Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-02T19:19:24.954Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Liberalism after Burczak: redistribution, worker self-management and the market process

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 August 2010

DAVID EMANUEL ANDERSSON*
Affiliation:
Institute of Public Affairs Management, National Sun Yat-Sen University, Kaohsiung, Taiwan

Abstract:

In Socialism after Hayek, Theodore Burczak uses Hayekian insights to argue in favor of a socialist society with real markets, but also with wealth redistribution and prohibition of wage labor. In so doing, he offers not only a socialist vision but also asks questions that may challenge Hayekian liberals to reformulate their institutional analyses. A critical assessment that combines Austrian and institutional theories leads to the conclusion that some redistributive policies may enhance the knowledge-disseminating function of markets, but that a market order that is limited to worker-managed firms diminishes the knowledge dissemination properties of the market process.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The JOIE Foundation 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Andersson, D. E. (2008a), ‘The Double-edged Nature of the Hayekian Knowledge Problem: Systemic Tendencies in Markets and Science’, Studies in Emergent Order, 1: 5172.Google Scholar
Andersson, D. E. (2008b), Property Rights, Consumption and the Market Process, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S. and Gintis, H. (1986), Democracy and Capitalism, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Burczak, T. A. (2006), Socialism after Hayek, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
diZerega, G. (1989), ‘Democracy as a Spontaneous Order’, Critical Review, 3: 206240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
diZerega, G. (2008), ‘New Directions in Emergent Order Research’, Studies in Emergent Order, 1: 123.Google Scholar
Ellerman, D. (1992), Property and Contract in Economics, Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Foldvary, F. E. (2002), ‘Small Group, Multi-Level Democracy: Implications of Austrian Public Choice for Governance Structure’, Review of Austrian Economics, 15 (2/3): 161174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, K., Foss, N. J., Klein, P. G., and Klein, S. K. (2007), ‘The Entrepreneurial Organization of Heterogeneous Capital’, Journal of Management Studies, 44: 11651186.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1937), ‘Economics and Knowledge’, Economica, 4: 3354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1945), ‘The Use of Knowledge in Society’, American Economic Review, 35: 519530.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1952), The Sensory Order, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1960), The Constitution of Liberty, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1979), Law, Legislation and Liberty, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1999), Economics and Utopia: Why the Learning Economy Is Not the End of History, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Horwitz, S. (2007), ‘Leftists for Hayek: What Happens When a Socialist Applies the Insights of Austrian Economics’, Reason (July).Google Scholar
Jones, E. (1981), The European Miracle: Environments, Economies and Geopolitics in the History of Europe and Asia, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. ([1937]1973), ‘The General Theory of Employment’, in Moggridge, D. (ed.), The General Theory and After Part II: Defense and Development, New York: St Martin's Press, pp. 109123.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. M. (1973), Competition and Entrepreneurship, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. M. (1989), Discovery, Capitalism and Distributive Justice, Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1921), Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Koppl, R. (2002), Big Players and the Economic Theory of Expectations, Basingstoke: Palgrave.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lachmann, L. M. (1976), ‘From Mises to Shackle: An Essay on Austrian Economics and the Kaleidic Society’, Journal of Economic Literature, 14 (1): 5462.Google Scholar
Lachmann, L. M. (1986), The Market as an Economic Process, Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Lange, O. and Taylor, F. M. (1948), On the Economic Theory of Socialism, Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
Nozick, R. (1974), Anarchy, State, and Utopia, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
O'Driscoll, G. P. Jr. and Rizzo, M.. ([1985]1996), The Economics of Time and Ignorance, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1965), The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prychitko, D. L. (1998), ‘Hayekian Socialism: Rethinking Burczak, Ellerman, and Kirzner’, Rethinking Marxism, 10 (2): 7585.Google Scholar
Samuels, W. J. (1981), ‘Maximization of Wealth as Justice: An Essay on Posnerian Law and Economics as Policy Analysis’, Texas Law Review, 60: 147172.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Storr, V. H. (2007), ‘Review of Theodore A. Burczak's Socialism after Hayek’, Review of Austrian Economics, 20: 313316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar