Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T23:52:14.712Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Preferences, vote choice, and the politics of social investment: Addressing the puzzle of unequal benefits of childcare provision

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 June 2021

ERIK NEIMANNS*
Affiliation:
Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies, Paulstr. 3, 50676 Cologne, Germany Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Research on the politics of social investment finds public opinion to be highly supportive of expansive reforms and expects this support to matter for the politics of expanding social investment. Expanding social investment, it is argued, should be particularly attractive to left-wing voters and parties because of the egalitarian potential of such policies. However, few studies have examined to what extent individual preferences concerning social investment really matter politically. In this paper, I address this research gap for the crucial policy field of childcare by examining how individual-level preferences for expanding childcare provision translate into voting behavior. Based on original survey data from eight European countries, I find that preferences to expand public childcare spending indeed translate into electoral support for the left. However, this link from preferences to votes turns out to be socially biased. Childcare preferences are much more decisive for voting the further up individuals are in the income distribution. This imperfect transmission from preferences to voting behavior implies that political parties could have incentives to target the benefits of childcare reforms to their more affluent voters. My findings help to explain why governments frequently fail to reduce social inequality of access to seemingly egalitarian childcare provision.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press

Introduction

Over the past few years, the notion of a social investment welfare state has received increasing scholarly attention. The underlying idea of this work has been that a recalibration of the welfare state from passive compensatory transfers to social policies aimed at creating, mobilizing, and preserving skills (Garritzmann et al., Reference Garritzmann, Häusermann, Palier and Zollinger2017: 37) has the potential to strengthen social equality, welfare state sustainability, and economic growth (see also Morel et al., Reference Morel, Palier and Palme2012; Hemerijck, Reference Hemerijck2013). Yet, compared with the potential benefits, the implementation of social investment reforms has so far been rather piecemeal. In some countries, governments have expanded social investment over recent years whereas in others governments have even cut back on it (Hemerijck, Reference Hemerijck2013; Morgan, Reference Morgan2013; Bouget et al., Reference Bouget, Frazer, Marlier, Sabato and Vanhercke2015). In addition, socially disadvantaged individuals are often found to benefit less from social investment policies than individuals in the middle classes (Pavolini and Van Lancker, Reference Pavolini and Van Lancker2018; Bonoli and Liechti, Reference Bonoli and Liechti2018). Those unequal benefits put into doubt whether social investment policies are in fact able to unfold their egalitarian potential.

This discrepancy between potential benefits and realized reforms has motivated research on the politics of social investment. Generally, scholars expect expansive social investment reforms to be attractive to governments operating under severe fiscal constraints. Left-wing parties in particular might be able to use social investment as a means of “affordable credit claiming” by enacting widely popular, egalitarian, and relatively inexpensive social policies in times of severe fiscal constraints (Bonoli, Reference Bonoli2013). The growing number of studies on individual-level preferences towards social investment is in line with such reasoning, finding overall high levels of public support for expanding social investment (for example, Garritzmann et al., Reference Garritzmann, Busemeyer and Neimanns2018). Studies diverge more regarding the amount of class conflict surrounding social investment reforms. While some studies expect the more affluent middle classes to be most supportive of social investment (Häusermann and Kriesi, Reference Häusermann, Kriesi, Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015), others find support to be highest in the lowest income groups (for example, Chung and Meuleman, Reference Chung and Meuleman2017). In most studies of individual-level preferences towards social investment, including my own, the relevance of studying preferences is motivated by the argument that preferences matter as a potential factor shaping the politics of expanding social investment (Beramendi et al., Reference Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015; Häusermann and Kriesi, Reference Häusermann, Kriesi, Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015; Busemeyer and Neimanns, Reference Busemeyer and Neimanns2017; Chung and Meuleman, Reference Chung and Meuleman2017; Neimanns, Reference Neimanns2020; Neimanns and Busemeyer, Reference Neimanns and Busemeyer2021). However, those studies hardly pay attention to the question of the extent to which those preferences in fact translate into politics.

In this paper, I address this research gap by examining how individual preferences with regard to early childhood education and care (hereafter, childcare) translate into real political behavior. Childcare is a crucial test case for social investment more generally, given that it is often considered a central element of a social investment approach (Morel et al., Reference Morel, Palier and Palme2012; Hemerijck, Reference Hemerijck2013), and that social inequality of enrolment is often particularly pronounced (Van Lancker, Reference Van Lancker2013; Abrassart and Bonoli, Reference Abrassart and Bonoli2015; Van Lancker and Pavolini, Reference Van Lancker2018). Using original survey data for eight European countries (INVEDUC, 2014), I examine how preferences for increasing public childcare spending affect party vote choice.

My central claim is that the link from childcare preferences to voting behavior, which can be seen as a necessary condition for individual-level preferences mattering politically, is less trivial than it is often portrayed. My findings show that, on average, preferences for increasing childcare spending are indeed related to voting behavior, with supporters of expanding childcare being more likely to vote for left-wing parties. This association holds when controlling for preferences regarding social spending and social value orientations, which takes into account that childcare preferences are embedded in broader latent attitudes. However, it turns out that the transmission from preferences to votes is socially biased. For lower-income individuals, childcare preferences are unrelated to voting intentions. The higher up the income distribution individuals are, the more tightly voting behavior connects to preferences towards childcare. Thus, although lower-income individuals might be the strongest supporters of additional public childcare spending, political parties of the left and the right have incentives to target reforms to more affluent voters because those voters’ preferences translate more directly into actual votes. Taken together, my findings help us to understand why expansive social investment reforms are implemented less than one might expect and why they are often implemented in a socially stratified way. More broadly, these insights also connect to recent debates about unequal political representation (Bartels, Reference Bartels2008; Gilens and Page, Reference Gilens and Page2014; Elsässer et al., Reference Elsässer, Hense and Schäfer2020).

The politics of social investment: Individual-level preferences and voting behavior

Most studies of individual-level preferences regarding social investment and childcare policies argue that preferences matter as a potential factor shaping the politics of expanding social investment and childcare provision (for example, Beramendi et al., Reference Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015; Häusermann and Kriesi, Reference Häusermann, Kriesi, Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015; Busemeyer and Neimanns, Reference Busemeyer and Neimanns2017; Chung and Meuleman, Reference Chung and Meuleman2017). Generally, social investment policies are found to be widely popular among the public, with large majorities supporting expansion (Garritzmann et al., Reference Garritzmann, Busemeyer and Neimanns2018). Besides assessing the overall level of support for social investment policies, analysis of the extent of class conflict in preferences has received central attention in this literature. Häusermann and Kriesi (Reference Häusermann, Kriesi, Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015) argue that the highly educated middle classes benefit most strongly from social investment and should therefore be the strongest supporters of such policies (see also Beramendi et al., Reference Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015; Garritzmann et al., Reference Garritzmann, Häusermann, Palier and Zollinger2017). Evidence from Garritzmann et al. (Reference Garritzmann, Busemeyer and Neimanns2018) supports this line of reasoning. Income is found to matter less as a determinant of preferences regarding various social investment policies compared with passive transfer policies. Yet, various studies that more directly examine preferences concerning childcare tend to find lower-income respondents to be significantly more supportive of a strong role of the state in childcare provision (for example, Borck and Wrohlich, Reference Borck and Wrohlich2011; Chung and Meuleman, Reference Chung and Meuleman2017).Footnote 1 None of these studies has examined the extent to which preferences in fact translate into politics, however.Footnote 2 Thus, it remains unclear whether public support for expanding childcare originates primarily from the lower or from the middle-income classes, and how this class-related patterning of preferences affects the politics of expanding childcare.

Why should preferences regarding childcare matter politically? To matter politically, preferences need to translate into political behavior, with voting behavior being probably the most direct and most widespread manifestation of political behavior. The transmission from preferences to votes rests on certain informational requirements (Hellwig, Reference Hellwig2014). Individuals need to identify a political party’s position on a specific policy issue, and they need to be able to identify differences in positions across parties. The embeddedness of issues in broader societal cleavages and parties´ programmatic identities usually help individuals to overcome such information problems (ibid.). In today´s postindustrial societies this cleavage structure is usually found to be two-dimensional, with preferences for expanding childcare provision being expected to correlate with economic positions and social values leaning more to the left (Beramendi et al., Reference Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015; Häusermann and Kriesi, Reference Häusermann, Kriesi, Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015; Garritzmann et al., Reference Garritzmann, Busemeyer and Neimanns2018). To matter politically, childcare preferences would need to be a determinant of vote choice, independent of latent attitudes along the two dimensions of economic position and social values. If childcare preferences were only a subset of latent attitudes, parties´ incentives to respond to voters´ preferences to expand childcare could be rather low. Voters could be expected to be less likely to cast their vote based on their specific childcare preferences, but more on their broader latent attitudes on socio-economic issues and social value orientations. Parties, in turn, could find it more attractive to expand other areas of social spending or address other aspects of gender egalitarian positions in order to satisfy voter preferences.

The cognitive identification of partisan differences furthermore needs to translate into political behavior. First, childcare provision would need to be sufficiently important for relevant electoral groups to base their vote choice upon their preferences concerning childcare. Value change among highly educated middle-class women has been identified as a central factor leading to partisan de-alignment; in other words, to the erosion of ties between the established parties and those voter groups (Morgan, Reference Morgan2013; Blome, Reference Blome2017; Schwander, Reference Schwander, Manow, Palier and Schwander2018; Abou-Chadi and Wagner, Reference Abou-Chadi and Wagner2019; León et al., Reference León, Pavolini, Miró and Sorrenti2019). The established parties have for a long time paid only limited attention to issues of work–family life reconciliation. Religiosity used to be an important factor in ensuring the political viability of this neglect by mainstream parties. Because sizable voter segments, and, above average, women, cast their votes for center-right parties out of mostly religious motivations, party competition about progressive family policies has often been limited (Emmenegger and Manow, Reference Emmenegger and Manow2014). With the declining importance of religion, also the strength of partisan attachments decreased. Those swing voters should be highly supportive of expanding childcare provision, and, it is hypothesized, childcare provision should often be sufficiently important to them to affect their vote choice.

As a second requirement for preferences to have a political impact, this partisan dealignment would need to have consequences for party competition; in other words, it would need to open up the potential for partisan realignment. With their future careers depending on continuing electoral success, professional politicians are regularly found to be highly attentive to changing preferences in their electorates (Soroka and Wlezien, Reference Soroka and Wlezien2010). They often devote considerable resources to inform themselves about public opinion, relying on the news media (Sevenans et al., Reference Sevenans, Walgrave and Joanna Epping2016), their professional and social networks (Herbst, Reference Herbst1998), or public opinion surveys (Hager and Hilbig, Reference Hager and Hilbig2020). For the case of childcare provision, more specifically, women´s groups within the political parties have often been relevant in raising awareness for the importance of childcare expansion to support gender equality and families that are increasingly not adhering to the male breadwinner model (Morgan, Reference Morgan2013). Concerns about demographic change in many Western societies further contributed to the perceived importance of modernized family policy in supporting the reconciliation of work and family life (ibid.; Fleckenstein and Seeleib-Kaiser, Reference Fleckenstein and Seeleib-Kaiser2011). The combination of a growing salience of the issue of childcare, and of partisan dealignment contributing to heightened electoral competition (Hobolt and Klemmensen, Reference Hobolt and Klemmensen2008) render it plausible that parties have been particularly attentive to public opinion on childcare and have adjusted their positioning to these new societal and political demands.

The incentives to attract votes by expanding public spending on services targeted to electorally relevant groups are expected to be particularly pronounced for left-wing parties (Häusermann and Kriesi, Reference Häusermann, Kriesi, Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015). Expanding childcare spending provides an affordable, potentially redistributive means of continued state engagement in social policy in mature welfare states and it responds to value change towards support for a more gender-egalitarian distribution of work and family responsibilities. With regard to voter preferences along a distributive and a social values dimension, left-wing parties are likely to find wider support and less opposition among their core electorates to expand childcare compared with right-wing parties (Häusermann and Kriesi, Reference Häusermann, Kriesi, Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015; Garritzmann et al., Reference Garritzmann, Busemeyer and Neimanns2018; Schwander, Reference Schwander, Manow, Palier and Schwander2018).Footnote 3 Thus, it should be easier and electorally more rewarding for left-wing parties to adjust their programmatic positions to societal value change.

In line with these expectations, empirical findings show, first, that left-wing governments are more likely to expand childcare provision and, second, that expanding childcare provision pays off electorally. Studying the effects of government partisanship on public childcare spending, Hieda (Reference Hieda2013) and Busemeyer and Seitzl (Reference Busemeyer and Seitzl2018) find left-wing governments to be more likely to expand childcare. In a similar vein, studies focusing on the electoral consequences of parties´ programmatic positioning find that if left-wing parties emphasize childcare and related policies more strongly, their vote share increases (Nelson and Giger, Reference Nelson and Giger2018; Abou-Chadi and Wagner, Reference Abou-Chadi and Wagner2019). On average, left-wing parties seem to be able to promote childcare expansion and to reap the electoral benefits of such programmatic positioning.

While the studies discussed above suggest a positive link between individual-level preferences regarding childcare and voting for the left, to date no study has directly examined whether this link really exists. Studies that have examined the electoral consequences of value change have focused primarily on value change across different electoral groups, based on factors such as gender or occupation. As a consequence, this literature remains disconnected from studies on the determinants of childcare preferences, which come up with distinct expectations regarding the popularity of childcare expansion and the associated potential of class conflict. Building on the literature discussed above, I expect:

Hypothesis 1: The more individuals support an expansion of public childcare spending, the more likely they are to vote for left-wing parties.

The expectation spelled out in Hypothesis 1 leaves us with an important empirical puzzle. If childcare preferences tend to go along with support for state involvement and redistribution, and if left-wing parties are often the central promotors of expansive social investment reforms, why have recent childcare reforms often failed to address the social upward-bias in childcare enrolment (Van Lancker, Reference Van Lancker2018)? Across Western countries, more affluent families are overrepresented among the users of childcare because lower-income families are to a disproportionate extent negatively affected by problems of affordability (Abrassart and Bonoli, Reference Abrassart and Bonoli2015), availability (Pennerstorfer and Pennerstorfer, Reference Pennerstorfer and Pennerstorfer2020), or a combination of factors (Van Lancker and Ghysels, Reference Van Lancker and Ghysels2016; Lewis and West, Reference Lewis and West2017).Footnote 4 In the following, I argue that the link between preferences and voting is likely to be in itself socially upward biased as well.

I expect factors on the input and output side of the political process to matter for the conditioning impact of individuals’ socioeconomic position on the preference–voting nexus. First, with regard to the input side, lower-income individuals are more likely to have lower political efficacy (Marx and Nguyen, Reference Marx and Nguyen2018). The experience of economic problems is emotionally and cognitively absorbing and reduces individuals´ willingness and capacity to stay politically informed. Because low-income individuals are less likely to believe that their vote could make a difference or to be aware of parties´ programmatic offers, their preferences towards childcare should matter less for their vote choice. In addition, low-income individuals are particularly likely to abstain from voting, which further reduces their weight in the political process (Schäfer, Reference Schäfer2015). Political efficacy might be particularly important for the case of childcare because of its investment character, with some of its benefits materializing only at some distant point in the future. Whereas individuals in a low socioeconomic position might assign more weight to their current consumption needs relative to future investment, those in a more privileged socioeconomic position are better equipped to take a more long-term perspective (Beramendi et al., Reference Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015).

Second, on the output side, lower levels of political efficacy find their reflection in socially unequal political representation. A growing number of studies document that the preferences of affluent individuals are better represented in political reforms, whereas the preferences of lower income groups often hardly influence policy output (Bartels, Reference Bartels2008; Gilens and Page, Reference Gilens and Page2014; Elsässer et al., Reference Elsässer, Hense and Schäfer2020). There can be a variety of reasons for unequal political representation, including reliance on private campaign donations, unequal political participation, or unequal descriptive representation in parliament (ibid.). These factors help to understand why governments could be more responsive to more narrowly defined private interests, neglect preferences of nonvoters, and might neglect preferences of their lower income constituencies, if their assessment of public opinion is biased by their own socio-economic background and their specific social and professional networks (Carnes, Reference Carnes2013; Schäfer, Reference Schäfer2015). Issues that are important for individuals with lower incomes are often also less salient in the public discourse which reduces the pressure for governments to address those issues (Busemeyer et al., Reference Busemeyer, Garritzmann and Neimanns2020: 323). The limited influence on reform processes is likely to further reduce the motivation of lower-income individuals to base their vote on their specific preferences towards childcare policy.

In the case of childcare more specifically, unequal policy benefits are reflected in socially unequal enrolment patterns (Van Lancker, Reference Van Lancker2013). Political debates about expanding childcare have often been driven by the goal of facilitating the combination of work and family life for working parents: in particular, working women (Fleckenstein and Seeleib-Kaiser, Reference Fleckenstein and Seeleib-Kaiser2011; Naumann, Reference Naumann, Bonoli and Natali2012; Morgan, Reference Morgan2013). In contrast, aspects related to access to childcare – e.g. for non-employed parents, or support for disadvantaged children, which might be of particular importance for lower-income constituencies – sometimes received a relatively low weight in the political process (Lewis and West, Reference Lewis and West2017). Socially stratified access to childcare might lead lower-income individuals to expect that they would not benefit from expansive childcare reforms (Neimanns and Busemeyer, Reference Neimanns and Busemeyer2021) and therefore might not let childcare preferences affect their vote choice. For those who already enjoy privileged access to childcare it might appear more plausible that they would benefit from additional public money spent on childcare.

Taken together, the factors related to the input and the output sides of the political process should contribute towards a socially biased link between childcare preferences and voting for the left. Lower-income individuals should have fewer incentives to base their vote choice on their specific childcare preferences, whereas for more affluent individuals the opposite should be the case:

Hypothesis 2: The strength of the association between support for expanding public childcare spending and voting for left-wing parties increases with income.

Empirics

Methods and data

The empirical analysis builds on data from an original public opinion survey (INVEDUC, 2014) which we collected as part of a larger collaborative research project. In this survey, we asked respondents for a range of preferences regarding education and social policies. The survey was conducted by a professional survey company using computer-assisted telephone interviews in early 2014 in eight European countries (Denmark, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom). The random probability sample is representative of each country´s adult population and comprises a total of 8,905 individuals (for details, see Busemeyer et al., Reference Busemeyer, Garritzmann, Neimanns and Nezi2018).Footnote 5

To examine how childcare preferences translate into voting behavior, I run multinomial logistic regression models with vote intention as the dependent variable (“If there was a general election tomorrow, which party would you vote for?”). The list of major parties in their country was read out to respondents and several residual categories for those without clear party preferences were mentioned as well. The mentioning of additional parties was recorded via open-ended questions. I include only individuals with citizenship of the respective country, who should be eligible to vote in the national elections. For the analysis, I assign parties to party families, following the coding by Döring and Manow (Reference Döring and Manow2016) (see Table A.1 in the appendix). Several further operationalization steps are necessary to avoid the number of observations for the individual parties becoming too small. First, I concentrate on left-wing and center-right parties because the number of observations is very small for some of the other parties in some countries. Second, on the left, I pool “communist/socialist,” “social democratic,” and “green/ecological” parties. On the center-right, I combine “Christian democratic” and “conservative” parties into a single category. Preliminary models show that pooling is appropriate. Childcare preferences do not matter as a determinant for vote choice between these three left-wing party families, on one hand, and the two center-right party families, on the other hand (see Table A.2 in the appendix). I refrain from including liberal and far-right parties in the right-party category, because those parties tend to be less coherent in their positions on social policy across countries compared with the other party families (Busemeyer et al., Reference Busemeyer, Franzmann and Garritzmann2013; Röth et al., Reference Röth, Afonso and Spies2018).Footnote 6 I use the residual category of having no determined voting intention for a specific party (which includes on average approximately 30 percent of respondents) as the reference category in the multinomial logistic regression models.

Focusing on voters of left and center-right parties implies that evidence of limited political influence of individuals from a lower socio-economic position should be interpreted as conservative estimates. The reason for this is abstention from voting, which is usually much more widespread among individuals from a low-income background (Schäfer, Reference Schäfer2015). This pattern is also present in the data used for this analysis. The likelihood among respondents in the lowest income quintile of reporting to not go to vote, to vote blank, or to cast a spoil vote is 12 percent, whereas it is around 6 percent for individuals in the three highest income quintiles (see Table A.9 in the appendix).

Preferences towards public childcare spending are the central independent variable. In the INVEDUC survey, respondents were asked:

“Please tell me whether you would like to see more or less government spending in each of the following areas. Keep in mind that ‘more’ or ‘much more’ might require a tax increase: Pre-school and early childhood education” Footnote 7

Respondents could indicate their preference for “much more”, “more”, “same as now,” “less,” or “much less” spending. Higher values indicate a preference for more public spending. The advantage of this variable on spending preferences is that it is a more direct and probably more realistic measure of individual-level support for government expansion of childcare provision than other available measures, such as the widely used item “government responsibility to ensure sufficient childcare” from the European Social Survey (ESS, 2008, 2016). As a comparison of factor analyses of preferences regarding various areas of social policy from the ESS and INVEDUC reveals, childcare preferences in the INVEDUC survey correlate much less with broader social policy preferences (see Table A.3 in the appendix). Using this measure of childcare spending preferences implies that I will be better able to capture the effect of preferences that is specific to childcare preferences, rather than measuring the effect of social policy preferences more generally. In addition, summary statistics show that support for public spending increases on childcare is more divided in contrast to the close to unanimous levels of support for childcare in the ESS (see Figure A.1 in the appendix). On average, 51 percent of respondents support additional public spending on childcare. Requiring the government to devote additional public resources to expand childcare might be more controversial in terms of political preferences, and it might be the more realistic measure of political preferences, compared with the more abstract notion that the government should “ensure sufficient childcare.”

Figure 1. Predicted probabilities of supporting additional public childcare spending by income

Note: Predicted probabilities and 95 percent confidence intervals based on logistic regressions. Regression results are reported in Table A.5 in the appendix.

In order to be able to identify the effects of childcare preferences on voting behavior, it is necessary to account as much as possible for potential endogeneity of childcare preferences to partisan preferences. If childcare preferences were endogenous to partisan preferences, this would imply that childcare preferences do not drive voting behavior, but rather that childcare preferences are a subset of broader ideological orientations. To control for this potential endogeneity, I add latent attitudes on social spending and social values as control variables. This allows me to capture the “net” effect of childcare preferences on voting behavior, independent of the two-dimensional left–right cleavage structure that has been found to matter in contemporary post-industrial societies (Beramendi et al., Reference Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015). More specifically, I control for general preferences towards social spending (“Should the government spend more or less on social benefits and social services?”) and for social value orientations, which are the predicted values of factor scores of two items on multiculturalism and law-and-order policies (“People who break the law should be given much harsher sentences than they are these days“ and “[COUNTRY]ʼs cultural life is generally enriched by people coming to live here from other countries“). The detailed operationalization of all variables included in the analysis is described in Table A.4 in the appendix.

I use household income (measured in quintiles) as an indicator of individuals’ socioeconomic position, which I expect to moderate the effect of childcare preferences on voting behavior. Household income is a suitable indicator in this context because it corresponds to the measures commonly used to capture inequality in the input and the output sides of the political process discussed above. In addition, I include a range of control variables, which are standard in analyses of the determinants of childcare preferences (for example, Busemeyer and Neimanns, Reference Busemeyer and Neimanns2017; Chung and Meuleman, Reference Chung and Meuleman2017). I control for age, gender, having kids above or below the age of ten, being a single parent, household size, employment status (interacted with gender), public sector employment, and whether a respondent lives in an urban or a rural area.

The analysis is run for the pooled sample of eight countries. I include country fixed effects in all models to control for unobserved heterogeneity at the country level. The main reason for pooling is to avoid the size of the different income-specific partisan voter groups becoming too small. Pooling is not unproblematic because childcare provision varies considerably across these eight European countries in terms of funding or coverage (Morgan, Reference Morgan2013). This variation could also be reflected in parties´ programmatic positioning regarding childcare policy. As a consistency check of whether it is appropriate to expect support for childcare expansion to be associated with support for left parties across countries, I examine party positions on the broader issue of traditional morality based on data from the Comparative Manifesto Project (Volkens et al., Reference Volkens, Krause, Lehmann, Matthieß, Merz, Regel and Weßels2019). Because the issue of childcare policy has often been embedded in a discourse on morality and debates about modern or traditional family and gender roles (Morgan, Reference Morgan2013; Emmenegger and Manow, Reference Emmenegger and Manow2014; Blome, Reference Blome2017), and given the lack of more adequate data with suitable spatial and temporal coverage, this data provides a useful consistency check. Table A.10 in the online appendix shows that around the time of the survey left parties in basically all countries had less traditional positions than their center-right counterparts on the issue of traditional morality.Footnote 8 Although partisan differences have been declining since the 2000s, positioning on traditional morality continued to clearly divide parties of the left and right (Figure A.6 in the appendix). Thus, it appears reasonable to expect preferences for childcare expansion to translate into electoral support for left parties across countries.

Results

Before assessing the impact of preferences regarding childcare expansion on voting intentions, it is necessary to clarify the extent to which it is plausible to expect childcare politics to structure political competition along socioeconomic lines. As discussed above, studies diverge in their findings on the relevance of class conflict in childcare preferences. Figure 1 plots predicted probabilities of supporting public spending increases on childcare by income group, controlling for socio-demographic and latent attitudinal covariates. The full regression results are reported in Table A.5 in the appendix.Footnote 9

The main message of Figure 1 is twofold. On the one hand, on average, individuals from the lowest income quintile are the strongest supporters of increases in public childcare spending. The predicted probability of supporting additional public childcare spending is 4.36 percentage points higher among people in the lowest income quintile compared to people in the highest income quintile. With the exception of individuals from the second income quintile, the association between income and childcare preferences is linear. The remarkably low level of spending support of individuals from the second income quintiles requires further examination. Additional analyses (Figure A.5 in the appendix) show that parents with small children are underrepresented and students and individuals with more traditional value orientations are overrepresented in the second income quintile. These characteristics matter in shaping preferences towards childcare spending and help to explain why individuals from the second income quintile deviate from the negative linear effect of income on preferences towards public childcare spending.

On the other hand, the income effect identified in Figure 1 is fairly weak in substantive terms and does not achieve statistical significance. Thus, while, on average, there does not appear to be a large potential for social class conflict surrounding childcare expansion, it is also inappropriate to consider support for expanding public childcare spending to originate primarily from middle-income groups.Footnote 10 Given that the socioeconomic structure of childcare preferences resembles the one frequently found for preferences regarding social policy and redistribution more generally (for example, Finseraas, Reference Finseraas2009), based on Figure 1, it appears plausible to expect preferences for expanding public childcare spending to translate into stronger electoral support for left vis-à-vis center-right parties.

Figure 2 shows how the predicted probabilities of voting for left or center-right parties depend on childcare spending preferences (see Table A.6 in the appendix for the full results of the multinomial logistic regressions). Figure 2 reveals that preferences for increasing public childcare spending are indeed tightly connected to electoral support for the left. Comparing individuals with a preference for unchanged spending levels to those who want to see much more public childcare spending accounts for an increased likelihood of voting for the left by 6.81 percentage points. This finding is likely to reflect partisan realignment, with left-wing parties being particularly responsive to value change in the electorate and with voters rewarding this (cf. Nelson and Giger, Reference Nelson and Giger2018). Figure 2 also indicates partisan dealignment for center-right parties. The likelihood of voting for center-right parties decreases by 3.19 percentage points among individuals with preferences for much more public childcare spending (compared to those wanting spending to remain unchanged). Thus, while the voting behavior of supporters of childcare expansion seems to matter for the electoral fortunes of both left and right parties, the stakes appear to be higher for left-wing parties. The electoral prospects of left-wing parties hinge to a particular extent on their capacity to attract the votes of those individuals supporting childcare expansion.

Figure 2. Childcare preferences and predicted probabilities of voting for left or center-right parties

Note: Predicted probabilities and 95 percent confidence intervals based on multinomial logistic regressions. Regression results are reported in Table A.6 in the appendix.

The findings presented in Figures 1 and 2 raise an important empirical puzzle: If childcare policies are demanded by individuals who would benefit from their redistributive potential, and if left-wing parties have incentives to expand such redistributive childcare policies, why does childcare enrolment continue to be highly socially stratified in most countries? Why do policymakers frequently fail to enable lower-income people to benefit more from childcare expansion, even though, on average, they are the policy’s strongest supporters? As I have argued above, the impact of childcare preferences on voting behavior is unlikely to be the same across socioeconomic groups. To evaluate this claim empirically, I add an interaction between preferences regarding public childcare spending and household income and in Figure 3 report the marginal effects of childcare preferences by income on support for left or center-right parties.Footnote 11 The full regression results are presented in Table A.7 in the appendix.

Figure 3. Average marginal effect of supporting additional public childcare spending on voting intention for left or center-right parties, conditioned by household income

Note: Average marginal effects and 95 percent confidence intervals based on multinomial logistic regressions. Regression results are reported in Table A.7 in the appendix.

Figure 3 strikingly shows that the association between childcare spending support and voting intentions is conditioned by income. The positive effect of childcare spending support on voting for the left rises with income. For respondents in the lowest income quintile, spending preferences do not matter for voting choice. In contrast, for respondents in the highest income quintile, support for increasing childcare spending increases the propensity to vote for the left by 6.96 percentage points. The flip side of the positive effect of income on the preference–voting nexus for the left is a negative income effect for center-right parties. Childcare preferences do not matter for voting intentions for center-right parties among individuals in the lowest income quintile for whom the average marginal effect estimate is basically zero. Childcare spending support is negatively signed and statistically insignificant for three of the other income quintiles, but for individuals from the fourth income quintile there is a significant effect of spending support on a reduced likelihood to vote for center-right parties (6.31 percentage points). Taken together, Figure 3 suggests that higher-income voters, and in particular those potentially voting for the left, are more likely to base their vote choice on their preferences regarding childcare expansion.Footnote 12 One implication of this finding is that parties might have an incentive to target reforms to higher-income voters because it might turn out to be electorally most rewarding.

Is the social bias in the preference–voting nexus specific to the case of childcare? While some of the arguments that led me to Hypothesis 2 should apply across policy issues, the long-term investment character (Beramendi et al., Reference Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015) and the nearly omnipresent high level of social inequality of enrolment (Van Lancker, Reference Van Lancker2013) should render this social bias particularly pronounced for the case of childcare. To examine this, I replicate Figure 3, replacing childcare preferences as the central independent variable with (a) social spending preferences and (b) social value orientations. Those figures (Figures A.2 and A.3 in the appendix) show income effects for the preference–voting nexus similar to those found in Figure 3. One important difference, however, is that in these additional figures preferences are a significant predictor of vote choice across income groups, including individuals in the lowest income quintile.Footnote 13 Thus, the irrelevance of childcare preferences to the voting behavior of low-income individuals, as identified in Figure 3, seems to be particularly linked to the characteristics of childcare.

Conclusion

Recent research suggests that high levels of public support for social investment policies should provide incentives for political parties to expand social investment. To date, however, no study has directly examined the extent to which preferences regarding social investment in fact translate into politics. This paper has addressed this research gap for one step of this causal chain for the crucial policy field of childcare. It has analyzed how individual preferences for expanding public childcare spending translate into politics: namely, by affecting individual propensities to vote for left or center-right political parties. I find that preferences indeed seem to translate into voting behavior, with individuals supportive of childcare expansion being more likely to vote for left and less likely to vote for center-right parties. The transmission from preferences to votes is, however, highly socially biased. For individuals in the lowest income groups, preferences are not significantly related to voting behavior. With rising income, preferences become more decisive in affecting voting intentions.

My findings help us to understand the often socially stratified nature of social investment reforms. Despite being demanded in particular by individuals in a lower-income position, left-wing parties could have incentives to target childcare reforms to individuals located higher up the income distribution because the latter’s voting behavior is most tightly connected to their preferences regarding childcare expansion. The same can be expected to hold true for right-wing parties, which might try to prevent (middle- and upper-income) voters interested in childcare expansion defecting to the political left. These incentives to discount the preferences of lower-income individuals are likely to be even exacerbated because lower-income individuals are more likely to abstain from voting (Schäfer, Reference Schäfer2015). The results appear pessimistic from the perspective of social equality because they suggest that political opportunity structures make it difficult for political parties to maximize the egalitarian potential of social investment policies. More broadly, my results connect to the growing literature on unequal political representation (Bartels, Reference Bartels2008; Gilens and Page, Reference Gilens and Page2014; Elsässer et al., Reference Elsässer, Hense and Schäfer2020). The socially upward-biased link between preferences and voting presents one of several possible mechanisms that explain why parties might have stronger incentives to represent the preferences of more affluent citizens.

This paper raises several further questions, which should be addressed in future research. I examine only a small step in the causal chain of the politics of social investment, and I do this only for the single, but nevertheless crucial policy field of childcare. How voting shapes parties´ programmatic offers and how it might in fact depend on those offers is beyond the scope of this paper. The same applies to cognitive decision-making processes at the level of parties: Are professional politicians aware of the varying preferences towards childcare provision among their different electorates and how could such information impact the positioning of parties regarding childcare expansion? Furthermore, a range of confounding and contextual factors can be expected to intervene in the relationship between childcare preferences and vote choice (cf. Emmenegger and Manow, Reference Emmenegger and Manow2014; Schwander, Reference Schwander, Manow, Palier and Schwander2018). Future research should explore in more detail how party competition and further contextual factors might either strengthen or attenuate the strength of and social bias in the preference–voting nexus. This would make it possible to identify political conditions under which childcare reforms are more likely to be designed in a way that in fact benefits the most disadvantaged individuals.

Acknowledgements

I wish to thank Björn Bremer and Lea Elsässer for highly helpful comments and suggestions on previous versions of this manuscript. This work was supported by the European Research Council under Grant No. 311769.

Competing interests

The author declares none.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/S0047279421000325

Footnotes

1 An additional strand of research has begun to study preferences towards social investment policies by taking into account fiscal constraints (Busemeyer and Garritzmann, Reference Busemeyer and Garritzmann2017; Busemeyer et al., Reference Busemeyer, Garritzmann, Neimanns and Nezi2018; Neimanns et al., Reference Neimanns, Busemeyer and Garritzmann2018). This research finds that the popularity of social investment policies drops significantly when an expansion of social investment comes at the cost of fiscal- or policy trade-offs. However, because those approaches are unable to capture the full menu of policy options that is available to policymakers when expanding social investment, I focus on unconstrained preferences regarding public spending as the more parsimonious measure of individual-level preferences.

2 But see Blome (Reference Blome2017: 135) for an examination of the association between value orientations and voting behavior in Germany and Italy.

3 There might be opposition to childcare expansion among core constituencies of both the traditional left and right parties because of traditional value orientation among the working class for the former and the role of religious voters for the latter. However, because left-wing voters should be more supportive of an active and potentially redistributive role of the government in childcare expansion, childcare expansion should, on average, be easier and electorally more rewarding for left-wing parties. In addition, right-wing parties might be strategically constrained in their positioning by far-right competitor parties (Garritzmann et al., Reference Garritzmann, Busemeyer and Neimanns2018; Schwander, Reference Schwander, Manow, Palier and Schwander2018).

4 Pavolini and Van Lancker (Reference Pavolini and Van Lancker2018) find that insufficient availability and affordability of childcare are decisive in shaping social inequality of enrolment. Other factors such as cultural attitudes or parental employment patterns matter less.

5 The data set is available at the GESIS Data Archive: https://doi.org/10.4232/1.13140.

6 As the only exception I assign the Danish liberal party Venstre to the conservative camp, because Venstre is the largest party of the center-right party spectrum in Denmark. In all other countries, the liberal parties are smaller than the main conservative or Christian democratic parties.

7 Clarifying notes in the questionnaire indicated that “pre-school early childhood education“ covers all programs that include components of early childhood educational development before primary school.

8 The United Kingdom constitutes an exception with the Labour Party scoring somewhat higher than the Conservatives on the issue of traditional morality. This observation is in line with Emmenegger and Manow´s (Reference Emmenegger and Manow2014) notion of the absence of a strong religious cleavage in the UK. Nevertheless, given the extensive budgetary cuts in the area of childcare applied by the Conservative-led government in the period preceding the survey (Lewis and West, Reference Lewis and West2017), it appears plausible to expect support for childcare expansion to translate into support for the political left including in the UK.

9 To ease presentation, Figure 1 relies on a logistic regression model using a binary operationalization of childcare preferences. Preferences for “more” or “much more” spending (coded as 1) are distinguished from preferences for “same as now,” “less,” or “much less” spending (coded as 0). The results hold, if the original categorical measure is used with an ordered logistic regression model (Table A.8 in the appendix).

10 It should be noted that the country-pooled models presented here brush over cross-country differences in the potential for social class conflict across income groups (Neimanns and Busemeyer, Reference Neimanns and Busemeyer2021). Because I am interested in the average association between income and childcare preferences as a plausibility check for the hypothesized link between childcare preferences and electoral support for the left, I disregard cross-country differences in this analysis.

11 Because it is computationally too demanding to run the multinomial logistic regression model underlying Figure 3 with a categorical operationalization of childcare preferences (for which the number of responses in some response categories is low; see Figure A.1), I use a binary operationalization of this variable in this step of the analysis.

12 In contrast to the findings in Figure 3, childcare preferences are not systematically associated with the intention to abstain from voting (Figure A.4 in the appendix).

13 The only exception being individuals from the lowest income quintile with regard to the role of social value orientations as a determinant of voting for center-right parties (Figure A.3).

References

Abou-Chadi, T. and Wagner, M. (2019), ‘The electoral appeal of party strategies in postindustrial societies: when can the mainstream left succeed?’, The Journal of Politics, 81(4), 14051419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abrassart, A. and Bonoli, G. (2015), ‘Availability, Cost or Culture? Obstacles to Childcare Services for Low Income Families’, Journal of Social Policy, 44(4), 787806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartels, L. M. (2008), Unequal democracy: The political economy of the new gilded age, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Beramendi, P., Häusermann, S., Kitschelt, H. and Kriesi, H. (Eds.). (2015), The Politics of Advanced Capitalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blome, A. (2017), The Politics of Work-Family Policy Reforms in Germany and Italy, London, New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bonoli, G. (2013), The Origins of Active Social Policy: Labour Market and Childcare Policies in a Comparative Perspective, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonoli, G. and Liechti, F. (2018), ‘Good intentions and Matthew effects: access biases in participation in active labour market policies’, Journal of European Public Policy, 25(6), 894911.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borck, R. and Wrohlich, K. (2011), ‘Preferences for Childcare Policies: Theory and Evidence’, European Journal of Political Economy, 27(3), 436454.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouget, D., Frazer, H., Marlier, E., Sabato, S. and Vanhercke, B. (2015), Social Investment in Europe: A study of National Policies, Luxembourg: European Commission-European Social Policy Network (ESPN).Google Scholar
Busemeyer, M. R., Franzmann, S. T. and Garritzmann, J. L. (2013), ‘Who Owns Education? Cleavage Structures in the Partisan Competition over Educational Expansion’, West European Politics, 36(3), 521546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, M. R. and Garritzmann, J. L. (2017), ‘Public opinion on policy and budgetary trade-offs in European welfare states: evidence from a new comparative survey’, Journal of European Public Policy, 24(6), 871889.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, M. R., Garritzmann, J. L. and Neimanns, E. (2020), A loud but noisy signal? Public opinion and education reform in Western Europe, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, M. R., Garritzmann, J. L., Neimanns, E. and Nezi, R. (2018), ‘Investing in Education in Europe: Evidence from a New Survey of Public Opinion’, Journal of European Social Policy, 28(1), 3454.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, M. R. and Neimanns, E. (2017), ‘Conflictive Preferences Towards Social Investments and Transfers in Mature Welfare States: The Cases of Unemployment Benefits and Childcare Provision’, Journal of European Social Policy, 27(3), 229246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, M. R. and Seitzl, L. (2018), ‘The Partisan Politics of Early Childhood Education in the German Länder’, Journal of Public Policy, 38(2), 243274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carnes, N. (2013), White-collar government: The hidden role of class in economic policy making, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chung, H. and Meuleman, B. (2017), ‘European parents’ attitudes towards public childcare provision: The role of current provisions, interests and ideologies’, European Societies, 19(1), 4968.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Döring, H. and Manow, P. (2016), Parliaments and Governments Database (Parlgov): Information on Parties, Elections and Cabinets in Modern Democracies.Google Scholar
Elsässer, L., Hense, S. and Schäfer, A. (2020), ‘Not just money: unequal responsiveness in egalitarian democracies’, Journal of European Public Policy, 119.Google Scholar
Emmenegger, P. and Manow, P. (2014), ‘Religion and the gender vote gap: Women’s changed political preferences from the 1970s to 2010’, Politics & Society, 42(2), 166193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
ESS. (2008), European Social Survey Round 4 Data. Data file edition 4.3. NSD - Norwegian Centre for Research Data, Norway – Data Archive and distributor of ESS data for ESS ERIC.Google Scholar
ESS. (2016), European Social Survey Round 8 Data. Data file edition 2.1. NSD - Norwegian Centre for Research Data, Norway – Data Archive and distributor of ESS data for ESS ERIC.Google Scholar
Finseraas, H. (2009), ‘Income Inequality and Demand for Redistribution: A Multilevel Analysis of European Public Opinion’, Scandinavian Political Studies, 32(1), 94119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleckenstein, T. and Seeleib-Kaiser, M. (2011), ‘Business, skills and the welfare state: the political economy of employment-oriented family policy in Britain and Germany’, Journal of European Social Policy, 21(2), 136149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garritzmann, J., Häusermann, S., Palier, B. and Zollinger, C. (2017), ‘WOPSI-the World Politics of Social Investment’, LIEPP Working Paper 64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garritzmann, J. L., Busemeyer, M. R. and Neimanns, E. (2018), ‘Public demand for social investment: new supporting coalitions for welfare state reform in Western Europe?’, Journal of European Public Policy, 25(6), 844861.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilens, M. and Page, B. I. (2014), ‘Testing theories of American politics: Elites, interest groups, and average citizens’, Perspectives on Politics, 12(3), 564581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Häusermann, S. and Kriesi, H. (2015), ‘What Do Voters Want? Dimensions and Configurations in Indiviudal-Level Preferences and Party Choice’, in Beramendi, P., Häusermann, S., Kitschelt, H., and Kriesi, H. (eds), The Politics of Advanced Capitalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 202230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hager, A. and Hilbig, H. (2020), ‘Does public opinion affect political speech?’, American Journal of Political Science, 64(4), 921937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellwig, T. (2014), ‘The structure of issue voting in postindustrial democracies’, The Sociological Quarterly, 55(4), 596624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hemerijck, A. (2013), Changing Welfare States, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Herbst, S. (1998), Reading public opinion: How political actors view the democratic process, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hieda, T. (2013), ‘Politics of Childcare Policy beyond the Left–Right Scale: Post-Industrialisation, Transformation of Party Systems and Welfare State Restructuring’, European Journal of Political Research, 52(4), 483511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobolt, S. B. and Klemmensen, R. (2008), ‘Government Responsiveness and Political Competition in Comparative Perspective’, Comparative Political Studies, 41(3), 309337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
INVEDUC. (2014), Investing in Education in Europe: Attitudes, Politics and Policies (Inveduc). Busemeyer, M. R., Garritzmann, J. L., Neimanns, E. and Nezi, R. GESIS Datenarchiv, Köln. ZA6961 Datenfile Version 1.0.0 (2018), https://doi.org/10.4232/1.13140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
León, M., Pavolini, E., Miró, J. and Sorrenti, A. (2019), ‘Policy Change and Partisan Politics: Understanding Family Policy Differentiation in Two Similar Countries’, Social Politics: International Studies in Gender, State & Society. Online first.Google Scholar
Lewis, J. and West, A. (2017), ‘Early childhood education and care in England under austerity: continuity or change in political ideas, policy goals, availability, affordability and quality in a childcare market?’, Journal of Social Policy, 46(2), 331348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marx, P. and Nguyen, C. G. (2018), ‘Political participation in European welfare states: does social investment matter?’, Journal of European Public Policy, 25(6), 912943.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morel, N., Palier, B. and Palme, J. (2012), Towards a Social Investment Welfare State?, Bristol: The Policy Press.Google Scholar
Morgan, K. J. (2013), ‘Path Shifting of the Welfare State: Electoral Competition and the Expansion of Work-Family Policies in Western Europe’, World Politics, 65(1), 73115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naumann, I. K. (2012), ‘Childcare Politics in the “New” Welfare State’, in Bonoli, G. and Natali, D. (eds), The Politics of the New Welfare State, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 158181.Google Scholar
Neimanns, E. (2020), ‘Unequal benefits–diverging attitudes? Analysing the effects of an unequal expansion of childcare provision on attitudes towards maternal employment across 18 European countries’, Journal of Public Policy, Online first, 126.Google Scholar
Neimanns, E., Busemeyer, M. R. and Garritzmann, J. L. (2018), ‘How Popular Are Social Investment Policies Really? Evidence from a Survey Experiment in Eight Western European Countries’, European Sociological Review, 34(3), 238253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neimanns, E. and Busemeyer, M. R. (2021), ‘Class politics in the sandbox? An analysis of the socio-economic determinants of preferences towards public spending and parental fees for childcare’, Social Policy & Administration, 55(1), 226241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, M. and Giger, N. (2018), ‘Social investment by popular demand? The electoral politics of employment-centered family policy’, Comparative European Politics, 17(3), 426446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pavolini, E. and Van Lancker, W. (2018), ‘The Matthew effect in childcare use: a matter of policies or preferences?’, Journal of European Public Policy, 25(6), 878893.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pennerstorfer, A. and Pennerstorfer, D. (2020), ‘Inequalities in spatial accessibility of childcare: The role of non-profit providers’, Journal of Social Policy. Online first.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Röth, L., Afonso, A. and Spies, D. C. (2018), ‘The impact of Populist Radical Right Parties on socio-economic policies’, European Political Science Review, 10(3), 325350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schäfer, A. (2015), Der Verlust politischer Gleichheit: warum die sinkende Wahlbeteiligung der Demokratie schadet, Frankfurt/New York: Campus Verlag.Google Scholar
Schwander, H. (2018), ‘Electoral Demand, Party Competition, and Family Policy: The Politics of a New Policy Field’, in Manow, P., Palier, B., and Schwander, H. (eds), Welfare Democracies and Party Politics: Explaining Electoral Dynamics in Times of Changing Welfare Capitalism, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 197224.Google Scholar
Sevenans, J., Walgrave, S. and Joanna Epping, G. (2016), ‘How political elites process information from the news: The cognitive mechanisms behind behavioral political agenda-setting effects’, Political Communication, 33(4), 605627.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soroka, S. N. and Wlezien, C. (2010), Degrees of Democracy: Politics, Public Opinion, and Policy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Van Lancker, W. (2013), ‘Putting the Child-Centred Investment Strategy to the Test: Evidence for the EU27’, European Journal of Social Security, 15(1), 427.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Lancker, W. (2018), ‘Reducing inequality in childcare service use across European countries: What (if any) is the role of social spending?’, Social Policy & Administration, 52(1), 271292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Lancker, W. and Ghysels, J. (2016), ‘Explaining patterns of inequality in childcare service use across 31 developed economies: A welfare state perspective’, International Journal of Comparative Sociology, 57(5), 310337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volkens, A., Krause, W., Lehmann, P., Matthieß, T., Merz, N., Regel, S. and Weßels, B. (2019), The Manifesto Data Collection. Manifesto Project (MRG/CMP/MARPOR).Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Predicted probabilities of supporting additional public childcare spending by incomeNote: Predicted probabilities and 95 percent confidence intervals based on logistic regressions. Regression results are reported in Table A.5 in the appendix.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Childcare preferences and predicted probabilities of voting for left or center-right partiesNote: Predicted probabilities and 95 percent confidence intervals based on multinomial logistic regressions. Regression results are reported in Table A.6 in the appendix.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Average marginal effect of supporting additional public childcare spending on voting intention for left or center-right parties, conditioned by household incomeNote: Average marginal effects and 95 percent confidence intervals based on multinomial logistic regressions. Regression results are reported in Table A.7 in the appendix.

Supplementary material: File

Neimanns supplementary material

Neimanns supplementary material

Download Neimanns supplementary material(File)
File 528.2 KB