Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-8bhkd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T00:03:49.043Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Microeconomics of Market Making

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2009

Abstract

This paper examines the influence of risk aversion on the pricing policies of a market maker for securities. It is shown that a market maker's bid-ask spread can be decomposed into a portion for the known limit orders, a risk-neutral adjustment for expected market orders, and a risk adjustment for market order and inventory value uncertainty. It is demonstrated that a risk-averse market maker may set a smaller spread than a risk-neutral specialist. Finally, this paper demonstrates the pervasive role of inventory in affecting both the placement and size of the spread.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1986

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

[1]Amihud, Y., and Mendelson, H.. “Dealership Market: Market Making with Uncertainty.” Journal of Financial Economics, 8 (03 1980), 3154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[2]Blume, L.; Easley, D.; and O'Hara, M.. “Characterization of Optimal Plans for Stochastic Dynamic Programs.” Journal of Economic Theory, 28 (12 1982), 221234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[3]Bradfield, J.A Formal Dynamic Model of Market Making.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 14 (06 1979), 275291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[4]Bradfield, J.Optimal Dynamic Behavior of a Market-Maker in Choosing Bid and Asked Prices.” Journal of Economics and Business, 34 (1982), 303316CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[5]Burdett, K., and O'Hara, M.. “Building Blocks: An Introduction to Block Trading.” Working Paper, Cornell Univ. (12 1983).Google Scholar
[6]Cohen, K.; Maier, S.; Schwartz, R.; and Whitcomb, D.. “Transactions Costs, Order Placement Strategy, and Existence of the Bid-Ask Spread.” Journal of Political Economy, 89 (04 1981), 287305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[7]Demsetz, H.The Cost of Transacting.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82 (02 1968), 3353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[8]Feller, W.An Introducton to Probability Theory and Its Applications. Vol. II, 2nd Ed., New York: John Wiley & Sons (1971).Google Scholar
[9]Garman, M. B.Market Microstructure.” Journal of Financial Economics, 3 (06 1976), 257275.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[10]Ho, T., and Stoll, H.. “Optimal Dealer Pricing under Transactions and Return Uncertainty.” Journal of Financial Economics, 9 (03 1981), 4773.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[11]Smith, V.Bidding Theory and the Treasury Bill Auction: Does Price Discrimination Increase Bill Prices?Review of Economics and Statistics, 48 (05 1966), 141146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[12]Smidt, S.Continuous vs. Intermittent Trading on Auction Markets.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 14 (11 1979), 837866.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[13]Tinic, S., and West, R.. “The Securities Industry under Negotiated Brokerage Commissions: Changes in the Structure and Performance of New York Stock Exchange Member Firms.” Bell Journal of Economics, 11 (Spring 1980), 2941.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[14]Zabel, E.Competitive Price Adjustment without Market Clearing.” Econometrica, 49 (09 1981), 12011221.Google Scholar