Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T03:23:21.009Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Efficiency Wages and Classical Wage Theory

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Michael E. Bradley
Affiliation:
Professor of Economics, University of Maryland, Baltimore County.

Extract

In The General Theory, John Maynard Keynes lumped together the marginalist and neoclassical economics of the late nineteenth and twentieth centuries and the more narrowly defined “classical” economics of Adam Smith, David Ricardo, J. R. McCulloch, James and John Stuart Mill and other mainstream economists of the late eighteenth and early nineteenth into what he called the “classical theory of employment,” which he reduced to two “fundamental postulates”:

(a) The wage is equal to the marginal product of labour

(b) The utility of the wage when a given volume of labour is employed is equal to the marginal disutility ofthat amount of employment…(Keynes 1936, p. 5).

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Agell, J. and Lundborg, P. (1992) Fair Wages, Involuntary Unemployment and Tax Policies in the Simple General Equilibrium Model, Journal of Public Economics, 47 (04), pp. 299320.Google Scholar
Agell, J. and Lundborg, P. (1995) Fair Wages in the Open Economy, Economica, New Series, 62 (08), pp. 335–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G. A. (1984) Gift Exchange and Efficiency-wage Theory: Four Views, American Economic Review (05), pp. 7983.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A. and Yellen, J. L. (1990) The Fair Wage-effort Hypothesis and Unemployment, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105 (05), pp. 255–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaug, M. (Ed) (1991) Thomas Robert Malthus (1766–1834) and John Stuart Mill (1806–1873) (Aldershot: Edward Elgar Publishing).Google Scholar
Blaug, M. (1996) Economic Theory in Retrospect, 5th edition (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Boal, W. M. and Ransom, M. R. (1997) Monopsony in the Labor Market, Journal of Economic Literature, 35 (03), pp. 86112.Google Scholar
Bowman, Rhead S. (2006) Population and Policy in Marshall's Economics, Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 28 (06), pp. 199219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breit, William (1967) The Wages Fund Controversy Revisited, Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 33 (11), pp. 509–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brems, H. (1986) Pioneering Economic Theory, 1630–1980: A Mathematical Restatement (Baltimore and London: The Johns Hopkins University Press).Google Scholar
Bulkley, G. and Myles, G. D. (1996) Trade Unions, Efficiency Wages, and Shirking, Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, 48 (01), pp. 7588.Google Scholar
Bulow, J. I. and Summers, L. H. (1986) A Theory of Dual Labor Markets with Application to Industrial Policy, Discrimination, and Keynesian Unemployment, Journal of Labor Economics, 4 (07), pp. 376414.Google Scholar
IIICampbell, C. M. (1993) Do Firms Pay Efficiency Wages? Evidence with Data at the Firm Level, Journal of Labor Economics, 11 (07), pp. 442–70.Google Scholar
Cannan, E. (1917) A History of the Theories of Production and Distribution in English Political Economy from 1776 to 1848 (London: Staples Press).Google Scholar
Cannan, E. (1929) A Review ofEconomic Theory (London: P.S. King and Son).Google Scholar
Clark, J. B. (1899) The Distribution of Wealth (New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1965).Google Scholar
Corden, W. M. (1978) Keynes and the Others: Wage and Price Rigidities in Macro-economic Models, Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, 30 (07), pp. 159–80.Google Scholar
Doeringer, P. B. (1986) Internal Labor Markets and Noncompeting Groups, American Economic Review, 76 (05), pp. 4852.Google Scholar
Doeringer, P. B. and Piore, M. J. (1970) Internal Labor Markets and Manpower Analysis (Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath).Google Scholar
Dasgupta, P. (1993) An Inquiry into Well-Being and Destitution (Oxford: Clarendon Press).Google Scholar
Eaton, C. and White, D. (1983) The Economy of High Wages: an Agency Problem, Economica, New Series, 50 (05), pp. 175–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekelund, R. B. (1976) A Short-run Classical Model of Capital and Wages: Mill's Recantation of the Wages Fund, Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, 28 (03), pp. 6685.Google Scholar
Filene, E. A. (1923) The Minimum Wage and Efficiency, American Economic Review, 13 (09), pp. 411–15.Google Scholar
Foster, A. D. (1995) Nutrition and Health Investment, American Economic Review, 85 (05), pp. 148–52.Google Scholar
Gerrard, B. (1995) Keynes, the Keynesians and the Classics: a Suggested Interpretation, Economic Journal, 105 (03), pp. 445–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, R. J. (1990) What is new-Keynesian Economics?, Journal of Economic Literature, 28 (09), 1115–71.Google Scholar
Greenwald, B. and Stiglitz, J. (1993) New and old Keynesians, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7 (Winter), pp. 2344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwald, B. and Stiglitz, J. E. Pareto (1988) Inefficiency of Market Economies: Search and Efficiency Wage Models, American Economic Review, 78 (05), pp. 351–55.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1963) The Theory of Wages, 2nd edition (London: Macmillan).Google Scholar
Hollander, S. (1968) The Role of Fixed Coefficients in the Evolution of the Wages-fund Controversy,’ Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, 20 (07), pp. 320–41, reprinted in: Mark M. Blaug (Ed) (1991), Thomas Robert Malthus (1766–1834) and John Stuart Mill (1806–1873) (Aldershot: Edward Elgar), pp. 47–68.Google Scholar
Hollander, S. (1985) The Economics ofJohn Stuart Mill, 2 vols. (Toronto: Toronto University Press).Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. (1879) Theory of Political Economy (New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1965).Google Scholar
Holmes, J. M. and Hutton, P. A. (1996) Keynesian Involuntary Unemployment and Sticky Wages, Economic Journal, 106 (11), pp. 1564–85.Google Scholar
Katz, L. F. (1988) Some Recent Developments in Labor Economics and Their Implications for Macroeconomics, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 20 (08), pp. 507–22.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1924) A Tract on Monetary Reform (Amherst, NY: Prometheus Books, 2000).Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (New York: Harcourt, Brace & World).Google Scholar
Krueger, A. B. and Summers, L. H. (1988) Efficiency Wages and the Inter-industry Wage Structure, Econometrica, 56 (03), 259–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leibenstein, Harvey (1957) The Theory of Underemployment in Backward Economies, Journal of Political Economy, 65 (04), 91103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Machlup, Fritz (1937), On the Meaning of the Marginal Product, Essays in Economic Semantics Miller, Merton H. (Ed) (New York: W. W. Norton 1957), pp. 191206.Google Scholar
MacLeod, W. B., Malcomson, J. M. and Gomme, P. (1994) Labor Turnover and the Natural Rate of Unemployment: Efficiency Wage Versus Frictional Unemployment, Journal of Labor Economics, 12 (04), pp. 276315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malcomson, J. M. (1981) Unemployment and the Efficiency Wage Hypothesis, Economic Journal, 91 (12), pp. 848–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malcomson, J. M. (1985) Incomplete Contracts and Involuntary Unemployment, Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, 37 (06), pp. 196209.Google Scholar
Malthus, T. R. (1798) An Essay on the Principle of Population, Appleman, Philip (Ed) (New York: Norton, 1976).Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1920), Principles of Economics, 8th edition (Philadelphia: Porcupine Press, 1990).Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1869), Thornton on Labour and its Claims, in: Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vol. V (Toronto: Toronto University Press, 1967), pp. 331–69.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1871) Principles of Political Economy, in: Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vols.II and III (Toronto: Toronto University Press, 1965).Google Scholar
Moore, H. L. (1907) The Efficiency Theory of Wages, Economic Journal, 17 (12), pp. 571–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oi, W. Y. (1990) Employment Relations in Dual Labor Markets (‘It's nice work if you can get it’), Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 8, pp. S124–S149.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. (1932) The Economics of Welfare, 4th edition (London: Macmillan, 1952).Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. (1933) The Theory of Unemployment (New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1971).Google Scholar
Pigou, A.C. (1949), Mill and the Wages Fund, Economic Journal, 59 (06), pp. 171–80.Google Scholar
Raff, D. M. G. and Summers, L. M. (1987) Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? Journal of Labor Economics, 5 (10), pp. S57–S86.Google Scholar
Rees, A. (1973) The Economics of Work and Pay (New York: Harper & Row).Google Scholar
Ricardo, D. (1821) The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (London: J. M. Dent & Sons, 1911).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1950) History ofEconomic Analysis (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Shapiro, C. and Stiglitz, J. E. (1984) Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device, American Economic Review, 74 (06), pp. 433–44.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 2 vols. (Indianapolis: Liberty Press, 1981).Google Scholar
Taussig, F. W. (1896) Wages and Capital: An Examination of the Wages Fund Doctrine (New York: D. Appleton and Company).Google Scholar
Tolles, N. A. (1964) Origins ofModern Wage Theories (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall).Google Scholar
Walker, Francis Amasa (1876) The Wages Question, Library of Economics and Liberty, http://www.econlib.org/library/YPDBooks/Walker/wlkWQ1.html,2004.Google Scholar
West, E. G. and Hafer, R. W. (1978) J. S. Mill, Unions and the Wages Fund Recantation: A Reinterpretation, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 92 (11), pp. 603–19.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1934) Lectures on Political Economy, Vol. I (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul).Google Scholar