Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T21:50:30.700Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Property Rights and the Making of Christendom

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 April 2015

Extract

The contemporary turmoil in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union reflects acceptance by their populations that collectivism has failed them and that they have more to hope for from the property rights systems of the West. In economic terms, indeed, Western culture has depended fundamentally on these rights, and in recent years economic historians have been paying increasing attention to them. In doing so, however, they have encountered a problem which they are unable to solve within the terms of their own discipline: economics relies on the concept of agents who act only according to rational self-interest, but property rights as they can actually be found in history have often reflected forces that can only be described as altruism. Economics is now therefore having to take account of cultural factors in the formation of property rights, and the deeper these are studied the clearer the religious influence on them appears to be.

The earliest type of property must have been in the form of “exclusive communal” rights which, by establishing some form of defence against “outsiders,” prevented the latter from sharing in a resource which a tribe considered to belong to it. It is plausible that the historical shift from hunting and gathering to settled agriculture depended on the development of such rights. However, the extent to which they can lead to prosperity on their own is quite limited.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Center for the Study of Law and Religion at Emory University 1992

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. Hardin, , The Tragedy of the Commons, 162 Science 1243, 1244 (1968)Google ScholarPubMed.

2. North, , Institutions, Transaction Costs and Economic Growth, 25 Economic Inquiry 419, 421–22 (07 1987)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3. North, D., Structure and Change in Economic History 49, 47 (1981)Google Scholar.

4. Dawson, C., Progress and Religion 167 (1929)Google Scholar.

5. Finley, M.I., The Ancient Economy 29 (1973)Google Scholar.

6. Nicholas, B., An Introduction to Roman Law 153–57 (1962)Google Scholar. But see also Honore, T., Making Law Bind ch. 8 (1987)Google Scholar.

7. Matt. 20:15.

8. Gibbon, E., The Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire chs. 1-3 (17761778)Google Scholar.

9. Matt. 5:42; Luke 6:30.

10. Hengel, M., Property and Riches in the Early Church 34 (English, ed. 1973)Google Scholar.

11. Acts 18:3; I Thess. 4:12, 5:14.

12. Avila, C., Ownership: Early Christian Teaching 4558 (1983)Google Scholar. References to individual Church Fathers supra 57-115.

13. 1 Troeltsch, E., The Social Teaching of the Christian Churches 160 (English, trans. 1931)Google Scholar.

14. Dawson, C., Religion and the Rise of Western Culture 57 (1950)Google Scholar.

15. 3 Newman, J.H., Historical Sketches 410 (1876)Google Scholar.

16. C. Dawson supra note 14 at 102, 170. Also, see Dawson, C.The Making of Europe 212–13 (1932)Google Scholar.

17. Pirenne, H., Medieval Cities 158 (English, trans. 1925)Google Scholar.

18. Schlatter, R., Private Property: The History of an Idea 7576 (1951)Google Scholar.

19. Samuelsson, K., Religion and Economic Action (English, trans. 1961)Google Scholar.

20. Tawney, R.H., Religion and the Rise of Capitalism 249 (1926)Google Scholar.

21. Figgis, J.N., The Political Aspects of St. Augustine's City of God 99 (1921)Google Scholar.

22. Quoted material in K. Samuelsson, supra note 19, at 12-14.

23. Landes, D., The Unbound Prometheus 1516 (1969)Google Scholar.

24. C. Dawson, supra note 4, at 178-79.

25. Sombart, W., The Jews and Modern Capitalism ch. 6 (English, trans. 1913)Google Scholar.

26. North, D. & Thomas, R., The Rise of the Western World 142 (1973)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27. Id. at 157.

28. Locke, J., Two Treatises on Government II, § 124 (1690)Google Scholar. See also supra §§ 87, 94, 123.

29. White, L. Jr., Machina Ex Deo 64 (1968)Google Scholar.

30. Id. at 65.

31. Id. at 64.

32. Id. at 65.

33. Dawson, C., Medieval Religion 5794 (1934)Google Scholar.

34. In Specificatio, whereby a right could be obtained in some cases by the maker of something new out of existing materials. See Jolowicz, H.F. & Nicholas, B., Historical Introduction to Roman Law 143 (1972)Google Scholar; see also B. Nicholas supra note 6, at 136.

35. Madison, J., The Federalist No. 43 (1788)Google Scholar.

36. Interestingly, Jefferson thought the same until convinced otherwise by personal experience of the working of the Patent system. See Federico, , Operation of the Patent Act of 1790, 18 Journal of the Patent Office Society 237 (1936)Google Scholar.

37. Marx, K. & Engels, F., The Communist Manifesto 85 (Penguin London ed. 1967)Google Scholar.

38. On the Hundredth Anniversary of Rerum Novarum, Centesimus Annus, Encyclical Letter (May 1991).

39. Usher, D., The Economic Prerequisite to Democracy 78 (1981)Google Scholar.

40. Matt. 13:29.

41. 2 Mill, J.S., Principles of Political Economy ch. I, § 3 (1848)Google Scholar.

42. Buchanan, J.M. & Tullock, G., The Calculus of Consent 289 (1962)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

43. Olson, M., The Rise and Decline of Nations 144–45 (1982)Google Scholar.

44. Barzel, Y., Economic Analysis of Property Rights (1989)Google Scholar.

45. D. Usher, supra note 39, at 8.

46. Munzer, S., A Theory of Property 469 (1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

47. Becker, L., Property Rights 99 (1977)Google Scholar.

48. Id. at 117.

49. Waldron, J., The Right to Private Property 444 (1988)Google Scholar.

50. Id. at 438-39.

51. Matt. 10:16.