Hostname: page-component-cc8bf7c57-j4qg9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-11T22:15:56.890Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Portfolio Selection and Purchasing Power Risk–Recent Canadian Experience

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 October 2009

Extract

This paper examined the empirical consequences of explicit consideration of purchasing power risk in portfolio decisions. It was shown that, during a period of significant inflation, the differences between the variance-covariance relations of nominal rates of return and those of real rates of return were sufficiently pronounced to change the composition of investment portfolios. Further, it was shown that the set of real efficient portfolios dominates any investment strategy that ignores purchasing power risk.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1976

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

[1]Biger, N. “Real Returns, Portfolio Decisions and the Capital Asset Pricing Model,” Unpublished Doctoral Dissertation, York University (1974).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[2]Black, F.; Jensen, M.; and Scholes, M.. “The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Some Empirical Results,” In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, edited by Jensen, M.. New York: Praeger (1972).Google Scholar
[3]Cramer, H.Mathematical Methods of Statistics. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press (1946).Google Scholar
[4]Fama, E. F.The Behavior of Stock Market Prices.” Journal of Business, vol. 38 (January 1965), pp. 35105.Google Scholar
[5]Fama, E. F.Short-term Interest Rates as Predictors of Inflation.” Working Paper, The University of Chicago (1973).Google Scholar
[6]Fisher, I.The Theory of Interest. New York (1930).Google Scholar
[7]Gordon, M. J., and Halpern, P. M.. “The Capital Asset Pricing under Inflation.” Working Paper, The University of Toronto (1974).Google Scholar
[8]Lintner, J.Security Prices, Risk, and Maximal Gains from Diversification.” Journal of Finance, vol. 20 (December 1965), pp. 587615.Google Scholar
[9]Lintner, J. “Inflation and Common Stock Prices in a Cyclical Context.” 53rd Annual Report, National Bureau of Economic Research Inc. (September 1973), pp. 2336.Google Scholar
[10]Long, J. B. Jr.Stock Prices, Inflation and the Term Structure of Interest Rates.” Working Paper series No. 7310, Graduate School of Management, University of Rochester (April 1973).Google Scholar
[11]Markowitz, H. M.Portfolio Selection.” Journal of Finance, vol. 7 (March 1952), pp. 7791.Google Scholar
[12]Markowitz, H. M.Portfolio Selection. New York: John Wiley & Sons (1959).Google Scholar
[13]Mossin, J.Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market.” Econometrica, vol. 34 (1966), pp. 768783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[14]Sarnat, M.Purchasing Power Risk, Portfolio Analysis and the Case of Index-Linked Bonds.” Journal of Money Credit and Banking (1973), pp. 836845.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[15]Sarnat, M.“Inflation and Portfolio Selection.”Presented to the XX International Meeting of the Institute of Management Sciences,Israel(June 1973).Google Scholar
[16]Sharpe, W. F.Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk.” Journal of Finance, vol. 19 (September 1964), pp. 425442.Google Scholar
[17]Sharpe, W. F.Mutual Fund Performance.” Journal of Business, vol. 39 (January 1966).Google Scholar