Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-03T19:18:22.292Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The revolving door, state connections, and inequality of influence in the financial sector

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 January 2019

Elise S. Brezis
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University, Israel and Fondation pour les études et recherches sur le développement international (Ferdi), Clermont-Ferrand, France
Joël Cariolle*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University, Israel and Fondation pour les études et recherches sur le développement international (Ferdi), Clermont-Ferrand, France
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

This paper shows that the revolving door generates inequality of influence between financial firms and creates economic distortions. We first develop a theoretical model, introducing the notion of “bureaucratic capital” and stressing how the revolving door generates inequality in bureaucratic capital leading to inequality in profits. Then this prediction is tested, using a new database that tracks the revolving door process involving the 20 biggest US “diversified banks.” We show that regulators who supply a large stock of bureaucratic capital are more likely to be hired by the top five banks. We also develop indices of the inequality of influence between banks. We show that banks in the top revenue quintile concentrate around 80% of revolving door movements. Goldman Sachs appears as the prime beneficiary of this process, capturing approximately 30% of the total stock of bureaucratic capital.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Afonso, G., Santos, J. and Traina, J. (2014), ‘Do “Too-Big-To-Fail” Banks Take on More Risk?Federal Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, 20(2): 118.Google Scholar
Ban, P. and You, H. Y. (2017), ‘Presence and Influence in Lobbying: Evidence from Dodd–Frank’, working paper. Accepted in Business & Politics.Google Scholar
Bhattacharya, S., Boot, A. W. and Thakor, A. V. (1998), ‘The Economics of Bank Regulation’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 30(4): 745770.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J. and Kiyotaki, N. (1987), ‘Monopolistic Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand’, American Economic Review, 77(4): 647666.Google Scholar
Boubakri, N., Guedhami, O., Mishra, D. and Saffar, W. (2012), ‘Political Connections and the Cost of Equity Capital’, Journal of Corporate Finance, 18: 541599.Google Scholar
Brezis, E. S. (2017), ‘Legal Conflicts of Interest of the Revolving Door’, Journal of Macroeconomics, 52: 175188.Google Scholar
Brezis, E. S. and Weiss, A. (1997), ‘Conscientious Regulation and Post-regulatory Employment Restrictions’, European Journal of Political Economy, 13: 517536.Google Scholar
Chan, W. K. K. (1977), ‘Bureaucratic Capital and Chou Hsüeh-hsi in Late Ch'ing China’, Modern Asian Studies, 11: 427439.Google Scholar
Dellisanti, D. and Wagner, R. (2018), ‘Bankruptcies, Bailouts, and Some Political Economy of Corporate Reorganization’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 14(5): 119.Google Scholar
Faccio, M., Masulis, M. W. and McConnell, J. J. (2006), ‘Political Connections and Corporate Bailouts’, Journal of Finance, 61(6): 25972635.Google Scholar
Flannery, M. J. and Sorescu, S. M. (1996), ‘Evidence of Bank Market Discipline in Subordinated Debenture Yields: 1983–1991’, Journal of Finance, 51(4): 13471377.Google Scholar
Hellman, J. and Kaufmann, D. (2004), ‚The Inequality of Influence’, in Kornai, J. and Rose-Ackerman, S. (eds), Building a Trustworthy State, New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp.100118.Google Scholar
Henning, P. (2010), ‘The Revolving Door and SEC enforcement’, New York Times, 8 April.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D. and Vicente, P. C. (2011), ‘Legal Corruption’, Economics & Politics, 23(2):195219.Google Scholar
Kroszner, R. and Stratmann, T. (1998), ‘Interest-Group Competition and the Organization of Congress’, American Economic Review, 88(5): 11631187.Google Scholar
Laffont, J. J. and Tirole, J.. (1996), A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Lucca, D., Seru, A. and Trebbi, F. (2014), ‘The Revolving Door and Worker Flows in Banking Regulation’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 65: 1732.Google Scholar
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) (2009), ‘Revolving Doors, Accountability and Transparency’, Public Governance Committee, Paris.Google Scholar
Peltzman, S. (1976), ‘Toward a More General Theory of Regulation’, Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2): 211240.Google Scholar
Romer, P. M. (1990), ‘Endogenous Technological Change’, Journal of Political Economy, 98(5): 71103.Google Scholar
Santos, J. (2014), ‘Evidence from the Bond Market on Banks “Too-Big-To-Fail” Subsidy’, Federal Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, 20(2): 2939.Google Scholar
Smallberg, M. (2013), ‘Big Business Offer Revolving Door Rewards’, Project on Government Oversight (POGO), 21 March.Google Scholar
Sorkin, A. R. (2011), ‘Revolving Door at SEC is Hurdle to Crisis Cleanup’, New York Times, 1 August.Google Scholar
Stein, J. (2018), ‘Many Lawmakers and Aides who Crafted Financial Regulations after the 2008 Crisis Now Work for Wall Street’, Washington Post, 7 September.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. (1971), ‘The Theory of Economic Regulation’, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1): 321.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. (1985), ‘Credit Markets and the Control of Capital’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 17(2): 133152.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. and Weiss, A. (1981), ‘Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information’, American Economic Review, 71(3): 393410.Google Scholar
Transparency International (2011), ‘Cabs for Hire? Fixing the Revolving Door between Government and Business’, Transparency International UK.Google Scholar
United States Securities and Exchange Commission Office of Inspector General (2010), ‘Investigation of the SEC's Response to Concerns Regarding Robert Allen Stanford's Alleged Ponzi Scheme’, Case No. OIG-526, 31 March.Google Scholar
Werner, R. A. (2014), ‘How Do Banks Create Money, and Why Can Other Firms Not Do the Same?International Review of Financial Analysis, 36: 7177.Google Scholar
Zingales, L. (2015), ‘Presidential Address: Does Finance Benefit Society?Journal of Finance, 70(4): 13271363.Google Scholar
Zingales, L. (2017), ‘Towards a Political Theory of the Firm’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 31(3): 113130.Google Scholar