Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T20:38:44.007Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Hayek on tacit knowledge

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 May 2010

FUAT OĞUZ*
Affiliation:
Başkent University, Ankara, Turkey

Abstract:

This paper discusses the place of ‘tacit knowledge’ in Hayek's writings. How did Hayek understand tacit knowledge? How did his understanding change through time? I address these questions and follow the change in Hayek's works from skills and techniques of thought in the 1930s to the use of ‘tacit knowledge’ in the1960s. Hayek uses Polanyi's concept in many writings, but remains short of approving its implications. The paper emphasizes that while Hayek was quite aware of the differences between tacit knowing and knowing-how, he was not keen to stress the divergence. In the end, I offer some potential explanations for this preference.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The JOIE Foundation 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ancori, B., Bureth, A., and Cohendet, P. (2000), ‘The Economics of Knowledge: The Debate about Codification and Tacit Knowledge’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 9 (2): 255287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bladel, J. (2005), ‘Against Polanyi-centrism: Hayek and the Re-emergence of “Spontaneous Order”’, Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 8 (4): 1530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Butos, W. N. (1997), ‘Hayek and Rational Expectations’, in Keizer, W., Tieben, B., and van Zijp, R. (eds.), Austrian Economics in Debate, London: Routledge, pp. 220242.Google Scholar
Butos, W. N. and McQuade, T. J. (2002), ‘Mind, Market, and Institutions: The Knowledge Problem in Hayek's Thought’, in Birner, J., Garrouste, P., and Aimar, T. (eds.), F.A. Hayek a Political Economist, London and New York: Routledge, pp. 113133.Google Scholar
Caldwell, B. (1997), ‘Hayek and Socialism’, Journal of Economic Literature, 35 (4): 18561890.Google Scholar
Caldwell, B. (2004), Hayek's Challenge, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Caldwell, B. (2004a), ‘Some Reflections on F. A. Hayek's The Sensory Order’, Journal of Bioeconomics, 6 (3): 239254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowan, R, David, P. A., and Foray, D. (2000), ‘The Explicit Economics of Knowledge Codification and Tacitness’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 9 (2): 211253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dreyfus, H. L. (1991), Being-in-the-World, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Fleetwood, S. (1995), Hayek's Political Economy, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Gordon, D. (1986), ‘Hermeneutics and Austrian Economics’, Mises Institute, Auburn, available at http://www.mises.org/etexts/hermeneutics.asp.Google Scholar
Gray, J. (1982), ‘F. A. Hayek and the Rebirth of Classical Liberalism’, Literature of Liberty, 5 (4): 19101.Google Scholar
Gray, J. (1988), ‘Hayek, the Scottish School, and Contemporary Economics’, in Winston, G. C. and Teichraeber III, R. F. (eds.), The Boundaries of Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 5370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grondin, J. (1994), Introduction to Philosophical Hermeneutics, tr: J. Wensheimer, Yale.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1941), Pure Theory of Capital, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1948a), ‘The Use of Knowledge in Society’, in his Individualism and Economic Order, Chicago: Chicago University Press, pp. 7791.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1948b), ‘Economics and Knowledge’, in his Individualism and Economic Order, Chicago: Chicago University Press, pp. 3356.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1948c), ‘The Socialist Calculation II: The State of the Debate’, in his Individualism and Economic Order, Chicago: Chicago University Press, pp. 148180.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1952), The Sensory Order, London: Routledge & Paul Kegan.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1952a), The Counterrevolution of Science, Indianapolis: LibertyFund.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1960), Constitution of Liberty, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1967), ‘Rules, Perception, and Intelligibility’, in his Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, pp. 4365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1967a), ‘Degrees of Explanation’, in his Studies, pp. 3–21.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1973), Law, Legislation and Liberty: Rules and Order, vol. 1, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1978), ‘Competition as a Discovery Procedure’, in his New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics, and the History of Ideas, Chicago: Chicago University Press, pp. 179190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1978a), ‘The Primacy of Abstract’, in his New Studies, pp. 35–49.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1979), Law, Legislation and Liberty: The Political Order of a Free People, vol. 3, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1988), Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism, Bartley III, W. W. (ed.), Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoppe, H. H. (1994), ‘Comment on Don Lavoie’, Presentation at the 1994 Mont Pelerin Society Meeting, available at http://www.hanshoppe.com/publications/hoppe_lavoie.pdf.Google Scholar
Hoppe, H. H. (1996), ‘Socialism: A Property or Knowledge Problem’, Review of Austrian Economics, 9 (1): 147154.Google Scholar
Ioannides, S. (2000), ‘Austrian Economics, Socialism and Impure Forms of Economic Organization’, Review of Political Economy, 12 (1): 4572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobs, S. (1999), ‘Michael Polanyi's Theory of Spontaneous Orders’, Review of Austrian Economics, 11 (1): 111127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, J. and Wilson, W. (1987), An Incomplete Education, New York: Ballantine Press.Google Scholar
Khalil, E. (2002), ‘Information, Knowledge and the Close of Hayek’ System’, Eastern Economic Journal, 28 (3): 319341.Google Scholar
Lavoie, D. (1985), National Economic Planning: What is Left?, Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.Google Scholar
Lavoie, D. (1995), ‘The Market as a Procedure for the Discovery and Conveyance of Inarticulate Knowledge’, in Prychitko, D. L. (ed.), Individuals, Institutions, Interpretations, Avebury.Google Scholar
Merleau-Ponty, M. (1962), Phenomenology of Perception, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. (1998), ‘Economics, Science, and Knowledge: Polanyi vs. Hayek’, Tradition and Discovery, 25 (1): 2942.Google Scholar
Nightingale, P. (2003), ‘If Nelson and Winter are only Half Right about Tacit Knowledge, Which Half?’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 12 (2): 149183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Driscoll, G. and Rizzo, M. (1996), The Economics of Time and Ignorance, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Polanyi, M. (1958), Personal Knowledge, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Polanyi, M. (1969), Knowing and Being, Greene, M. (ed.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Rizzo, M. (2005), ‘The Problem of Moral Dirigisme’, NYU Journal of Law and Liberty, 1 (2): 781835.Google Scholar
Rothbard, M. (1989), ‘The Hermeneutical Invasion of Philosophy and Economics’, Review of Austrian Economics, 3 (1): 4559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothbard, M. (1991), ‘The End of Socialism and the Calculation Debate Revisited’, Review of Austrian Economics, 5 (2): 5176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ryle, G. (1949), The Concept of Mind, New York: Barnes & Noble.Google Scholar
Sabooglu, M. and Langlois, R. N. (2001), ‘Knowledge, and Meliorism in the Evolutionary Theory of F. A. Hayek’, in Dopfer, K. (ed.), The Evolutionary Economics: Program and Scope, Dordrecht: Kluwer, pp. 231251.Google Scholar
Scott, W. (1971), ‘Tacit Knowing and the Concept of Mind’, The Philosophical Quarterly, 21 (82): 2235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, B. (1988), ‘Knowing How vs. Knowing That’, in Nyiri, J. C. and Smith, B. (eds.), Practical Knowledge, New York: Croom Helm, pp. 116.Google Scholar
Smith, B. (1997), ‘The Connectionist Mind: A Study of Hayekian Psychology’, in Frowen, S. F. (ed.), Hayek: Economist and Social Philosopher, New York: St Martin Press, pp. 929.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanberg, V. (1991), ‘Spontaneous Market Order and Social Rules: A Critical Examination of F. A. Hayek's Theory of Cultural Evolution’, in Wood, J. C. and Woods, R. N. (eds.), Friedrich A. Hayek: Critical Assessments, 4: 177201.Google Scholar
Vanberg, V. (1994), ‘Hayek's Legacy and the Future of Liberal Thought: Rational Liberalism versus Evolutionary Agnosticism’, Cato Journal, 14 (2): 179199.Google Scholar
Vaughn, K. (1994), Austrian Economics in America, New York: Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yeager, L. (1997), ‘Calculation and Knowledge: Let's Write Finis’, Review of Austrian Economics, 10 (1): 133136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zappia, C. (1996), ‘The Notion of Private Information in a Modern Perspective: A Reappraisal of Hayek's Contribution’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 3 (1): 107132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar