Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T08:56:07.023Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Self-Selection and the Pricing of Bank Services: an Analysis of the Market for Loan Commitments and the Role of Compensating Balance Requirements

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2009

Extract

The idea that various characteristics of financial contracts and institutions can be explained as a rational response to problems created by information asymmetries has received a great deal of attention recently. A central theme of the literature in this area is that while moral hazard may hamper the direct transfer of information between market participants, information may be conveyed indirectly through the actions of market participants. For example, the characteristics of the insurance contract purchased may convey information as to riskiness of the insured. Recognition of the possible effects of information asymmetries has provided valuable insights into the role of financial intermediaries and the characteristics of the contracts they offer. In this paper we apply this literature to an analysis of the market for bank loan commitments. Through our analysis we are able to explain the use of various payment options such as fees and compensating balance requirements associated with loan commitments. Extensions of our analysis into the pricing of other bank services are also explored.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1981

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

[1]Adams, William J., and Yellen, Janet. “Commodity Bundling and the Burden of Monopoly.” Quarterly Journal of Economics (08 1976), pp. 475498.Google Scholar
[2]Akerlof, G.The Market for ‘Lemons’: Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 87 (08 1976), pp. 488500.Google Scholar
[3]Campbell, Tim S.A Model of the Market for Lines of Credit.” Journal of Finance (03 1978), pp. 231245.Google Scholar
[4]Campbell, Tim S., and Boltz, Paul W.. “Innovations in Bank Loan Contracting: Recent Evidence.” Staff Studies #104, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (05 1979).Google Scholar
[5]Campbell, Tim S., and Brendsel, Leland. “The Impact of Compensating Balance Requirements on the Cash Balance of Manufacturing Corporations: An Empirical Study.” Journal of Finance (03 1977), pp. 3141.Google Scholar
[6]Grossman, Hershel I.Adverse Selection Dissembling and Competitive Equilibrium.” Bell Journal of Economics (Spring 1979), pp. 336343.Google Scholar
[7]Guttentag, Jack, and Davis, Richard. “Balance Requirements and Deposit Competition.” Journal of Political Economy (12 1963), pp. 581585.Google Scholar
[8]Hodgman, Donald. “The Deposit Relationship and Commercial Bank Investment Behavior.” Review of Economics and Statistics (08 1961), pp. 257268.Google Scholar
[9]Jaffee, Dwight, and Russell, Thomas. “Imperfect Information, Uncertainty and Credit Rationing.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 90 (1976), pp. 651666.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[10]James, Christopher. “Loan Rate Indexation and the Allocation of Bank Credit.’ Working paper, University of Oregon (1980).Google Scholar
[11]Kolodny, Richard; Seeley, Peter; and Polakoff, Murray. “The Effect of Compensating Balance Requirements on the Profitability of Borrowers and Lenders.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis (12 1977), pp. 801817.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[12]Leland, Haynes E., and Pyle, David H.. “Information Asymmetries, Financial Structure and Financial Intermediation.” Journal of Finance (05 1977), pp. 371387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[13]Mayers, David, and Smith, Clifford. “Towards a Positive Theory of Insurance.” Working paper, University of California – Los Angeles (1976).Google Scholar
[14]Munn, Glenn G. “The Twenty Percent Rule or Why Bankers Keep a Part of the Money They Lend.” Banker's Magazine (02 1922).Google Scholar
[15]Mullin, David Wiley. “Restrictions on the Rate of Interest on Demand Deposits and the Theory of Compensating Balances.” Journal of Finance (05 1976), pp. 233255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[16]Orr, Daniel. “A Note on the Uselessness of Transaction Demand Models.” Journal of Finance (1974), pp. 15651572.Google Scholar
[17]Riley, J.Competitive Signaling.” Journal of Economic Theory (04 1975), pp. 174186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[18]Ross, S. A.The Determination of Financial Structure: The Incentive Signaling Approach.” The Bell Journal of Economics (Spring 1977), pp. 2341.Google Scholar
[19]Rothchild, Michael, and Stiglitz, J.. “Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information.” Quarterly Journal of Economics (1976), pp. 629650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[20]Salop, J., and Salop, Steven. “Self-Selection and Turnover in the Labor Market.” Quarterly Journal of Economics (1976), pp. 619628.Google Scholar
[21]Severson, Gary. “Determining Pricing Alternatives.” Journal of Commercial Bank Lending (11 1974), pp. 28.Google Scholar
[22]Sprenkle, Case. “The Uselessness of Transaction Demand Models.” Journal of Finance (12 1969), pp. 835847.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[23]Wrightsman, Dwayne. “On the Rationality of Compensating Balance Requirements.” Southern Economic Journal (01 1973), pp. 427430.Google Scholar