Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T20:03:17.418Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Individualistic values, institutional trust, and interventionist attitudes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 January 2017

HANS PITLIK*
Affiliation:
Austrian Institute of Economic Research, Vienna, Austria
MARTIN RODE*
Affiliation:
Departamento de Economía, Campus Universitario, 31009, Universidad de Navarra, Pamplona, Spain

Abstract

A popular explanation for economic development is that ‘individualistic values’ provide a mind-set that is favorable to the creation of growth-promoting institutions. The present paper investigates the relationship between individualistic values and personal attitudes toward government intervention. We consider two key components of an individualistic culture to be particularly relevant for attitude formation: self-direction (‘social’ individualism) and self-determination (‘economic’ individualism). Results indicate that both are negatively associated with interventionist attitudes. Effects of self-direction are much weaker though, than self-determination. Moreover, the effects of self-direction are mitigated through higher trust in the state and lower confidence in companies, while that is not the case for self-determination values. We conclude that especially economic individualism supports attitudes conducive to the formation of formal market-friendly institutions.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. (2012), Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty, New York, NY: Random House.Google Scholar
Aghion, P., Algan, Y., Cahuc, P. and Shleifer, A. (2010), ‘Regulation and Distrust’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125 (3): 10151049.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A. and Angeletos, G. M. (2005), ‘Fairness and Redistribution’, American Economic Review, 95 (4): 960980.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A. and Giuliano, P. (2015), ‘Culture and Institutions’, Journal of Economic Literature, 53 (4): 898944.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Algan, Y. and Cahuc, P. (2013), ‘Trust and Growth’, Annual Review of Economics, 5: 521549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angrist, J.D. and Pischke, J.S. (2008). Mostly harmless econometrics, An empiricist's companion. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, R. (2001), ‘Individualism, Collectivism, and Economic Development’, The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 573: 5784 (2).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bandura, A. (1977), ‘Self-Efficacy: Toward a Unifying Theory of Behavioral Change’, Psychological Review, 84 (2): 191215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barker, D. C. and Carman, C. J. (2000), ‘The Spirit of Capitalism? Religious Doctrine, Values, and Economic Attitude Constructs’, Political Behavior, 22 (1): 127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bavetta, S. and Navarra, P. (2012), ‘Freedom and Redistribution’, Rivista di Politica Economica, 3: 2949.Google Scholar
Bénabou, R. and Tirole, J. (2006), ‘Belief in a Just World and Redistributive Politics’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121 (2): 699746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berggren, N. and Elinder, M. (2012), ‘Is Tolerance good or bad for Growth?’, Public Choice, 150 (1): 283308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bird, R. M. (1971), ‘Wagner's Law of expanding state Activity’, Public Finance 26 (1): 126.Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, C. (2010), ‘How Does Social Trust Lead to Better Governance? An Attempt to Separate Electoral and Bureaucratic Mechanisms’, Public Choice, 144 (1): 323346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bjørnskov, C. (2012), ‘How Does Social Trust Affect Economic Growth?’, Southern Economic Journal, 78 (4): 13461368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bjørnskov, C. and Paldam, M. (2012), ‘The Spirits of Capitalism and Socialism. A cross-country Study of Ideology’, Public Choice, 150 (3): 469498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boettke, P.J., Coyne, C.J. and Leeson, P.T. (2008). ‘Institutional Stickiness and the New Development Economics’, The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 67 (2): 331358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, C. and Posner, D. N. (1998), ‘Social Capital: Explaining its Origins and Effects on Government Performance’, British Journal of Political Science, 28 (4): 686695.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brambor, T., Clark, W. R. and Golder, M. (2006), ‘Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analyses’, Political Analysis, 14 (1): 6382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chadi, A. and Krapf, M. (2015), ‘The Protestant Fiscal Ethic: Religious Confession and Euro Skepticism in Germany’, IAAEU Discussion Paper Series in Economics No. 07/2015.Google Scholar
Clausen, B., Kraay, A. and Nyiri, Z. (2011), ‘Corruption and Confidence in Public Institutions: Evidence from a Global Survey’, World Bank Economic Review, 25 (2): 212249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D'Orlando, F., Ferrante, F. and Ruiu, G. (2010), ‘Culturally-based Beliefs and Labour Market Institutions’, Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche Università di Cassino Working Paper, 2/2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daniele, G. and Geys, B. (2015), ‘Interpersonal Trust and Welfare State support’, European Journal of Political Economy, 39: 112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Haan, J., Jong-A-Pin, R. and Mierau, J. (2013). Do budgetary institutions mitigate the common pool problem? New empirical evidence for the EU, Public Choice, 156 (3), 423441.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, L. (2016), ‘Individualism and Economic Development: Evidence from Rainfall Data’, Kyklos, 69 (3): 426470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimitrova-Grajzl, V.P, Grajzl, P. and Guse, A.J (2011). ‘Trust, Perceptions of Corruption, and Demand for Regulation: Evidence from Post-Socialist Countries’, Journal of Socio-Economics, 41 (3): 292303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, S. (1988), ‘Structure and Consistency in public Opinion: The Role of core Beliefs and Values’, American Journal of Political Science, 32 (2): 416440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, S. and Zaller, J. (1992). The Political Culture of Ambivalence: Ideological Responses to the Welfare State, American Journal of Political Science, 36 (1): 268307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fevre, R. (2016), Individualism and Inequality: The Future of Work and Politics, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freedom House (2016), Freedom in the World Report 2016. Anxious Dictators, Wavering Democracies: Global Freedom under Pressure, Washington D.C.: Freedom House.Google Scholar
Gorodnichenko, Y. and Roland, G. (2011), ‘Which Dimensions of Culture Matter for Long-Run Growth?’, American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 101 (3): 492498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorodnichenko, Y. and Roland, G. (2011b), ‘Culture, Institutions and the Wealth of Nations’, University of California Berkeley Working Paper, 01/2011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorodnichenko, Y. and Roland, G. (2015a), ‘Understanding the Individualism-Collectivism Cleavage and its Effects: Lessons from Cultural Psychology’, XVIth Congress of the International Economic Association.Google Scholar
Gorodnichenko, Y. and Roland, G. (2015b), ‘Culture, Institutions, and Democratization’, NBER Working Paper 04/2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. (1994), ‘Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies’, Journal of Political Economy, 102 (5): 912950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grönlund, K. and Setälä, M. (2012), ‘In Honest Officials We Trust: Institutional Confidence in Europe’, American Review of Public Administration, 42 (5): 523542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P. and Zingales, L. (2006), ‘Does Culture Affect Economic Outcomes?’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20 (2): 2348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gwartney, J., Lawson, R. and Hall, J. (2016), Economic Freedom of the World. 2016 Annual Report, Vancouver, CA: The Fraser Institute.Google Scholar
Haidt, J. (2012), The Righteous Mind: Why good People are divided by Politics and Religion, New York, NY: Random House.Google Scholar
Hansen, C. W. (2013), ‘Economic Growth and Individualism: The Role of Informal Institutions’, Economics Letters, 118 (2): 378380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrison, L. E. (2013), Jews, Confucians, and Protestants: Cultural Capital and the End of Multiculturalism, Lanham, MA: Rowman & Littlefield.Google Scholar
Hofstede, G. (2011), ‘Dimensionalizing Cultures: The Hofstede Model in Context’, Online Readings in Psychology and Culture, 2 (1): 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Inglehart, R. and Welzel, C. (2010), ‘Changing Mass Priorities: The Link between Modernization and Democracy’, Perspectives on Politics, 8: 551567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jenssen, M. C. W. and Mendys-Kamphorst, E. (2004), ‘The Price of a Price: On the Crowding out and in of Social Norms’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 55 (3): 377395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jottier, D. and Heyndels, B. (2012), ‘Does Social Capital increase Political Accountability? An empirical test for Flemish municipalities’, Public Choice, 150 (3): 731744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kouba, L. and Pitlik, H. (2014). ‘I wanna live my life: Locus of Control and Support for the Welfare State’, MENDELU Working Papers in Business and Economics, 07/2014.Google Scholar
Kovac, M. and Spruk, R. (2016), ‘Institutional Development, Transaction Costs and Economic Growth: Evidence from a Cross-country Investigation’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 12 (1): 129159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kyriacou, A. (2016). ‘Individualism–Collectivism, Governance and Economic Development’, European Journal of Political Economy, 42: 91104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamartina, S. and Zaghini, A. (2011), ‘Increasing Public Expenditure: Wagner's Law in OECD Countries’, German Economic Review, 12 (2): 149164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lavoie, D. and Chamlee-Wright, E. (2000), Culture and Enterprise: The Development, Representation and Morality of Business, London, UK: Routledge.Google Scholar
Licht, A. N., Goldschmidt, C. and Schwartz, S. H. (2005), ‘Culture, Law, and Corporate Governance’, International Review of Law and Economics, 25 (2): 229255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Licht, A. N., Goldschmidt, C. and Schwartz, S. H. (2007), ‘Culture Rules: The Foundations of the Rule of Law and Other Norms of Governance’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 35 (4): 659688.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maseland, R. and van Hoorn, A. (2011), ‘Why Muslims like Democracy yet have so little of it’, Public Choice, 147 (3): 481496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mathers, R. L. and Williamson, C. R. (2011), ‘Cultural Context: Explaining the Productivity of Capitalism’, Kyklos, 64 (2): 231252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, J. (1990). The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Moulton, B. (1990), ‘An Illustration of a Pitfall in Estimating the Effects of Aggregate Variables in Micro Units’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 72 (2): 334338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nannestad, P. (2008), ‘What have we Learned About Generalized Trust, if Anything?’, Annual Review of Political Science, 11: 413436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oyserman, D. and Lee, S. W. (2008), ‘Does Culture Influence What and How we Think? Effects of Priming Individualism and Collectivism’, Psychological Bulletin, 134 (2): 311342.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Paldam, M. and Gundlach, E. (2008), ‘Two Views on Institutions and Development: The Grand Transition vs the Primacy of Institutions’, Kyklos, 61 (1): 65100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pitlik, H. and Kouba, L. (2015), ‘Does Social Distrust always Lead to a Stronger Support for Government Intervention?’, Public Choice, 163 (3): 355377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, R. (1993), Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, Princeton, NY: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Robbins, B. G. (2012), ‘A Blessing and a Curse? Political Institutions in the Growth and Decay of Generalized Trust: A Cross-National Panel Analysis, 1980–2009’, PLOS ONE, April 25, DOI: 10.1371/journal.pone.0035120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rode, M. and Coll, S. (2012), ‘Economic Freedom and Growth. Which Policies matter the most?’, Constitutional Political Economy, 23 (2): 95133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotter, J. B. (1966), ‘Generalized Expectancies for Internal versus External Control of Reinforcement’, Psychological Monographs: General and Applied, 80 (1): 128.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schwartz, S. H. (2004), ‘Mapping and Interpreting Cultural Differences around the World’, in Vinken, H., Soeters, J. and Ester, P. (eds.), Comparing Cultures, Dimensions of Culture in a Comparative Perspective, Leiden: Brill, pp. 4373.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, A. (2004), ‘Does Competition Destroy Ethical Behavior?’, American Economic Review, 94 (2): 414418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svallfors, S. (2013), ‘Government Quality, Egalitarianism, and Attitudes to Taxes and Social Spending: A European Comparison’, European Political Science Review, 5 (3): 363380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Storr, V. H. (2013). Understanding the Culture of Markets, London, UK: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swank, D. (1996), ‘Culture, Institutions, and Economic Growth: Theory, Recent Evidence, and the Role of Communitarian Polities’, American Journal of Political Science, 40 (3): 660679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tabellini, G. (2008), ‘Institutions and Culture’, Journal of the European Economic Association, 6 (2–3): 255294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tabellini, G. (2010), ‘Culture and Institutions: Economic Development in the Regions of Europe’, Journal of the European Economic Association, 8 (4): 677716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tirole, J. (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
van Hoorn, A. (2014), ‘Individualism and the Cultural Roots of Management Practices’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 99: 5368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Hoorn, A. (2015), ‘Individualist-Collectivist Culture and Trust Radius: A Multilevel Approach’, Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 46 (2): 269276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, M. (1930), The Protestant Ethic and the Rise of Capitalism, Crows Nest, AU: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Williamson, C. R. (2009), ‘Informal Institutions Rule: Institutional Arrangements and Economic Performance’, Public Choice, 139 (3): 371387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, C. R. and Kerekes, C. B. (2011), ‘Securing Private Property: The Relative Importance of Formal versus Informal Institutions’, Journal of Law and Economics, 54 (3): 537572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (2000), ‘The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead’, Journal of Economic Literature, 38 (3): 595613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yoo, D. and Steckel, R. H. (2016), ‘Property Rights and Economic Development: The Legacy of Japanese colonial Institutions’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 12 (3): 623650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zak, P. J. and Knack, S. (2001), ‘Trust and Growth’, The Economic Journal, 111 (470): 295321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar