Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-mlc7c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-20T05:20:18.411Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The change in social norms in the Mafia's territories: the anti-racket movement of Addiopizzo

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 September 2020

Francesca Lipari*
Affiliation:
Grupo Interdisciplinar de Sistemas Complejos (GISC), Departamento de Matemáticas, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Leganés, Spain
Giulia Andrighetto
Affiliation:
Institute of Cognitive Sciences and Technologies, Italian National Research Council, Rome, Italy Institute for Futures Studies, Stockholm, Sweden Malardalens University, Vasteras, Sweden
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

Social norms pervade society and when they conflict with legal norms, the former undermine the latter making them ineffective. In this study, we propose that the extortion racket in Sicily has turned into a social norm and this is why recent top-down interventions have failed in stalling this socially undesirable activity. One exception is represented by Addiopizzo, a grass root movement that uses non-legal means to fight the racket phenomenon in Sicily. During the last 15 years, Addiopizzo was able to produce an effective reduction in the payment of protection money in the Sicilian city of Palermo by triggering, we suggest, among other things, a process of change in social norms. Acknowledging the importance of a change in social norms to achieve social change allows us to link the theory of institutions as ‘rules’ with the theory of institutions as ‘equilibria’.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Akerlof, G. A. and Yellen, J. L. (1994), ‘Gang Behavior, Law Enforcement, and Community Values’, in Values and Public Policy, Washington, DC: The Brookings Institute, pp.173209.Google Scholar
Alvord, S. H., Brown, L. D. and Letts, C. W. (2004), ‘Social Entrepreneurship and Societal Transformation: An Exploratory Study’, The Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 40(3): 260282.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. (2001), Towards a Comparative Institutional Analysis, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Apollonio, A. and Montanaro, G. (2015), Il Sistema delle Estorsioni in Puglia. Potere e Legittimazione, Collana Arcipelago: Rubettino Editore.Google Scholar
Arcidiacono, D., Avola, M. and Palidda, R. (2016), Mafia, Estorsioni e Regolazione dell'economia nell'altra Sicilia, Rome: Franco Angeli.Google Scholar
Asmundo, A. and Lisciandra, M. (2008), ‘The Cost of Protection Racket in Sicily’, Global Crime, 9(3): 221240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balletta, L and Lavezzi, A. M. (2019), ‘The Economics of Extortion: Theory and Evidence on the Sicilian Mafia (No. 2019/242)’.Google Scholar
Battisti, M., Lavezzi, A. M., Masserini, L. and Pratesi, M. (2018), ‘Resisting the Extortion Racket: An Empirical Analysis’, European Journal of Law and Economics, 46(1): 137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bicchieri, C. (2006), The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, C. (2016), Norms in the Wild: How to Diagnose, Measure, and Change Social Norms, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, C and Mercier, H (2014), ‘Norms and Beliefs: How Change Occurs’, in The Complexity of Social norms (Vol. 3), Berlin: Springer Verlag, pp. 3754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bicchieri, C., Lindemans, J. W. and Jiang, T. (2014), A Structured Approach to a Diagnostic of Collective Practices. Frontiers in Psychology, 5: 1418. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2014.01418CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Calderoni, F. (2014), ‘Mythical Numbers and the Proceeds of Organised Crime: Estimating Mafia Proceeds in Italy’, Global Crime, 15(1–2): 138163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conte, R., Andrighetto, G. and Campennl, M. (eds.) (2013), Minding Norms: Mechanisms and Dynamics of Social Order in Agent Societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daniele, G. and Geys, B. (2015), ‘Organised Crime, Institutions and Political Quality: Empirical Evidence From Italian Municipalities’, The Economic Journal, 125(586): 233255.Google Scholar
Daniele, V. and Marani, U. (2011), ‘Organized Crime, the Quality of Local Institutions and FDI in Italy: A Panel Data Analysis’, European Journal of Political Economy, 27(1): 132142.Google Scholar
Di Gennaro, G. (2015), Le Estorsioni in Campania. Il Controllo Dello Spazio Sociale tra Violenza e Consenso, Collana Arcipelago: Rubettino Editore.Google Scholar
Dimico, A., Isopi, A. and Olsson, O. (2017), ‘Origins of the Sicilian Mafia: The Market for Lemons’, The Journal of Economic History, 77(4): 10831115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elsenbroich, C., Anzola, D. and Gilbert, N. (eds.) (2016), Social Dimensions of Organised Crime: Modelling the Dynamics of Extortion Rackets, Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Festinger, L. (1957), A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. (1996), ‘A Positive Approach to Organized Consumer Action: The “Buycott” as an Alternative to the Boycott’, Journal of Consumer Policy, 19(4): 439451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gambetta, D. (1988), ‘Mafia: The Price of Distrust’, in Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative relations (Vol. 10), Oxford: Basil Blackwell, pp. 158175.Google Scholar
Gambetta, D. (1993), The Sicilian Mafia: The Business of Private Protection, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gennaro, G. D. and Spina, A. L. (2016), ‘The Costs of Illegality: A Research Programme’, Global Crime, 17(1): 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, M. S. (1973), ‘The Strength of Weak Ties’, The American Journal of Sociology, 78(6): 13601380.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2006), Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons From Medieval Trade, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A and Kingston, C. (2011), ‘Institutions: Rules or Equilibria?’, in Political Economy of Institutions, Democracy and Voting, Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 1343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. and Laitin, D. D. (2004), ‘A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change’, American Political Science Review, 98(4): 633652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gunnarson, C. (2014), ‘Changing the Game: Addiopizzo's Mobilisation Against Racketeering in Palermo’, The European Review of Organised Crime, 1(1): 3977.Google Scholar
Gunnarson, C. (2015), ‘United, yet Divided: Analysing the Cohesion of Addiopizzo's Anti-Racketeering Campaign in Palermo’, Global Crime, 16(2): 139161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haile, G. D (2006), A Study on Community Dialogue Leading Towards Abandoning of Harmful Traditional Practices, with Special Reference to Female Genital Cutting, Early Marriage, and Marriage by Abduction, Ethiopia: UNICEF.Google Scholar
Hill, P. B. (2003), The Japanese Mafia: Yakuza, Law, and the State, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, J. M. (2006), ‘What Are Institutions?’, Journal of Economic Issues, 40(1): 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, L. K. and Patel, R. N. (2017), ‘Collective Action on Corruption in Nigeria: A Social Norms Approach to Connecting Society and Institutions Chatham House Report’.Google Scholar
Insight, I. (2010), ‘The Dynamics of Social Change Towards the Abandonment of Female Genital Mutilation/Cutting in Five African Countries’, Innocenti Insight.Google Scholar
Kingston, C. and Caballero, G. (2009), ‘Comparing Theories of Institutional Change’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 5(2): 151180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1997), ‘Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff? A Cross-Country Investigation’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4): 12511288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Spina, A. (ed.). (2008). I Costi dell'illegalità, Il Mulino, Bologna: Mafia ed estorsioni in Sicilia..Google Scholar
Lavezzi, A. M. (2014), ‘Organised Crime and the Economy: A Framework for Policy Prescriptions’, Global Crime, 15(1–2): 164190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lessig, L. (1995), ‘The Regulation of Social Meaning’, University of Chicago Law Review, 62(3): 943972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, D. D., Junxin, F. and Hongping, J. (2006), ‘Institutional Entrepreneurs’, The American Economic Review, 96(2): 358362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lisciandra, M. (2014), ‘Proceeds From Extortions: The Case of Italian Organised Crime Groups’, Global Crime, 15(1–2): 93107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mackie, G. (1996), ‘Ending Footbinding and Infibulation: A Convention Account’, American Sociological Review, 61(6): 9991017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mete, V. (2018), ‘The Trader Perspective: Researching Extortion in Palermo’, Modern Italy, 23(3): 283298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2005), Understanding Institutional Diversity, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. and Basurto, X. (2011), ‘Crafting Analytical Tools to Study Institutional Change’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 7(3): 317343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paternotte, C. and Grose, J. (2013), ‘Social Norms and Game Theory: Harmony or Discord?’, The British Journal for the Philosophy of Science, 64(3): 551587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pinotti, P. (2015), ‘The Causes and Consequences of Organised Crime: Preliminary Evidence Across Countries’, The Economic Journal, 125(586): 158174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, R. D., Leonardi, R. and Nanetti, R. Y. (1994), Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, New Jersey: Princeton university press.Google Scholar
Rogers, E. M. (1962), Diffusion of Innovations, New York: Free Press of Glencoe.Google Scholar
Savona, E. U. (2012), ‘Italian Mafias’ Asymmetries’, Traditional Organized Crime in the Modern World, Boston, MA: Springer, pp. 325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scaglione, A. (2017), ‘Crime Mapping e Controllo Del Territorio: La Variabile “Addiopizzo”’, in L'apporto Della Geografia tra Rivoluzioni e Riforme. Atti del XXXII Congresso Geografico Italiano (Roma, 7–10 Giugno 2017), pp. 407414.Google Scholar
Scaglione, A. (2020), ‘Social Change and Anti-Mafia Movements: The “Addiopizzo” Variable’, Modern Italy, 25(1): 1731.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sciarrone, R. (2002), The Dark Side of Social Capital: The Case of Mafia, Workshop on Social Capital and Civic Involvement-Cornell University, September 13–14, 2002.Google Scholar
Skarbek, D. (2011), ‘Governance and Prison gangs’, American Political Science Review, 105(4): 702716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Storr, V. H., Grube, L. E. and Haeffele-Balch, S. (2017), ‘Polycentric Orders and Post-Disaster Recovery: A Case Study of one Orthodox Jewish Community Following Hurricane Sandy’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 13(4): 875897.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stuntz, W. (2000), ‘Self-Defeating Crimes’, Virginia Law Review, 86(8): 18711882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Székely, Á., Nardin, L. G. and Andrighetto, G. (2018), ‘Countering Protection Rackets Using Legal and Social Approaches: An Agent-Based Test’, Complexity, 2018: 3568085. https://doi.org/10.1155/2018/3568085CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vaccaro, A. (2012), ‘To Pay or Not to Pay? Dynamic Transparency and the Fight Against the Mafia's Extortionists’, Journal of Business Ethics, 106(1): 2335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vaccaro, A. and Palazzo, G. (2015), ‘Values Against Violence: Institutional Change in Societies Dominated by Organized Crime’, Academy of Management Journal, 58(4): 10751101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varese, F. (2001), The Russian Mafia: Private Protection in a New Market Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vasile, V. (2005), Non ti Pago: Storie di Estorsioni Mafiose e di Antiracket, Milano: L'Unità.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1968), Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, New York: Bedminster Press.Google Scholar
Wenzel, M. (2005), ‘Misperceptions of Social Norms About Tax Compliance: From Theory to Intervention’, Journal of Economic Psychology, 26(6): 862883.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, P. (2009), ‘Illicit Markets, Weak States and Violence: Iraq and Mexico’, Crime Law and Social Change, 52(3): 323336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xenitidou, M. and Edmonds, B. (2014), The Complexity of Social Norms, Berlin: Springer Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xiao, E. and Houser, D. (2011), ‘Punish in Public’, Journal of Public Economics, 95(7–8): 10061017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar