical Context. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, Vincent. 1999. “Soviet Economists in Opposition and Overseas.” In Thatcher, I. D., ed., Regime and Society in Twentieth-Century Russia. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Barnett, Vincent. 2000. “Tugan-Baranovskii's vision of an international socialist economy.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 7 (Spring): 115–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bleaney, Michael. 1976. Underconsumption Theories. London: Lawrence and Wishart.Google Scholar
Brandt, B. F. 1902. Torgovo-promyshlenny i krizis v Zapadnoi Evrop i v Rossii, part 1. St. Petersburg: Kirshbaum.Google Scholar
Bukovetskii, A. I. 1962. “'Svobodnaya nalichnost” i zolotoi zapas tsarskogo pravitel'stva v konetse XIX-nachale XX v.” In Manopolii i inostrannye kapital v Rossii. Moscow-Leningrad: AN SSSR.Google Scholar
Evans, D. M. 1859. The History of the Commercial Crisis, 1857–58 and the Stock Exchange Panic of 1859. New York: Kelley, 1969.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1933. Booms and Depressions. London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Haberler, Gottfried. 1940. Prosperity and Depression. Geneva: League of Nations.Google Scholar
Hald, E. C. 1954. Business Cycles. Cambridge, MA: Riverside Press.Google Scholar
Hansen, A. H. 1927. Business Cycle Theory. Boston: Ginn and Company.Google Scholar
Hansen, A. H. 1951. Business Cycles and National Income. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1941. The Pure Theory of Capital. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hilferding, Rudolf. 1910. Finance Capital. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1981.Google Scholar
Hull, G H. 1911. Industrial Depressions. New York: F A. Stokes and Company.Google Scholar
Hutchison, T. W. 1953. A Review of Economic Doctrines, 1870–1929. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Jasny, Naum. 1972. Soviet Economists of the Twenties. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1863. “A Serious Fall in the Value of Gold Ascertained.” In W. S. Levons, Investigations in Currency and Finance. London: Macmillan, 1884.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1866. “On the Frequent Autumnal Pressure in the Money Market, and the Action of the Bank of England.” In W. S. Levons, Investigations in Currency and Finance. London: Macmillan, 1884.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1884. Investigations in Currency and Finance. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kalecki, Michal. 1990. Collected Works of Michal Kalecki, vol. 1, edited by Osiantynski, lerzy. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1913. “How Far Are Bankers Responsible for the Alternations of Crisis and Depression?” In Moggridge, Donald, ed., The Collected Writings of J. M. Keynes, vol. XIII, part I. Cambridge: Macmillan, 1973.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1930. A Treatise on Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1934. “Poverty in Plenty: Is the Economic System Self-Adjusting?” In Moggridge, Donald, ed., The Collected Writings of J. M. Keynes, vol. XIII, part I. Cambridge: Macmillan, 1973.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1937. “Alternative Theories of the Rate of Interest.” Economic Journal XLVII: 241–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1939. “The Process of Capital Formation.” Economic Journal XLIX: 569–74.Google Scholar
Kindersley, Richard. 1962. The First Russian Revisionists. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Klein, J. L. 1997. Statistical Visions in Time: A History of Time Series Analysis, 1662–1938. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kondratiev, Nikolai. 1923. “The Life of Tugan-Baranovsky.” In Makasheva, Natalia, Samuels, Warren J. and Barnett, Vincent, eds., The Works of Nikolai D. Kondratiev, vol. 4. London: Pickering and Chatto, 1998.Google Scholar
Laidler, David. 1999. Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, W. A. 1978. Growth and Fluctuations, 1870–1913. London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Link, R. G. 1959. English Theories of Economic Fluctuations, 1815–48. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Lutz, F. A. 1938. “The Outcome of the Saving-Investment Discussion.” In Readings in Business Cycle Theory. London: Allen and Unwin, 1950.Google Scholar
Luxemburg, Rosa. 1951. The Accumulation of Capital. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Mainwaring, Lynn. 1995. “Tugan's ‘Bubble’: Underconsumption and Crises in a Marxian Model.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 19: 305–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, Alfred. 1890. Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan, 1938.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1864. Principles of Political Economy, 5th edition. New York: Appleton.Google Scholar
Minutes of Evidence taken before the Committee on Finance and Industry. 1931. London: H.M. Stationery Office.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley. 1913. Business Cycles. New York: Franklin, 1970.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley. 1927. Business Cycles: The Problem and its Setting. New York: NBER, 1954.Google Scholar
Pervushin, S. A. 1914. Teoriya krizisov M.I. Tugan-Baranovskago. Moscow.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1927. Industrial Fluctuations. London: Frank Cass, 1967.Google Scholar
Presley, J. R. 1978. Robertsonian Economics. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robertson, D. H. 1914a. “Review of Les Crises Industrielles en Angleterre.” Economic Journal XXIV: 81–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robertson, D. H. 1914b. “Some Material for a Study of Trade Fluctuations.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society LXXVII: 159–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robertson, D. H. 1915. A Study of Industrial Fluctuation. London: King and Son.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. H. 1926. Banking Policy and the Price Level. London: King and Son.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. H. 1940. “Mr Keynes and the Rate of Interest.” In Readings in the Theory of Income Distribution. London: Allen and Unwin, 1950.Google Scholar
Romer, C. D. 1994. “Remeasuring Business Cycles.” The Journal of Economic History 54 (09): 573609.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ropke, Wilhelm. 1936. Crises and Cycles. London: Hodge and Company.Google Scholar
Rostow, W. W. 1990. Theorists of Economic Growth from David Hume to the Present. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Samuels, W. J. 1972. “The Teaching of Business Cycles in 1905–06.” History of Political Economy 4: 140–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt, Hermann. 1902. “Review of Studien zur Theorie und Geschichte der Handelskrisen in England.” Economic Journal XII: 524–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph. 1954. A History of Economic Analysis. London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Seligman, Ben. 1962. Main Currents in Modern Economics. Glencoe: Free Press.Google Scholar
Slater, Robert. 1 July 1858. In Report from the Select Committee on the Bank Acts together with the Proceedings of the Committee, Minutes of Evidence, Appendix and Index. London: House of Commons.Google Scholar
Tsiang, S. C. 1987. “Loanable Funds.” In Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P., eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovskii, M. I. 1892. Dzh. S. Mill'. Ego zhizn' i ucheno-literaturnaya deyatel'nost'. St. Petersburg.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovskii, M. I. 1894. Promyshlennye krizisy v sovremennoi Anglii, ikh prichiny i blizhaishie vliyaniya na narod-nuyu zhizn'. St. Petersburg.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovskii, M. I. 1895. “Krizisy khozyaistvennye.” In Brokgauz, F A. and Efron, I. A., eds., Entsiklopedicheskii slovar', vol. 32. St. Petersburg.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovskii, M. I. 1896. “Mill, Dzhon Styuart.” In Brokgauz, F A. and Efron, I. A., eds., Entsiklopedicheskii slovar', vol. 19. St. Petersburg.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovskii, M. I. 1900. Promyshlennye krizisy. Ocherk iz sotsial'noi istorii Anglii. St. Petersburg.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovskii, M. I. 1914. Izbrannoe: Periodicheskie prommyshlennye krizisy. Moscow: Nauka, 1997.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovskii, M. I. 1916. “Znachenie birzhi v sovremennom khozyaistvennom stroe.” In Yasnopol'skii, L. N., ed., Bankovaya entsiklopediya. Kiev.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovskii, M. I. 1917. Osnovy politicheskoi ekonomii, 4th edition. Moscow: Rosspen, 1998.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovskii, M. I. 1918. Kluchshemu budushchemu. Moscow: Rosspen, 1996.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovskii, M. I. 1923. Periodicheskie promyshlennye krizisy. Petrograd-Moscow.Google Scholar
Tuhan-Baranovsky, M. I. 1954. “Periodic Industrial Crises.” In Annals of the Ukrainian Academy of Arts and Sciences in the United States, pp. 745802.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovsky, M. I. 1970. The Russian Factory in the 19th Century. Illinois AEA.Google Scholar
Wagemann, Ernst. 1930. Economic Rhythm. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut. 1898. Interest and Prices. London: Macmillan, 1936.Google Scholar
Zarnowitz, Victor. 1997. “Business Cycles.” In Glasner, David, ed., Business Cycles and Depressions: An Encyclopedia. New York: Garland.Google Scholar