Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-01T13:49:09.016Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Altruism and Self Interest in Medical Decision Making

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2021

Extract

It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest.

Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations

As the quote above indicates, economists generally are more comfortable with self interest as a motivating force for social benefit than with altruism. This is because in most instances in a market economy, self interest will lead agents to provide benefits for others. Ultimately this is because the butcher or baker will not get paid unless he does something that others are willing to pay for. This is the source of the famous “invisible hand,” also discussed by Adam Smith.

This might sound trivial, except that in discussing aspects of medicine we seem to lose sight of this mechanism and rely on other tools to provide benefits. These tools do not work as well as naked self interest would. Some might say that medicine and medical progress is too important to depend on the market.

Type
Symposium
Copyright
Copyright © American Society of Law, Medicine and Ethics 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

For an argument that reliance on markets is preferable to reliance on tools preferred by ethicists in providing body parts, see Hylton, K. N., “Biomedical Ethics and the Law: A Critical Perspective”, Annual Review of Law and Ethics (Jahrbuch für Recht und Ethik) 15 (2007): 611631.Google Scholar
Excerpted Remarks of Billy Tauzin, President and Chief Executive Officer Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America, PhRMA 2007 Annual Meeting, Washington, D.C., March 16, 2007, available at <http://www.phrma.org/about_phrma/straight_talk_from_billy_tauzin/serving_patients_our_central_mission/> (last visited June 3, 2009).+(last+visited+June+3,+2009).>Google Scholar
For a critique of all aspects of the drug industry, see Angell, M., The Truth About the Drug Companies: How They Deceive Us and What to Do about It (New York: Random House, 2005). This book is a polemic against the drug industry by Dr. Angell, the former editor of the New England Journal of Medicine. She is a major critic of the view I am espousing here, that self interest by the drug companies will lead to social benefits. While there are many critics of the drug industry I will rely on Dr. Angell as a foil since she is a respected member of the medical community and expresses (albeit often in an extreme form) most of the criticisms that are generally applied to the industry. Her discussion of “me too” drugs is in Chapter 5 of her book.Google Scholar
Id., at 3536. She makes this point in the context of discussing the benefits of the FDA, but it also applies to other issues regarding learning about drugs.Google Scholar
For example, Soumerai, S. B. and Avorn, J., “Economic and Policy Analysis of University-Based Drug ‘Detailing,’” Medical Care 24, no. 4 (1986): 313331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, H., “Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint,” Journal of Law and Economics 12, no. 1 (1969); 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
The classic source is Akerlof, G., “The Market for Lemons: Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 84, no. 3 (1970): 488500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, P., “Information and Consumer Behavior,” Journal of Political Economy 78, no. 2 (1970): 311329; Klein, B. and Leffler, K. B., “The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance”, Journal of Political Economy 89, no. 4 (1981): 615-641.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
This issue is discussed more generally in Rubin, P. H., “Regulation of Information and Advertising”, Competition Policy International 4, no. 1 (2008): 168192.Google Scholar
Lichtenberg, F. R. and Virabhak, S., “Pharmaceutical-Embodied Technical Progress, Longevity, and Quality of Life: Drugs as ‘Equipment for Your Health,’” Managerial and Decision Economics 28, nos. 4–5 (2007): 371392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichtenberg, F. R., “Benefits and Costs of Newer Drugs: An Update,” Managerial and Decision Economics 28, no. 4–5 (2007): 485490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
See Angell, , supra note 5, at 124.Google Scholar
The original copyright on Angell's book is 2004. Lichtenberg published results in 2001 in Lichtenberg, F., “Are the Benefits of Newer Drugs Worth Their Costs? Evidence from the 1996 MEPS”, Health Affairs 20, no. 5 (2001): 241251. Health Affairs is a leading journal in the medical field and so no competent scholar would have said that there is “no good reason” to think that newer drugs are better.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
See Angell, , supra note 5, at 130.Google Scholar
Rubin, P. H., “An Uncertain Diagnosis” Regulation 28, no. 2 (2005): 3439.Google Scholar
Wazana, A., “Physicians and the Pharmaceutical Industry: Is a Gift Ever Just a Gift?” Journal of the American Medical Association 283, no. 3 (2000): 373380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Id., at 378.Google Scholar
For an interesting approach, see the website <www.nofreelunch.org>, a website of a group of health care professionals who are opposed to pharmaceutical promotion. This website does have an excellent and apparently unbiased searchable bibliography on the issue.,+a+website+of+a+group+of+health+care+professionals+who+are+opposed+to+pharmaceutical+promotion.+This+website+does+have+an+excellent+and+apparently+unbiased+searchable+bibliography+on+the+issue.>Google Scholar
Chren, M.-Margaret and Landefeld, C. S., “Physicians' Behavior and Their Interactions with Drug Companies: A Controlled Study of Physicians Who Requested Additions to a Hospital Drug Formularies,” Journal of the American Medical Association 271, no. 9 (1994): 684689.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, P. H., “Letter to the Editor,” Journal of the American Medical Association 272, no. 5 (1994): 355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chren, M.-M. and Landefeld, C. S., “Reply,” Journal of the American Medical Association 272, no. 5 (1994): 355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
See Angell, , supra note 5, at 125.Google Scholar
The first published paper to point out the possible benefits was Masson, A. and Rubin, P. H., “Matching Prescription Drugs and Consumers: The Benefits of Direct Advertising,” New England Journal of Medicine 313, no. 8 (1985): 513515. For a recent article showing that benefits of this advertising are greater than costs, see Atherly, A. and Rubin, P. H., “The Cost-Effectiveness of Direct-to-Consumer Advertising for Prescription Drugs”, Medical Care Research and Review (2009) (in press.)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
National Health Council Statement, Direct-To-Consumer Prescription Drug Advertising, January 2002, available at <http://www.nationalhealthcouncil.org/advocacy/dtc.htm> (last visited June 8, 2009).+(last+visited+June+8,+2009).>Google Scholar
See Angell, , supra note 5, at 124.Google Scholar
This is discussed in great detail in my book, Rubin, P., Darwinian Politics: The Evolutionary Origin of Freedom (New Jersey: Rutgers University Press, 2002). I have applied it more specifically to economic beliefs in Rubin, P. H., “Folk Economics,” Southern Economic Journal 70, no. 1 (2003): 157171.Google Scholar
Caplan, B., The Myth of the Rational Voter (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2007): 3036.Google Scholar
Gowlett, J. A. J., “Tools—the Paleolithic Record,” in Jones, S., Martin, R. and Pilbeam, D., The Cambridge Encyclopedia of Human Evolution (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992): 350360.Google Scholar
Giaccotto, C., Santerre, R. E. and Vernon, J. A., “Drug Prices and Research and Development Investment Behavior in the Pharmaceutical Industry,” Journal of Law and Economics 48, no. 1 (2005): 195214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pinker, S., The Blank Slate: The Modern Denial of Human Nature (New York: Penguin, 2002).Google Scholar
Huddle, T. S., “Drug Reps and the University Medical Care Center: A Case for Management Rather than Prohibition,” Perspectives in Biology and Medicine 51, no. 2 (2008): 251260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kessel, R. A., “Price Discrimination in Medicine,” Journal of Law and Economics 1, no. 1 (1958): 2053.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
This point is often attributed to Friedman, M., “The Social Responsibility of Business Is to Increase Its Profits,” New York Times Magazine, September 13, 1970, at SM17.Google Scholar
Beauchamp, T. L. and Childress, J. F., Principles of Biomedical Ethics, 5th ed. (New York: Oxford University Press, 2001): at 28. Motives are considered again on page 50 for organ donors.Google Scholar
Trivers, R. L., “The Evolution of Reciprocal Altruism,” Quarterly Review of Biology 46, no. 1 (1971): 3557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trivers, R., “The Elements of a Scientific Theory of Self-Deception,” in LeCroy, D. and Moller, P., eds., Evolutionary Perspectives on Human Reproductive Behavior, Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences 907 (New York: Academy of Sciences Press, 2000): at 114131.Google Scholar