Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T08:14:58.450Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Generalized Rate of Return**

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 October 2009

Extract

Investment analysis, both for purposes of capital expenditures and for financial investments, is based on an evaluation of cash flows. This evaluation involves the application of interest rates in order to determine whether a given option–a series of cash flows–is profitable or not. For numerous reasons, primarily that of simplicity, it has been traditional to assume that the rates of interest used to measure the worth of an investment are constant. With this assumption it is possible to equate the two familiar investment criteria when investments are independent and outlays are not subject to expenditure constraints, i.e., when capital markets are taken to be perfect in the usual sense. An investment is profitable if its net present value is positive when discounting of cash flows uses the (assumed constant) cost of capital, or if its (assumed unique) internal rate of return is greater than the cost of capital. Equivalence of these two criteria is historically most frequently identified with Irving Fisher [3, 4], and his two-period analysis, portrayed graphically, is generally utilized to establish the correctness of the equivalence of the criteria.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1966

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1.Durand, D., Basic Yields of Corporate Bonds, 1900–1942, Technical Paper 3 (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1942).Google Scholar
2.Durand, D., and Winn, W. J., Basic Yields of Bonds, 1926–1947: Their Measurement and Pattern, Technical Paper 6 (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1947).Google Scholar
3.Fisher, I., The Theory of Interest. (New York: Macmillan Company, 1930).Google Scholar
4.Hirshleifer, J., “On the Theory of Optimal Investment,” Journal of Political Economy (August, 1958), pp. 329352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
5.Kessel, R., The Cyclical Behavior of the Term Structure Of Interest Rates, Occasional Paper 91 (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1965).Google Scholar
6.Meiselman, D., The Term Structure of Interest Rates (Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1962).Google Scholar
7.Weingaxtner, H. M., “The Excess Present Value Index—A Theoretical Basis and Critique,” Journal of Accounting Research (Fall, 1963), pp. 213224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
8.Williams, A. C., and Nasser, J. I., “Financial Measurement of Capital Investments,” Management Science (forthcoming).Google Scholar