Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-p9bg8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T07:42:06.542Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Conceptualizing the fiscal state: implications for sub-Saharan Africa

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 February 2023

Matilde Jeppesen
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Aarhus University, Aarhus, Denmark
Ane Karoline Bak
Affiliation:
Danish Centre for Welfare studies, University of Southern Denmark, Odense, Denmark
Anne Mette Kjær*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Aarhus University, Aarhus, Denmark
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper contributes to the debate on domestic revenue mobilization and state-building in the Global South by exploring the concept of fiscal states and the common assumption that such states are present in sub-Saharan Africa. We systematically review the diverse understandings of the fiscal state across relevant literatures to revisit its conceptualization. On that basis, we define the fiscal state as a state whose public revenue base is dominated by tax revenue and loans, and where the relationship between taxation and external and domestic borrowing is balanced and thereby sustainable and characterized by interdependence. We distinguish the fiscal state conceptually from the tax, debt, and rentier states and present a typology of these ideal state types, discussing illustrative empirical examples of different states in sub-Saharan Africa. These illustrate that not all sub-Saharan states can be categorized as fiscal states. This is important because when African states are regarded as fiscal states, assumptions are made about their economic structures; yet, to the extent that these are absent, fiscal policy reforms are unlikely to carry long-term positive effects.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - SA
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike IGO licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the same Creative Commons licence is included and the original work is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial re-use.
Copyright
Copyright © UNU-WIDER, 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Millennium Economics Ltd

1. Introduction

The term ‘fiscal state’ used to be a prerogative of industrialized nation states with a specific narrative aimed at explaining why Europe spearheaded state formation. Within the past two decades, this has changed. Mentions of the fiscal state in scholarly work have increased across disciplines, and the term is now applied in works on state-building globally, including in the Global South. This turn in the literature has occurred in parallel with the emergence of an increased focus in the international development community on how low-income countries can tax more and better. Programmes to support taxation are typically formulated based on an implicit assumption that the prerequisites for building or advancing fiscal states exist in low-income countries. This paper sets out to clarify the defining features of a fiscal state as a first step towards interrogating these assumptions.

The body of literature on fiscal states within the field of economic history is substantial (e.g. Bonney, Reference Bonney1999; Dincecco, Reference Dincecco2011; Johnson and Koyama, Reference Johnson and Koyama2014; O'Brien, Reference O'Brien2011; Yun-Casalilla, Reference Yun-Casalilla, Yun-Casalilla, O'Brien and Comin2012), but despite frequent application of the term and continuous discussion of ‘the fiscal state in Africa’ (e.g. Albers et al., Reference Albers, Jerven and Suesse2020; Moore, Reference Moore2021; Waris, Reference Waris2018), there is little focus on (re)assessing and (re)defining the concept as it has entered new realms. Few scholars have directly examined whether states in low-income countries have developed from tax states (provided that they even qualified as such) to fiscal states. It has not been explicitly discussed what such a development would look like in contemporary lower-income countries or what the defining attributes of a fiscal state are.

This is problematic in two ways. For researchers studying the emergence and consequences of fiscal states, proper conceptualization is key. While concepts that are properly delimited theoretically and empirically have intrinsic value, there is of course also instrumental value. To explain the emergence of a phenomenon, the phenomenon itself, and the subsequent effects hereof, we need to be able to disentangle and conceptually distinguish causes, concept, and effects from each other. While some lessons may be learned from the early European emergence of fiscal states and state-building efforts, the fiscality of many contemporary states has developed and changed under different conditions. Consequently, we need a fresh look at the concept of fiscal states to avoid conflating cause, concept, and effect. Otherwise, such conflation would limit our ability to empirically understand and examine these factors.

Second, the lack of explicit conceptualization of the contemporary fiscal state is problematic in a development policy context. Fiscal policy recommendations are often formulated in a way that seems to take for granted that African states are fiscal states and assumptions are made about their economic structures. Yet, if such assumptions are mistakenly made, effective tax policy implementation and fruitful yields are very unlikely, regardless of any ‘political will’ to tax more. Recognizing the absence or presence of fiscal states is a first step towards explaining why significant efforts to reform the tax system, including the implementation of VAT and administrative reforms, have not substantially increased tax revenue in many African countries (Fjeldstad, Reference Fjeldstad2014; Fossat and Bua, Reference Fossat and Bua2013; Jeppesen, Reference Jeppesen2021; Moore, Reference Moore2021; Moore and Fjeldstad, Reference Moore, Fjeldstad, Bräutigam, Moore and Fjeldstad2008).

This article conceptualizes the fiscal state in an empirically relevant and analytically applicable fashion. We pursue this purpose by reviewing the fiscal state literature to explore how the term ‘fiscal state’ has been understood and applied, which in turn leads to a definition of the fiscal state as a state whose public revenue base is dominated by tax revenue and loans, where the relationship between taxation and external and domestic borrowing is balanced, characterized by interdependence and therefore sustainable. The state is here understood in the Weberian sense, referring to contemporary states with centralized authority and sovereign rule (Frankema and van Waijenburg, Reference Frankema, Van Waijenburg, Genschel and Seelkopf2021). We elaborate on and discuss the key defining attributes of fiscal states before we use a typology to illustrate the differences and dynamics between the fiscal state and three other state ideal types: the tax state, the rentier state, and the debt state. We substantiate the relevance of this endeavour by including country illustrations.

2. Reviewing the meaning of the fiscal state concept

Taxation is intimately linked with state-building. Fiscal sociology has produced many historical analytical narratives that describe the concurrent political and economic processes that led to the emergence of the fiscal state (Bonney, Reference Bonney1999; He, Reference He2013; O'Brien, Reference O'Brien2011; O'Brien and Hunt, Reference O'Brien and Hunt2007; Yun-Casalilla, Reference Yun-Casalilla, Yun-Casalilla, O'Brien and Comin2012). Schumpeter's (Reference Schumpeter1918 [1954]) seminal work marked the advent of the fiscal sociology literature. Schumpeter associates the ‘tax state’ with the transition from a domain state, where the main source of income was the king's own domain, to a situation where inhabitants in the kingdom provided most funds. Hence, a tax state relies primarily on the mobilization of revenue through taxes. Later, as rulers expanded domestic revenue mobilization, they were able to use future tax payments as security in large-scale borrowing. Combined, governments' capacity to borrow, their power to tax, and the interaction between taxation and loan constraints became central to shaping the powers of the modern state (Bonney, Reference Bonney1999). Taxation and borrowing created a nexus that sowed the seeds of today's complex state economies that many would call fiscal states (Moore, Reference Moore2004).

Since its early employment in historical research to explain ‘why Europe’ in the state-building literature, the fiscal state concept has travelled across time and space to other contexts and development levels. On this journey, the concept has grown unclear and diluted. Today, the term often encompasses countries with various political regimes, social institutions, and modes of production. This risky journey towards conceptual stretching is to be expected when a concept is applied across disciplines from economic history to political economy, and it is not necessarily problematic (Sartori, Reference Sartori1970). Nevertheless, the lack of a common understanding, or clear definitions to facilitate comparative thoughts, inhibits interdisciplinary exchange as well as accumulation of knowledge about the dynamics of contemporary fiscal states and, not least, theorization about their causes and effects (Gerring, Reference Gerring1999; Hodgson, Reference Hodgson2019). If we have not clearly defined the fiscal state, how can we recognize it when we see it or be certain that we are able to separate its potential preconditions from its defining attributes as well as these from its ascribed effects?

To explore how understandings of the fiscal state differ across fields and empirical contexts, we carried out a systematic literature review. We used the main academic databases, Web of Science and Scopus, employing a search strategy in which we combined keyword and reference searches. Specifically, we searched for sources that mention ‘fiscal state*’ and cite Schumpeter (Reference Schumpeter1918), Moore (Reference Moore2004), Herbst (Reference Herbst2000), Besley and Persson (Reference Besley and Persson2009), Bonney (Reference Bonney1999), North and Weingast (Reference North and Weingast1989), or Dincecco (Reference Dincecco2011). These constitute key references in the historic fiscal state literature and contemporary, specifically African, state-building literature. To stay clear of broader non-fiscal state-building perspectives, we excluded references to Levi (Reference Levi1988), who focuses primarily on political economy and actors, and Tilly (Reference Tilly1992), who has a broader perspective on war and state-making. We expect the contractarian perspectives of fiscal states to be captured by Moore (Reference Moore2004). Second, we conducted a literature search combining the above references with the keywords ‘tax state*’, ‘rentier state*’, and ‘fiscal capacity’ to create a basis for delimiting the fiscal state from other types of states.

To illustrate, the search in Scopus on ‘fiscal state*’ produced 1,258 search resultsFootnote 1, which were reduced to 190 sources after the reference searches. Most of these do not engage the fiscal state concept analytically, though. Rather, they refer more or less in passing to ‘the rise of the fiscal state’ literature, including references such as Bonney (Reference Bonney1999), O'Brien (Reference O'Brien2011), Yun-Casalilla (Reference Yun-Casalilla, Yun-Casalilla, O'Brien and Comin2012), He (Reference He2013), and Torres Sánchez (Reference Torres Sànchez2007). For the review of fiscal state understandings, we relied only on sources that apply the concept in a manner where defining attributes can be discerned. Our literature review builds on these references combined with the corresponding group from Web of Science as well as key references added based on reviewer comments and inputs from a UNU-WIDER workshop (June 2021).

The fiscal state concept is not the only concept applied in research on fiscality in historical and contemporary state-building. For one, ‘fiscal constitution’ was defined by Brennan and Buchanan (Reference Brennan and Buchanan1980) as ‘a prevailing type of fiscal system in a specific country at a given moment in history’ (in Bonney, Reference Bonney1999: 5) and later by Levi (Reference Levi1988: 49) as ‘a polity's rules and procedures for extracting and collecting revenue’. Fiscal constitution is arguably comparable to ‘fiscal regime’ (Monson and Scheidel, Reference Monson, Scheidel, Monson and Scheidel2015: 7) as well as ‘fiscal systems’, most prominently used by Bonney (Reference Bonney1999) but also by Schumpeter (Reference Schumpeter1918 [1954]). All these terms allow us to study premodern fiscality – that is before actual states could be observed – as well as conduct analyses that cut across time and space because the state institutions are not included in concept definitions. For example, Frankema and Booth (Reference Frankema, Booth, Frankema and Booth2020) study fiscal systems and use this concept to investigate variations in fiscal capacity across colonial states. Andersson and Lazuka (Reference Andersson and Lazuka2019) and Bonney and Ormrod (Reference Bonney, Ormrod, Ormrod, Bonney and Bonney1999) use the term ‘fiscal system’ in a similar manner. As our main interest is in understanding the core defining attributes of contemporary fiscal states, we abstain from discussing further these empirically more inclusive analytical concepts or the dominant fiscal systems of the premodern era.

Few references define the fiscal state explicitly. Among those that do, the defining attributes either overlap or exhibit fundamental differences. In the following, we review the diverse understandings and applications of the fiscal state concept. This allows us to settle on a simple and concise definition of the fiscal state, which is both relevant and useful for understanding dynamics within and differences between states and whether SSA countries can be deemed fiscal states.

3. Diverse understandings of the fiscal state

At their core, most definitions of the fiscal state apply Schumpeter's simple understanding of the tax state as reliance mainly on income from taxes and, then, add the element of borrowing. Beyond this common ground, there seems to be a variety of understandings of the concept that raises important questions related both to the intension of the concept (i.e. what are the defining attributes) and its extension (i.e. to which empirical cases does the concept apply?) (Gerring, Reference Gerring1999; Sartori, Reference Sartori1970). Figure 1 presents these key questions that capture some of the differences and, one could say, inconsistencies in fiscal state understandings.

Figure 1. Review of conceptual extension and intension of the fiscal state.

Source: Authors' construction based on Ogden and Richards' triangle (Reference Ogden and Richards1923).

3.1 Are all states fiscal states?

There is implicit disagreement in the literature concerning whether all contemporary states can be categorized as fiscal states. One group of scholars either explicitly or implicitly assume that all modern states are fiscal states because they have the ability to raise revenue. Differences among them become a matter of how states use their fiscal tools to meet public policy goals such as adjusting market failure or designing welfare policies (Buchanan and Musgrave, Reference Buchanan and Musgrave2001; Jensen, Reference Jensen2011; Musgrave, Reference Musgrave1996). Such differences between states are taken as expressions of, for example, variations (Musgrave, Reference Musgrave1996) or advancements (Jensen, Reference Jensen2011) of fiscal states. Seen through this lens, all states in SSA would be considered fiscal states.

Other scholars, such as Yun-Casalilla (Reference Yun-Casalilla, Yun-Casalilla, O'Brien and Comin2012: 1), reserve the term ‘fiscal state’ for ‘nations and democratic states as they emerged over the nineteenth century’. Moreover, and relevant for exactly contemporary states, Yun-Casalilla distinguishes the fiscal state from the rentier state by whether they penetrate society to earn income (Ibid: 5). Over time, many scholars have analysed the rentier state as a distinctive state type defined by its dependence on rents from extractive natural resources or donors (e.g. Beblawi, Reference Beblawi, Belawi and Luciani1987; Chaudry, Reference Chaudry1989; Mahdavy, Reference Mahdavy and Cook1970; Moore, Reference Moore2004; Ross, Reference Ross, Lancaster and van de Walle2016; Sachs and Warner, Reference Sachs, Warner, Meier and Rauch2000). Interestingly, the literature review showed little overlap between references to fiscal states and rentier states, which implies that the two literatures are siloed. The conceptual relation between fiscal and rentier states has thus received limited attention. However, it is clear that rentier states and fiscal states represent contrasting examples of state development functioning. Rentier states are often characterized by their ‘pathologies’ (Moore, Reference Moore2004), meaning that dependence on particularly oil rents tends to have a series of negative effects on the economy and society. In contrast, fiscal states often involve positive connotations because the diverse revenue base is perceived to have several beneficial effects on the economy and society. Hence, the existence of the concept of rentier state and its widespread application on empirical cases such as Nigeria (Lewis, Reference Lewis2007) or Angola (Hammond, Reference Hammond2011) demonstrates the empirical relevance of this state type. Consequently, the contrasting foundation and empirical relevance of the rentier state ideal type indicates that not all states are fiscal states.

The question concerning the extension of the fiscal state is, of course, closely linked to its conceptual intension. The following three sections are structured around questions that arose from the literature review and that represent dimensions on which the defining attributes of the fiscal state concept vary, sometimes explicitly but often implicitly.

3.2 Is capacity a defining attribute of fiscal states?

The first question concerns whether capacity (administrative, state, or fiscal) is explicitly included as a defining attribute of fiscal states. Many see state capacity as a core attribute of the fiscal state: Boucoyannis (Reference Boucoyannis2015: 304) argues that state capacity allowed for the imposition of taxation, and Dincecco and Katz (Reference Dincecco and Katz2014) describe state capacity as states' ability to extract taxation. Cardoso and Lains (Reference Cardoso and Lains2010: 5) associate the rise of the fiscal state with ‘an increase in the ability of centralized states to manage the administrative apparatus for raising taxes, as well as with the ability of the sophisticated financial institutions to manage public debt’. Yet, many other sources do not mention state capacity explicitly as they discuss fiscal states (Musgrave, Reference Musgrave1996; Omeje, Reference Omeje2016; Sandbakken, Reference Sandbakken2006; Zhang, Reference Zhang2017).

Tightly linked to state capacity is fiscal capacity, which potentially adds another layer to the complexity. Fiscal capacity and fiscal states are sometimes used in conjunction and interchangeably, but only few papers mention both fiscal state and fiscal capacity. For example, the recent paper by Albers et al. (Reference Albers, Jerven and Suesse2020) is titled ‘The fiscal state in Africa’, but it only mentions and defines fiscal capacity. Therefore, it is difficult to determine if fiscal capacity is seen as a defining attribute of fiscal states or rather as a precondition or effect of its presence. Interestingly, the literature on fiscal capacity yields three times as many hits in Web of Science and one and a half times as many hits in Scopus. One likely reason is that while fiscal state and fiscal capacity might share core denotations, the latter seems to be more easily approached and measured if taken by the number of quantitative studies on fiscal capacity (e.g. Cárdenas, Reference Cárdenas2010; D'Arcy and Nistotskaya, Reference D'Arcy and Nistotskaya2018; Dincecco and Prado, Reference Dincecco and Prado2012; Jensen, Reference Jensen2011).

Fiscal states and fiscal capacity arguably carry different meanings and attributes because they represent two distinct analytical levels: one characterizes a type of state; the other characterizes attributes of a state. Meanwhile, fiscal capacity warrants its own discussion, and two curiosities are of relevance here. First, fiscal capacity is almost exclusively used in reference to states' ability to tax (e.g. Cárdenas, Reference Cárdenas2010; D'Arcy and Nistotskaya, Reference D'Arcy and Nistotskaya2018; Ricciuti et al., Reference Ricciuti, Savoia and Sen2018; one important exception being Frankema and Booth, Reference Frankema, Booth, Frankema and Booth2020). Connotations of the term fiscal capacity simply imply having capacity to ensure government revenue. Therefore, it would make more sense to talk of types of fiscal capacity such as tax capacity, which would refer to the ability to tax, borrowing capacity, as the ability to borrow, and rents capacity, as the ability to extract rents including from extractive natural resources. Such disaggregation is relevant because studies that use fiscal capacity but refer to, and measure it by, states' ability to collect taxes could simply opt for tax capacity (e.g. Baskaran and Bigsten, Reference Baskaran and Bigsten2013; Dincecco et al., Reference Dincecco, Fenske and Onorato2019; Dincecco and Prado, Reference Dincecco and Prado2012; Jensen, Reference Jensen2011).Footnote 2 Likewise, Ricciuti et al. (Reference Ricciuti, Savoia and Sen2018) argue that tax ability is just one dimension of fiscal capacity (the other dimension in their argument is impartiality). Second, researchers of fiscal capacity often focus on direct taxes. Even though direct taxes have traditionally been perceived as the most developed form of state income (e.g. Kaldor, Reference Kaldor1963), it is debatable whether direct taxes are a central enough tax source in today's developing states for them to be a relevant indicator of fiscal capacity (Bird and Zolt, Reference Bird and Zolt2005). This concern is also relevant for the conceptualization of the fiscal state; a narrow focus on this ‘modern tax’ (Genschel and Seelkopf, Reference Genschel and Seelkopf2021) can be problematic. The tax landscape in Africa obviously looks different than when the European fiscal state emerged. Direct taxation cannot be assumed to be broad-based in an African context and, hence, this tax type might entail very different qualities and implications. To the extent that fiscal capacity denotes the ability to tax, one risks neglecting the important conceptual distinction between the tax state and the fiscal state and the progression in sources of revenue that differentiate the two.

3.3 What are the revenue sources of fiscal states?

A second key question that arises concerns revenue sources. There seems to be consensus that fiscal states are financed through taxes and borrowing, but the relative weight given to these revenue sources differs in the literature.

Most scholars mainly associate the fiscal state with the ability to tax (Albers et al., Reference Albers, Jerven and Suesse2020; Cardoso and Lains, Reference Cardoso and Lains2010; Dincecco and Prado, Reference Dincecco and Prado2012; He, Reference He2013; Yun-Casalilla et al., Reference Yun-Casalilla, O'Brien and Comin2012), but few define the characteristics of taxation further. Thus, He (Reference He2013) emphasizes the centralized nature of tax collection, while O'Brien (Reference O'Brien2005: 30–31) implies that moving from direct taxes (such as land taxes) to easier-to-collect indirect taxes made Britain the most effective fiscal state in Europe at the time.

There is little discussion of how dependent a state needs to be on taxation vis-à-vis other revenue sources for it to qualify as a fiscal state. To the extent that this remains un(der)specified, there is a risk of conceptual overlap between the tax state and the fiscal state. Meanwhile, most scholars do mention that fiscal states – in addition to being able to tax – have the ability to issue paper money or borrow (e.g. Bonney, Reference Bonney1999; Cardoso and Lains, Reference Cardoso and Lains2010; He Reference He2013; Moore, Reference Moore2004; Piano and Salter, Reference Piano and Salter2021). While issuing paper money was a central part of early state-building, many contemporary states are not monetarily sovereign; their currencies are not in demand, they are indebted in foreign currencies, they are part of monetary unions, and they face global pressure not to conduct monetary policy (Gevorkyan and Kvangraven, Reference Gevorkyan and Kvangraven2016; Smith, Reference Smith2021; Sylla, Reference Sylla2020). Hence, monetary policy is not included in the definition here.

As for borrowing, the rise of the fiscal state is attributed to when it became possible to secure (mainly commercial) loans (Bonney, Reference Bonney and Bonney1995). This allowed the state to achieve ‘an economy of scale in mobilizing financial resources’ in the long term (He, Reference He2013: 5) and gave it ‘superior capacity … to raise the financial resources to cope with emergencies’ (Moore, Reference Moore2004: 301). Emergencies, most notably wars (e.g. Dincecco and Prado, Reference Dincecco and Prado2012), meant that tax revenues were insufficient and prompted rulers to borrow. Borrowing was the outcome of taxation in that states' fiscal systems provided the basis for credible commitment to lenders who gave significant loans on the basis of future tax revenues. As Bonney argues, fiscal states' powers were to be made up by ‘the capacity of governments to borrow, and the interaction between the constraints on borrowing and the power to tax’ (Reference Bonney and Bonney1995: 505).

Curiously, while borrowing is undisputedly a defining attribute of fiscal states, as highlighted above, empirical research on contemporary fiscal states mainly tends to focus on tax collection (Albers et al., Reference Albers, Jerven and Suesse2020; Beramendi et al., Reference Beramendi, Dincecco and Rogers2019; Besley, Reference Besley2020; Moore, Reference Moore2021). The reason might be that in today's complex economies, borrowing can be obtained through many other foundations than expectations about future tax revenue, for example, through expectations to states' growth potential or through natural resource collateralization (AFDB, 2021; Mihalyi et al., Reference Mihalyi, Adam and Hwang2020; Smith, Reference Smith2021). It might be that the ability to borrow is taken for granted in today's global economies. Hence, the literature instead (over)emphasizes the importance of taxation in the state economy. Importantly, this seems to reflect the fact that debt and taxes have often been presented as substitutes, i.e. if a state lacks tax revenue, for example in times of crisis, it can instead borrow money to cover expenses. Yet, this understanding de-emphasizes the important interplay between the two revenue sources. We argue that a key feature of the fiscal state is exactly that taxes and borrowing are complementary rather than substitutes. For example, the soundness of the tax base will influence the ability to gain favourable loans. This complementary interdependence between taxes and debt is part of what makes the fiscal state more sustainable than other state types. We will return to this point later.

3.4 Do fiscal states need to spend in certain ways?

A final significant question concerns whether fiscal states are defined solely by their sources of revenue or the character of the states' expenditure is also a defining attribute. The scholarly contributions analysed in the above do not address this question explicitly. Some contributions include the composition of public expenditure as part of the definition of a fiscal state whereas many other contributions do not. What is clear, therefore, is that there is significant unclarity in the literature.

Scholars who include the expenditure side in their understanding of the fiscal state consider whether domestic revenues are used to finance a government's policy objectives or publicly negotiated common goods, including redistributive purposes (Bird and Zolt, Reference Bird and Zolt2015; Buchanan and Musgrave, Reference Buchanan and Musgrave2001; Cardoso and Lains, Reference Cardoso and Lains2010; Martin et al., Reference Martin, Mehrotra, Prasad, Prasad, Mehrotra and Martin2009). They, for example, connect the rise of fiscal states to the emergence of democratic rule, modern state bureaucracy, and the first signs of public services beyond protection of citizens (Buchanan and Musgrave, Reference Buchanan and Musgrave2001; Mehrotra, Reference Mehrotra2013; Yun-Casalilla, Reference Yun-Casalilla, Yun-Casalilla, O'Brien and Comin2012).

Musgrave (Reference Musgrave1996) distinguishes between four types of fiscal states according to the structure of states' expenditure. His point of departure is public finance and the argument that fiscal states need to be categorized according to whose needs the state accommodates and the extent to which the state redistributes and meets market flaws. This is very different from other branches of the literature reviewed that mainly focus on the state's revenue side. For instance, Albers et al. (Reference Albers, Jerven and Suesse2020) are clearly interested in discerning whether fiscal states are emerging in sub-Saharan Africa based on long term analysis of whether domestic revenues are increasing.

Arguably, it is difficult, if not impossible, to include both the revenue source dimension and an expenditure side in the definition of a fiscal state while maintaining the ambition to develop an analytically useful concept. Including the expenditure side complicates the concept and empirical identification. And, more importantly, as will be theorized below, rather than constituting a defining attribute of the fiscal state, a contractual relationship between state and individuals is part of the feedback mechanisms that can reinforce and maintain the fiscal state. To illustrate, if a present-day fiscal state invests in increasing productivity on a long-term basis, this can strengthen the state's ability to tax and borrow in the future. On the other hand, unwise investment decisions might negatively affect future revenue sources. Assuming that the revenue sources and their composition then change, the state may enter into negative dynamics that will undermine its fiscality and make it fall out of the category of a fiscal state. Timmons (Reference Timmons2005) is but one contribution showing how state expenditure is explained by the composition of revenues pointing to e.g. how a high share of property tax in the USA incentivizes the government to spend a lot on private property protection. Steinmo (Reference Steinmo1993) shows how variations in welfare states can be explained by types of tax systems. These contributions need to analytically separate public expenditure policies from revenue sources since the latter explains the former. In addition, it is possible for a state to have an advanced system of social services without being a fiscal state, as is the case with some rentier states. Looking at the types of, say, social expenditure alone in these states would not necessarily capture the rentier state dynamics behind them. Likewise, debt states might use debt to finance growth-enhancing investments (i.e. expenditures), which in the future may lead to a change in the revenue source composition and, thus, in financial state type. We return to this point when presenting our typology and debating the sustainability of the different state types in section 4.2. Consequently, we argue that expenditure is not part of the fiscal state definition but instead influence its ability to persist in the future.

If the output side of public finances is included, the conceptual intension increases, extension decreases, and, importantly, conceptual complexity (and confusion) grows. In sum, the blurriness of the fiscal state concept inhibits a proper understanding of the implications of the fiscal state.

3.5 Summing up

Based on the literature review and the four conceptual questions that arose from it, we can make several observations. (1) While some contributions seem to assume that all contemporary states are fiscal states, there are grounds for arguing that this is not necessarily the case. (2) When considering how to define a fiscal state, attributes such as state capacity and fiscal capacity are important features. However, both are elusive concepts themselves and therefore not beneficial in an analytically applicable definition. (3) Though some scholars will analyse fiscality of a state by its ability to tax, other revenue sources are important to include, especially borrowing. (4) Lastly, many define fiscal states by the expenditure side or its link to revenue. Meanwhile, by including this in the definition, we risk confusing defining attributes with effects thereof.

Based on these conclusions, a definition of a fiscal state should enhance parsimony and clearly differentiate the concept's defining attributes from its causes and consequences (Gerring, Reference Gerring1999; Hodgson, Reference Hodgson2019). This implies that (1) the concept should not include the size and composition of public expenditure, which can instead be explained by the nature of a fiscal state; (2) it should be clearly distinguishable from other effects such as welfare, governance, and inequality; and (3) it should be distinguishable from its preconditions, such as the level of commercialization of the economy. While conceptual parsimony imposes limits on the depth of the concept, it increases its theoretical and field utility. In addition to parsimony and differentiation from causes and consequences, we seek familiarity and resonance (Gerring, Reference Gerring1999) by maintaining the core defining attributes identified above. We find that only a definition based solely on the characteristics of state revenue can accommodate these criteria. The remainder of the article will present and discuss the chosen definition, its key components, and illustrate the conceptual delimitations with empirical examples.

4. Definition and conceptualization of the fiscal state

Accommodating the criteria above, we define the fiscal state solely on the state's revenue side. Drawing on Moore's (Reference Moore2004) and Bonney's (Reference Bonney1999) definitions, we define the fiscal state as a state whose public revenue base is dominated by tax revenue and loans, and where the relationship between taxation and external and domestic borrowing is balanced, characterized by interdependence and thereby sustainable. The definition presumes that the state is a sovereign legal entity in the sense that it can use centrally collected tax revenues to take on long-term borrowing from the market (Frankema and Van Waijenburg, Reference Frankema, Van Waijenburg, Genschel and Seelkopf2021; He, Reference He2013). Centralization of state power has been seen as an important precondition for the rise of the fiscal state (e.g. Besley and Persson, Reference Besley and Persson2009; Cárdenas, Reference Cárdenas2010; Cardoso and Lains, Reference Cardoso and Lains2010; O'Brien and Hunt, Reference O'Brien and Hunt2007; Tilly, Reference Tilly1992). Here, sovereignty and centralization are not elaborated but are in a sense assumed in the definition.

Besides its specific focus solely on the revenue side, our definition distinguishes itself not by the fact that it includes taxation and borrowing, which is indeed quite common, but rather by its particular emphasis on the balance between them. To some extent, all contemporary states can tax and borrow money; however, the level of taxation, debt burden, and their internal relations vary greatly. We are not interested in a state's capacity to tax or borrow per se but rather in states' relative dependence and composition of revenue sources as this holds implications for the sustainability of states' public finances. A balance of taxation and borrowing is essential to the fiscal state (Bonney, Reference Bonney1999; Hart et al., Reference Hart, Brandon and Sánchez2018). We briefly elaborate on this balance before introducing a typology of fiscal states based on our definition. The typology includes illustrative examples of contemporary African states to demonstrate features of each ideal type.

4.1 A balance between taxation and borrowing

Most states today can tax and borrow, but we argue that the presence of a balance is what sets fiscal states apart from other states that depend exceedingly on loans, state monopolies, or natural resource extraction. Such a balance renders fiscal states more resistant to economic crises and shocks. Yet, the two revenue sources are not necessarily intimately linked. The loan market is diverse and consists of many different political and commercial interests. China, for example, lends money to lower-income countries in Africa as a part of political deals without necessarily considering their tax base (Bräutigam, Reference Bräutigam2020; McCormick, Reference McCormick2008).Footnote 3 This detachment between taxation and borrowing is not a new phenomenon. Frankema and Booth's (Reference Frankema, Booth, Frankema and Booth2020) observations of colonial states can be paralleled to contemporary states. They emphasize that decisions to take loans were not based primarily on risk assessments by private investors (or indeed only on tax capacity in the colonies) but rather on the decisions of officials of the metropole weighing the cost of development projects in the colony against the risks of default (Ibid.: 12). This was one reason for the lack of fiscal modernization of the colonial state and, conversely, an argument for why a balance and interdependence between taxation and borrowing is important.

To assess the balance between tax and debt, one must include the terms on which a state borrows. Borrowing is a means to stabilize an economy. It can be used to finance short-term measures of crisis management when tax revenue momentarily drops, or to support long-term growth-enhancing investment policies (AFDB, 2021; Dincecco and Prado, Reference Dincecco and Prado2012; Moore, Reference Moore2004; Smith, Reference Smith2021: 99–101). Most recently, however, debt has in many countries led to what IMF describes as fiscal stress rather than economic stability during the COVID-19 pandemic (AFDB, 2021; Smith, Reference Smith2021: 101–02). Importantly, whether debt has negative effects on fiscal sustainability does not necessarily depend on the size of a country's debt (Chandler, Reference Chandler2020). Instead, the conditions surrounding its debt such as the maturity of the loan, the interest rate, and the currency in which the loan is taken are determinants of a country's ability to service and repay debt obligations (Smith, Reference Smith2021: 91). Most often, borrowing based on stable tax revenue rather than growth potential or natural resource collateralization can ensure better and more stable loan conditions. This is because borrowing based on natural resource rents or growth potential renders the state more vulnerable. For example, if the prices of natural resources drop, if debt-financed project fails to generate predicted returns, or if the global market starts retracting such as during the financial crisis or the COVID-19 pandemic, this can limit borrowing opportunities or increase interest rates. The more tax revenue the government can collect now and in the future, the better its means for servicing debt, which in turn is likely to reduce the cost of borrowing. A balanced composition between tax and debt thus provides for better loan conditions and sustainability and makes fiscal states more resistant to crises.

We emphasize that fiscal states are characterized by a revenue composition dominated by a balance of taxation and borrowing because this alerts researchers to the importance of sustainability. Admittedly, including sustainability in the fiscal state concept risks adding to its elusiveness. However, we contend that sustainability applied in its most basic meaning is in fact fairly intuitive (Merriam-Webster, 2022). The relationship between taxation and borrowing is sustainable when it is maintained at length without interruption or weakening and when neither of the revenue sources are depleted or permanently damaged through its use. To assess sustainability, analyses need to be contextual, including both national and international factors, and they must also include a time dimension. One example of such an assessment is IMF's debt sustainability framework, which includes various dimensions of domestic capacity such as institutions and the tax base. Importantly, such an assessment acknowledges the deep-rooted variations in debt sustainability between countries at different levels of economic development (IMF, 2013, 2018; Smith, Reference Smith2021: 96–97). Accordingly, this also implies that economic growth would be a poor indicator when assessing fiscal sustainability because it does say much about the underlying conditions of fiscal sustainability including the breadth and diversity of the tax base (for a discussion of preconditions of the fiscal state, see Bak et al., Reference Bak, Jeppesen and Kjær2021). Hence, we would risk mischaracterizing states where growth is driven by, for example, large external rents or extensive borrowing, as we elaborate below.

4.2 Typology of ideal state types

According to the presented definition, not all states are fiscal states. This is consistent with the existence of other state types emerging from the literature review, such as the rentier state. In terms of the dominance of and balance between revenue sources, a rentier state exhibits a different structural basis than fiscal states. Hence, we argue that fiscal states and, for example, rentier states are distinct (ideal) state types rather than variations within a group. To illustrate, we have developed a state typology to demarcate the fiscal state from other ideal state types. Figure 2 operates with continuums in a coordinate system and thus emphasizes the dynamic room for state transitions as well as the grey zones between the ideal types.

Figure 2. Distinguishing between ideal state types defined by their revenue side.

Note: The dotted lines are included as figurative indications. The line without an arrow exemplifies when taxes and borrowing become dominant. The line with an arrow exemplifies when a balance is achieved between taxes and borrowing.

Source: Authors' construction.

Other typologies map states according to their revenues. Bonney and Ormrod (Reference Bonney, Ormrod, Ormrod, Bonney and Bonney1999), for example, have a helpful model of fiscal systems. However, our typology distinguishes itself in two ways. First, where Bonney and Ormrod's model explains historic fiscal systems, the present typology has the potential to understand contemporary states. Second, the Bonney-Ormrod model tends towards presenting a somewhat linear view of state development, not least given the inescapable historical empirical basis of their model. In contrast, our typology presents a dynamic perspective as it allows for states to move between the depicted ideal types.

As defined above, (1) fiscal states' revenue base is dominated by taxes and loans with a balance and interdependence between taxation and domestic and external borrowing. Thus, fiscal states exhibit relatively complex state financing. This differs from (2) tax states that have a relatively simple public economy primarily financed through taxes, and (3) debt states that might have some tax collection but predominantly rely on state revenue from borrowing, which is not necessarily linked to expected future tax revenue. Lastly, (4) rentier states neither tax nor borrow much but attain their main financing from aid or natural resource extraction. A last group of states could be termed non-fiscal in the sense that they have very limited state resources, such as fragile states experiencing long-term conflict. In Figure 2, these states would be placed with the rentier state but with a fundamentally different political economy and much less room for transitioning towards becoming a fiscal state. As these are ideal state types, real-world states typically lie in the grey zones between them. For this reason, we stress the importance of identifying the dominant revenue source(s) when determining empirically whether a state can be deemed a fiscal state. Consequently, if a state's finances are dominated solely by either tax revenue, aid or natural resources, or debt, the state does not classify as a fiscal state.

Though we define the ideal types along a revenue source dimension, we theorize that states can evolve and move between these ideal types as a result of changes in the composition of revenue sources – that is, the balance and dominance of revenue(s), as well as changes in expenditure demands. Changes in state expenditure can influence revenue composition through several feedback mechanisms: for example, if debt service expenditure becomes too high; if public investments in a sector contribute to sector growth and, in turn, more sectoral taxation; or, as indicated in fiscal contract theories (e.g. Levi, Reference Levi1988), if more spending increases quasi-voluntary compliance and, in this way, eases and increases tax collection. Hence, while the input side of revenue and the output side of spending are theoretically and empirically distinct, the output side manifesting the level of quid pro quo can help improve, sustain, or undermine the input side (Moore, Reference Moore2004, Reference Moore2021; O'Brien and Hunt, Reference O'Brien and Hunt2007; Prichard, Reference Prichard2015). While states can potentially move, for example, towards becoming fiscal states, they tend to be caught in the status quo as their main sources of revenue are likely to be self-reinforcing.

The rentier state receives rents primarily from foreign actors; they accrue directly to the state, and ‘only a few are engaged in the generation of this rent (wealth), the majority being only involved in the distribution or utilization of it’ (Beblawi, Reference Beblawi, Belawi and Luciani1987: 50). In many countries, the reliance on rents has demotivated productive investment in the broader economy and limited economic diversification (e.g. Beblawi, Reference Beblawi, Belawi and Luciani1987; Karl, Reference Karl1997; Ross, Reference Ross, Lancaster and van de Walle2016; Savoia and Sen, Reference Savoia and Sen2021). Reliance on rents will tend to be self-reinforcing; as the large amounts of ‘unearned income’ provides little incentive to invest in economic diversification, which implies that the composition of revenue comprising a heavy reliance on rents is maintained, if not exacerbated in the future (Ross, Reference Ross, Lancaster and van de Walle2016). To illustrate, Nigeria gets close to an ‘archetypal oil nation’ and, thus, rentier state (Watts, Reference Watts2004: 50). More than 95 per cent of foreign exchange earnings derive from petroleum exports, and oil revenues constitute 65–80 per cent of government revenues (depending on data source and time of assessment) (Fagbemi and Adeoye, Reference Fagbemi and Adeoye2020; Hailu and Kipgen, Reference Hailu and Kipgen2017). Nigeria's ‘rentier state’ characteristics have been self-reinforcing, and moreover, there is a broad consensus that its oil dependence has led to governance challenges including large-scale corruption, a lack of diversification of production, and other features of the so-called ‘resource curse’ (Auty, Reference Auty1993; Lewis, Reference Lewis2007). However, this does not mean that Nigeria could not move towards other state ideal types. Its dependence on oil can make its indebtedness larger in times when oil prices are low, which could push it towards becoming a debt state. Alternatively, political decisions to make productive investments beyond the oil sector (i.e. its expenditure decisions) could lead to gradual diversification of the economy. Such interventions would likely serve to diversify the revenue base in the longer run, which would improve the balance between different revenue sources and increase its fiscal sustainability. In other words, there is no deterministic relation between extractive natural resources and their negative effects. The relation is mediated by political and institutional variables (Lewis, Reference Lewis2007; Rosser, Reference Rosser2006).Footnote 4

Debt states tend to be caught in a trap of accumulating debt as one loan leads to another to pay off earlier ones. Meanwhile, it becomes continuously difficult to meet recurring expenditures and the spending demands that caused the loans in the first place. This can potentially lead to debt overhang or the need for debt relief. While a state's revenues are highly unlikely to consist only of loans, loans can be a dominant source of state financing which is obtained, for example, based on debt collateralization, such as commodity-secured loans, or growth potential (AFDB, 2021: 4–5, 64–65; Mihalyi et al., Reference Mihalyi, Adam and Hwang2020; Smith, Reference Smith2021: 116). This makes debt states vulnerable to drops in commodity prices, changes in global liquidity, credit ratings, or significant increases in borrowing costs and loan conditionalities (e.g. Gevorkyan and Kvangraven, Reference Gevorkyan and Kvangraven2016). To illustrate, while Zambia is highly dependent on its copper industry and collects various types of taxes, it has moved towards becoming a debt state. Zambia's debt load became increasingly unsustainable during the 2010s as a result of ‘reckless’ over-borrowing, a depreciation of the Zambian currency, and borrowing for consumption instead of investments (Smith, Reference Smith2021: 87–88, 143–145; ZIPAR, 2018). If cobber prices had not decreased in the period or borrowing had been used differently, the Zambian economy might have evolved more positively. Yet, this highlights the vulnerability of relying heavily on fluctuating resource rents and unbalanced debt, thus demonstrating the lack of sustainability in Zambia's financing. Consequently, Zambia became the first African country to default on its Eurobond loans in 2020 (Bräutigam, Reference Bräutigam2021; Smith, Reference Smith2021: 116). Today, Zambia's debt makes up more than 100 per cent of its GDP (Benson, Reference Benson2022; Smith, Reference Smith2021: 88). This accumulation of debt occurred despite significant debt relief and cancellations throughout the 2000s, although it could be argued that this history of debt cancellation also led to moral hazard risk when obtaining new loans (Bräutigam, Reference Bräutigam2021). Zambia's movement towards becoming a debt state highlights how debt accumulation tends to be actor-driven. For example, the Zambian parliament agreed to raise the ceiling on external borrowing, and the Zambian government ignored warnings from IMF in the mid-2010s (Smith, Reference Smith2021: 160; ZIPAR, 2018).

The least stable of the four types is the tax state. As taxation increases, so does demand for expenditure, and an established infrastructure for taxation provides a basis for beneficial borrowing, which is likely to set off a movement towards becoming a fiscal state. Accordingly, the tax state seems to have status as a historical rather than a contemporary phenomenon (He, Reference He2013). Evolving from a tax state to a debt or a fiscal state is obviously conditioned by the nature of economic transformation as well as the extent of access to the lending market. Access to loans is based on the state's ability to make credible commitments to loan providers due to an expanded and diversified economy. In addition, serious economic crises or conflicts could undermine taxation, either diminishing state finances altogether or necessitating loan-taking, which could push the country towards a status as a non-fiscal or debt state.

The fiscal state ideal type is the most stable of the four types due to its reliance on a balance of and interdependence between taxes and loans. The balance allows it to acquire loans on good terms based on its assurance in tax revenue, and tax revenue remains relatively stable because favourable loans help ensure a stable economy even in times of crisis. The balance and interrelation thus imply that the state's public finances are more sustainable and stable, and for this reason fiscal states are likely to be conducive to long-term economic development. As the revenue side reinforces a positive nexus, only few situations, such as unsustainably high expenditures, can lead them off track. To illustrate, Senegal would be much closer to the fiscal state ideal type than Nigeria or Zambia. Senegal's tax-to-GDP level is about 16–18 per cent; just at or above the Sub-Saharan African average (Bak, Reference Bak2019; Niang and Mbaye, Reference Niang and Mbaye2020; UNU-WIDER, 2021). A considerable proportion of Senegal's tax revenue is personal or corporate income tax (30 per cent), while VAT constitutes around 40 per cent. Senegal's revenues from natural resources or aid are not significant. Non-tax revenues thus consisted of 1 per cent of GDP. The domestic revenue take has allowed Senegal to maintain considerable debt levels, which were projected to peak at 68 per cent of GDP in 2022 (IMF, 2021). However, due to the COVID-19 crisis and the effects of the war in Ukraine, debt levels are now expected to reach 75 per cent (IMF, 2022), and Senegal's debt has been assessed by international financial institutions to be sustainable with a moderate risk of over-indebtedness and limited ability to absorb shocks (IMF, 2022). Compared to Nigeria and Zambia, Senegal was moving towards becoming a fiscal state; however, the balance between taxation and borrowing seems to be tipping, as in many other countries, during the COVID-19 crisis. While Senegal's per capita GDP growth has only been slightly higher than that of Zambia or Nigeria, Senegal's tax base is more diverse, and its reliance on taxes relative to rents is higher. Thus, Senegal's case shows that it is not economic growth per se that could make a fiscal state but the potential for fiscal sustainability that build on the level of diversification of the economy (Bak et al., Reference Bak, Jeppesen and Kjær2021).

In sum, we argue that a fiscal state is defined and identified by its input side. In practice, data on taxation (excluding natural resources revenue) and loans are the main indicators to use, but actually assessing the balance requires a qualitative assessment. Furthermore, it is imperative to take both conditions of revenue acquisition and factors on the expenditure side into consideration as these can improve, sustain, or undermine the revenue input. An extensive assessment is beyond the scope of this paper. Instead, we discuss the implications of our fiscal state definition and typology for understandings of fiscality and (ideal) state types.

5. Conclusion

While the different strands of the fiscal state literature originate from the same Schumpeterian roots, there is a tendency not to interlink historical and contemporary branches. Naturally, there are huge disparities in the international and political conditions of state-building now and then. However, due to the lack of grounding and perhaps aversion to drawing on historical state-building analysis, fiscal state-building today tends to be regarded mainly in terms of its institutional characteristics with less regard to the significance and necessity of economic changes for the emergence of fiscal states.

In this paper, we revisit the fiscal state concept with the objective of arriving at a definition which can be applied to identify the presence of fiscal states in SSA. After reviewing the diverse understandings of the fiscal state across literatures, we arrive at a definition that is both in line with the core defining attributes suggested in the literatures and analytically relevant and applicable to contemporary Africa: a fiscal state is a state whose public revenue base is dominated by tax revenue and loans, and where the relationship between taxation and external and domestic borrowing is balanced and thereby sustainable and characterized by interdependence. Specifically, we emphasize the importance of borrowing, which has received insufficient theoretical and empirical attention in the literature, especially related to contemporary African states. Furthermore, our definition highlights the balance between taxation and borrowing, which we argue to be central to deciding whether a state is really a fiscal state or rather tends towards a rentier, non-fiscal, or debt state.

Applying this definition would arguably imply that most SSA countries would not be categorized as fiscal states. Between the illustrative examples mentioned, Senegal would come closest, but even here, the balance is tipping towards a debt state. This apparent lack of fiscal states in SSA can to a large extent be explained by the absence of economic preconditions. Taxing more requires, first and foremost, a taxable surplus, and this requires economic transformation and diversification; without such a tax base, loans are acquired on other and more vulnerable foundations. This conclusion has important implications not only for how analyses of African public finances are presented and for subsequent policy recommendations, which tend to focus overwhelmingly on increasing domestic taxation. Applying our typology to analyse the fiscality of SSA states contributes to better understandings of the policy options available to governments, for example, when dealing with external shocks such as the COVID-19 pandemic. There are limits to what governments can accomplish out of sheer will if they do not first take account of their fiscal foundation and their actual economic room for manoeuvring.

Acknowledgements

We are thankful to Kunal Sen and Antonio Savoia for inviting us to take part in the Fiscal States work and for their support throughout. Four anonymous reviewers critically but constructively engaged with our paper. We are grateful to the participants at the UNU-WIDER Fiscal States workshop in June 2021, colleagues in the Comparative Politics section at the Department of Political Science, Aarhus University, and at the Danish Centre for Welfare Studies, University of Southern Denmark for their careful discussion of our work. We thank Amalie Dalegaard for excellent research assistance. Finally, we acknowledge generous funding from the UNU-Wider Fiscal States project (part of the Domestic Revenue Mobilization programme), and funding from the Political Settlement and Revenue Bargaining programme (www.ps.au.dk/psrb; grant no 16-03 Consultative Research Committee for Development Research).

Footnotes

1 Per 31 March 2021 when searching in ‘all fields’.

2 See also Ricciuti et al. (Reference Ricciuti, Savoia and Sen2018) for a detailed discussion of measurements of fiscal capacity.

3 China's lending is often part of a political deal with recipient countries, but not necessarily a deliberate attempt to create debt traps, as Bräutigam (Reference Bräutigam2020) convincingly argues.

4 See Addison and Roe (Reference Addison and Roe2018) for a recent and comprehensive volume discussing how the extractives wealth can be used for sustainable development.

References

Addison, T. and Roe, A. R. (2018), Extractive Industries: The Management of Resources as a Driver of Sustainable Development, WIDER Studies in Development Economics, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Africa Development Bank Group (AFDB) (2021), African Economic Outlook 2021, from Debt Resolution to Growth: The Road Ahead for Africa, Available at https://www.afdb.org/en/documents/african-economic-outlook-2021 (accessed 15 November 2021).Google Scholar
Albers, T. N. H., Jerven, M. and Suesse, M. (2020), The Fiscal State in Africa: Evidence from a Century of Growth, Working Paper 55, Bloemfontein: African Economic History Network.Google Scholar
Andersson, J. and Lazuka, V. (2019), ‘Long-Term Drivers of Taxation in Francophone West Africa 1893–2010’, World Development, 114(February 2019): 294313, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.10.008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auty, R. M. (1993), Sustaining Development in the Mineral Economies: The Resource Curse Thesis, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bak, A. K. (2019), When the Fiscal Social Contract is Not About Tax: Understanding the Limited Role of Taxation in Social Accountability in Senegal, Aarhus: Politica.Google Scholar
Bak, A. K., Jeppesen, M. and Kjær, A. M. (2021), Fiscal States in Sub-Saharan Africa: Conceptualization and Empirical Trends, WIDER Working Paper 2021/182, Helsinki: UNU-WIDER.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baskaran, T. and Bigsten, A. (2013), ‘Fiscal Capacity and the Quality of Government in Sub-Saharan Africa’, World Development, 45(May 2013): 92107, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2012.09.018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beblawi, H. (1987), ‘The Rentier State in the Arab World’, in Belawi, H. and Luciani, G. (eds), The Rentier State, London: Croom Helm, pp. 383398.Google Scholar
Benson, E. A. (2022), ‘20 Countries with the Highest Debt-to-GDP Ratio in Africa’, Business Insider Africa, Available at https://africa.businessinsider.com/local/markets/20-countries-with-the-highest-debt-to-gdp-ratio-in-africa/8qdmrsq (accessed 30 June 2022).Google Scholar
Beramendi, P., Dincecco, M. and Rogers, M. (2019), ‘Intra-Elite Competition and Long-Run Fiscal Development’, The Journal of Politics, 81(1): 4965, https://doi.org/10.1086/700273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. (2020), ‘State Capacity, Reciprocity, and the Social Contract’, Econometrica, 88(4): 13071335, https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA16863.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and Persson, T. (2009), ‘The Origins of State Capacity: Property Rights, Taxation and Politics’, American Economic Review, 99(4): 12181244, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.99.4.1218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bird, R. M. and Zolt, E. M. (2005), ‘Redistribution via Taxation: The Limited Role of the Personal Income Tax in Developing Countries’, UCLA Law Review, 52(6): 16271695.Google Scholar
Bird, R. M. and Zolt, E. M. (2015), ‘Fiscal Contracting in Latin America’, World Development, 67(March 2015): 323335, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2014.10.011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonney, R. (1995), ‘Revenues’, in Bonney, R. (ed.), The Origins of the Modern State in Europe 13th to 18th Centuries, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bonney, R. (1999), The Rise of the Fiscal State in Europe c.1200–1815, Oxford: Oxford University Press, https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198204022.001.0001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonney, R. and Ormrod, W. M. (1999), ‘Introduction: Crises, Revolutions and Self-Sustained Growth: Towards a Conceptual Model of Change in Fiscal history’, in Ormrod, W. M., Bonney, M. and Bonney, R. (eds.), Crises, Revolutions, and Self-Sustained Growth: Essays in European Fiscal History, 1130–1830, Stamford, UK: Shaun Tyas, pp. 12.Google Scholar
Boucoyannis, D. (2015), ‘No Taxation of Elites, No Representation: State Capacity and the Origins of Representation’, Politics & Society, 43(3): 303332, https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329215584765.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bräutigam, D. (2020), ‘A Critical Look at Chinese ‘Debt-Trap Diplomacy’: The Rise of a Meme’, Area Development and Policy, 5(1): 114, https://doi.org/10.1080/23792949.2019.1689828.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bräutigam, D. (2021), How Zambia and China Co-Created a Debt ‘Tragedy of the Commons’, Working Paper No. 2021/51, Washington, DC: CARI, Johns Hopkins University.Google Scholar
Brennan, G. and Buchanan, J. M. (1980), The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a Fiscal Constitution, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and Musgrave, R. A. (2001), Public Finance and Public Choice: Two Contrasting Visions of the State (4th edn), Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Cárdenas, M. (2010), ‘State Capacity in Latin America’, Economía, 10(2): 145, https://doi.org/10.1353/eco.2010.0003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cardoso, J. L. and Lains, P. (2010), Paying for the Liberal State: The Rise of Public Finance in Nineteenth-Century Europe, New York: Cambridge University Press, https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511845109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandler, B. (2020), ‘COVID-19 and African Debt: Further Distress or New Paradigm?’, Mo Ibrahim Foundation, Available at https://mo.ibrahim.foundation/sites/default/files/2020-06/debt-distress-covid19.pdf (accessed 15 November 2021).Google Scholar
Chaudry, K. (1989), ‘The Price of Wealth: Business and State in Labor Remittance and Oil Economies’, International Organization, 43(1): 101145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D'Arcy, M. and Nistotskaya, M. (2018), ‘The Early Modern Origins of Contemporary European Tax Outcomes’, European Journal of Political Research, 57(1): 4767, https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dincecco, M. (2011), Political Transformations and Public Finances: Europe, 1650–1913, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139013345.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dincecco, M. and Katz, G. (2014), ‘State Capacity and Long-Run Economic Performance’, The Economic Journal, 126(590): 189218, https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dincecco, M. and Prado, M. (2012), ‘Warfare, Fiscal Capacity, and Performance’, Journal of Economic Growth, 17(3): 171203, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-012-9079-4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dincecco, M., Fenske, J. and Onorato, M. G. (2019), ‘Is Africa Different? Historical Conflict and State Development’, Economic History of Developing Regions, 34(2): 209250, https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2019.1586528.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fagbemi, F. and Adeoye, G. O. (2020), ‘Nigerian Governance Challenge: Exploring the Role of Natural Resource Rents’, Global Journal of Emerging Market Economies, 12(3): 335358, https://doi.org/10.1177/0974910120919001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fjeldstad, O.-H. (2014), ‘Tax and Development: Donor Support to Strengthen Tax Systems in Developing Countries’, Public Administration and Development, 41(3): 115127, https://doi.org/10.1002/pad.1676.Google Scholar
Fossat, P. and Bua, M. (2013), Tax Administration Reform in the Francophone Countries of Sub-Saharan Africa, IMF Working Paper WP/13/173, Washington, DC: IMF, https://doi.org/10.5089/9781475581539.001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankema, E. and Booth, A. (2020), ‘Fiscal Capacity and the Colonial State: Lessons from a Comparative Perspective’, in Frankema, E. and Booth, A. (eds), Fiscal Capacity and the Colonial State in Asia and Africa, c. 1850–1960, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 135.Google Scholar
Frankema, E. and Van Waijenburg, M. (2021), ‘Fiscal Development Under Colonial and Sovereign Rule’, in Genschel, P. and Seelkopf, L. (eds.), Global Taxation: How Modern Taxes Conquered the World, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 6798.Google Scholar
Genschel, P. and Seelkopf, L. (eds.) (2021), Global Taxation: How Modern Taxes Conquered the World, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gerring, J. (1999), ‘What Makes a Concept Good? A Criterial Framework for Understanding Concept Formation in the Social Sciences’, Polity, 31(3): 357393, https://doi.org/10.2307/3235246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gevorkyan, A. V. and Kvangraven, I. H. (2016), ‘Assessing Recent Determinants of Borrowing Costs in Sub-Saharan Africa’, Review of Development Economics, 20(4): 721738, https://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hailu, D. and Kipgen, C. (2017), ‘The Extractives Dependence Index (EDI)’, Resources Policy, 51(March 2017): 251264, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2017.01.004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammond, J. L. (2011), ‘The Resource Curse and Oil Revenues in Angola and Venezuela’, Science & Society, 75(3): 348378, https://doi.org/10.1521/siso.2011.75.3.348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, M., Brandon, P. and Sánchez, R. T. (2018), ‘Introduction: Maximising Revenues, Minimising Political Costs-Challenges in the History of Public Finance of the Early Modern Period’, Financial History Review, 25(1): 118, https://doi.org/10.1017/S096856501800001X.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
He, W. K. (2013), Paths Towards the Modern Fiscal State: England, Japan and China, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, https://doi.org/10.4159/harvard.9780674074637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herbst, J. (2000), States and Power in Africa: Comparative Lessons in Authority and Control, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2019), ‘Taxonomic Definitions in Social Science, with Firms, Markets and Institutions as Case Studies’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 15(2): 207233, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137418000334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IMF (2013), Staff Guidance Note for Public Debt Sustainability Analysis in Market-Access Countries, Guidance Note, Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
IMF (2018), Guidance Note on the Bank-Fund Debt Sustainability Framework for Low Income Countries, Guidance Note, Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
IMF (2021), Senegal. IMF Country Report 21/18, Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
IMF (2022), Senegal. IMF Country Report 22/08, Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
Jensen, A. D. (2011), ‘State-Building in Resource-Rich Economies’, Atlantic Economic Journal, 39(2): 171193, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-011-9269-z.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jeppesen, M. (2021), ‘What We Hoped for and What We Achieved: Tax Performance of Semi-Autonomous Revenue Authorities in Sub-Saharan Africa’, Public Administration and Development, 41(3): 115127, https://doi.org/10.1002/pad.1952.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, N. D. and Koyama, M. (2014), ‘Tax Farming and the Origins of State Capacity in England and France’, Explorations in Economic History, 51(1): 120, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eeh.2013.07.005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1963), ‘Will Underdeveloped Countries Learn to Tax?’, Foreign Affairs, 41(2): 410419, https://doi.org/10.2307/20029626.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karl, T. L. (1997), The Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States, Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Levi, M. (1988), Of Rule and Revenue, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, P. M. (2007), Growing Apart: Oil, Politics, and Economic Change in Indonesia and Nigeria, University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahdavy, H. (1970), ‘The Pattern and Problems of Economic Development in Rentier States: The Case of Iran’, in Cook, M. A. (ed.), Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Martin, I. W., Mehrotra, A. K. and Prasad, M. (2009), ‘The Thunder of History: The Origins and Development of the New Fiscal Sociology’, in Prasad, M., Mehrotra, A. K. and Martin, I. W. (eds), The New Fiscal Sociology: Taxation in Comparative and Historical Perspective, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCormick, D. (2008), ‘China & India as Africa's New Donors: The Impact of Aid on Development’, Review of African Political Economy, 35(115): 7392, https://doi.org/10.1080/03056240802011501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehrotra, A. K. (2013), Making the Modern American Fiscal State: Law, Politics, and the Rise of Progressive Taxation, 1877–1929, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107358263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merriam-Webster (2022), ‘Sustainable’, In Merriam-Webster.com dictionary, Retrieved October 15, 2022, from https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/sustainability.Google Scholar
Mihalyi, D., Adam, A. and Hwang, J. (2020), Resource-Backed Loans: Pitfall and Potential, Natural Resource Governance Institute, February. https://resourcegovernance.org/analysis-tools/publications/resource-backed-loanspitfalls-potential.Google Scholar
Monson, A. and Scheidel, W. (2015), ‘Studying Fiscal Regimes’, in Monson, A. and Scheidel, W. (eds), Fiscal Regimes and the Political Economy of Premodern States, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, M. (2004), ‘Revenues, State Formation, and the Quality of Governance in Developing Countries’, International Political Science Review, 25(3): 297319, https://doi.org/10.1177/0192512104043018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, M. (2021), Glimpses of Fiscal States in Sub-Saharan Africa, WIDER Working Paper 2021/151, Helsinki: UNU-WIDER, https://doi.org/10.35188/UNU-WIDER/2021/091-7.Google Scholar
Moore, M. and Fjeldstad, O.-H. (2008), ‘Tax Reform and State-Building in a Globalised World’, in Bräutigam, D., Moore, M. and Fjeldstad, O.-H. (eds), Taxation and State-Building in Developing Countries, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 235260.Google Scholar
Musgrave, R. A. (1996), ‘The Role of the State in Fiscal Theory’, International Tax and Public Finance, 3(3): 247258, https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00418943.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niang, B. and Mbaye, A. A. (2020), Senegal: Making Domestic Resource Mobilization Work to Sustain Growth and Improve Service Delivery, CGD Policy Paper 165, Washington, DC: Center for Global Development.Google Scholar
North, D. C. and Weingast, B. R. (1989), ‘Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England’, The Journal of Economic History, 49(4): 803832, https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050700009451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, P. K. (2005), Fiscal and Financial Preconditions for the Rise of British Naval Hegemony 1485–1815, Working Paper 91/05, London: Department of Economic History, London School of Economics.Google Scholar
O'Brien, P. K. (2011), ‘The Nature and Historical Evolution of an Exceptional Fiscal State and Its Possible Significance for the Precocious Commercialization and Industrialization of the British Economy From Cromwell to Nelson’, Economic History Review, 64(2): 408446, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0289.2010.00538.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, P. K. and Hunt, P. (2007), ‘The Rise of a Fiscal State in England, 1485–1815’, Historical Research, 66(160): 129176, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2281.1993.tb01806.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ogden, C. K. and Richards, I. A. (1923), The Meaning of Meaning, London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Omeje, K. (2016), ‘Natural Resource Rent and Stakeholder Politics in Africa: Towards a New Conceptualisation’, Commonwealth & Comparative Politics, 54(1): 92114, https://doi.org/10.1080/14662043.2015.1126887.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piano, E. E. and Salter, A. W. (2021), ‘The Fundamental Coase of Development: Property Rights Foundations of the Effective State’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 17(1): 3752, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137420000260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prichard, W. (2015), Taxation, Responsiveness and Accountability in Sub-Saharan Africa, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316275511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ricciuti, R., Savoia, A. and Sen, K. (2018), ‘How Do Political Institutions Affect Fiscal Capacity? Explaining Taxation in Developing Economies’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 15(2): 351380, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137418000097.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, M. L. (2016), ‘The Politics of the Resource Curse: A Review’, in Lancaster, C. and van de Walle, N. (eds), The Oxford Handbook of the Politics of Development, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 200223, https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199845156.013.42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosser, A. (2006), ‘Escaping the Resource Curse’, New Political Economy, 11(4): 557570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sachs, J. and Warner, A. (2000), ‘Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth’, in Meier, G. and Rauch, J. (eds.), Leading Issues in Economic Development, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sandbakken, C. (2006), ‘The Limits to Democracy Posed by Oil Rentier States: The Cases of Algeria, Nigeria and Libya’, Democratisation, 13(1): 135152, https://doi.org/10.1080/13510340500378464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sartori, G. (1970), ‘Concept Misformation in Comparative Politics’, The American Political Science Review, 64(4): 10331053, https://doi.org/10.2307/1958356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savoia, A. and Sen, K. (2021), ‘The Political Economy of the Resource Curse: A Development Perspective’, Annual Review of Resource Economics, 13(1): 203223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, J. (1918 [1954]), ‘The Crisis of the Tax State’, International Economic Papers, (4): 330345.Google Scholar
Smith, G. (2021), Where Credit Is Due: How Africa's Debt Can Be a Benefit, Not a Burden, London: Hurst and Company.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinmo, S. (1993), Taxation and Democracy: Swedish, British and American Approaches to Financing the Modern State, New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Sylla, N. S. (2020), ‘Modern Monetary Theory in the Periphery’, Rosa Luxemburg Stiftung, 26 February, Available at https://www.rosalux.de/en/news/id/41764/modern-monetary-theory-in-the-periphery (accessed 15 November 2021).Google Scholar
Tilly, C. (1992), Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990–1992, Chichester: Wiley-Blackwell.Google Scholar
Timmons, J. F. (2005), ‘The Fiscal Contract: States, Taxes, and Public Services’, World Politics, 57(4): 530567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Torres Sànchez, R. (2007), Constructing a Fiscal-Military State in Eighteenth-Century Spain, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
UNU-WIDER (2021), UNU-WIDER Government Revenue Dataset, Helsinki: UNU-WIDER, Available at https://www.wider.unu.edu/project/government-revenue-dataset.Google Scholar
Waris, A. (2018), ‘Creating and Building a Post-Conflict Fiscal State Through Global Wealth Chains: A Case Study of Somaliland’, Journal of Money Laundering Control, 21(2): 171188. https://doi.org/10.1108/JMLC-05-2017-0019.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watts, M. (2004), ‘Resource Curse? Governmentality, Oil and Power in the Niger Delta, Nigeria’, Geopolitics, 9(1): 5080.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yun-Casalilla, B. (2012), ‘Introduction: The Rise of the Fiscal State in Eurasia from a Global, Comparative and Transnational Perspective’, in Yun-Casalilla, B., O'Brien, P. and Comin, F. (eds), The Rise of Fiscal States: A Global History, 1500–1914, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yun-Casalilla, B., O'Brien, P. and Comin, F. (eds.) (2012), The Rise of Fiscal States: A Global History, 1500–1914, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139004237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, C. (2017), ‘A Fiscal Sociological Theory of Authoritarian Resilience: Developing Theory Through China Case Studies’, Sociological Theory, 35(1): 3963, https://doi.org/10.1177/0735275117693038.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
ZIPAR (2018), Reversing Zambia's High Risk of Debt Distress, Working Paper No. 31, Lusaka: ZIPAR.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Review of conceptual extension and intension of the fiscal state.Source: Authors' construction based on Ogden and Richards' triangle (1923).

Figure 1

Figure 2. Distinguishing between ideal state types defined by their revenue side.Note: The dotted lines are included as figurative indications. The line without an arrow exemplifies when taxes and borrowing become dominant. The line with an arrow exemplifies when a balance is achieved between taxes and borrowing.Source: Authors' construction.