Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-lj6df Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T08:26:29.700Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Behavioral Capital Asset Pricing Theory

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2009

Abstract

This paper develops a capital asset pricing theory in a market where noise traders interact with information traders. Noise traders are traders who commit cognitive errors while information traders are free of cognitive errors. The theory includes the determination of the mean-variance efficient frontier, the return on the market portfolio, the term structure, and option prices. The paper derives a necessary and sufficient condition for the existence of price efficiency in the presence of noise traders and analyzes the effects of noise traders on price efficiency, volatility, return anomalies, volume, and noise trader survival.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1994

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

R., Ball, and Kothari, S. P.. “Non-Stationary Expected Returns: Implications for Tests of Market Efficiency and Serial Correlation in Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics, 25 (1989), 5174.Google Scholar
Banz, R. W.The Relation between Return and Market Value of Common Stocks.” Journal of Financial Economics, 9 (1981), 318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basu, S.The Relationship between Earnings Yield, Market Value, and Return for NYSE Common Stocks: Further Evidence.” Journal of Financial Economics, 12 (1983), 129156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, D.The Crash of 87: Was it Expected? The Evidence from Options Markets.” Journal of Finance, 46 (3, 1991), 10091044.Google Scholar
Beja, A.State Preference and the Riskless Interest Rate: A Markov Model of Capital Markets.” Review of Economic Studies, 46 (149, 1978), 435446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benninga, S., and Protopapadakis, A.. “Real and Nominal Interest Rates under Uncertainty: The Fisher Theorem and the Term Structure.” Journal of Political Economy, 91 (5, 1983), 856867.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benninga, S., and Mayshar, J.. “Dynamic Wealth Redistribution, Trade, and Asset Pricing.” Working Paper, Wharton School (1993).Google Scholar
Black, F.Noise.” Journal of Finance, 41 (3, 1986), 529543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blume, L., and Easley, D.. “Evolution and Market Behavior.” Journal of Economic Theory, 58 (1, 1992), 940.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, R., and Schaefer, S.. “The Term Structure of Real Interest Rates and the Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross Model.” Journal of Financial Economics, 35 (1994), 342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C.Do Biases in Probability Judgment Matter in Markets? Experimental Evidence.” American Economic Review, 77 (5, 1987), 981997.Google Scholar
Camerer, C.Does the Basketball Market Believe in the Hot Hand?American Economic Review, 79 (5, 1989), 12571261.Google Scholar
Campbell, J. Y., and Shiller, R. J.. “Stock Prices, Earnings, and Expected Dividends.” Journal of Finance, 43 (3, 1988), 661676.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canina, L., and Figlewski, S.. “The Informational Content of Implied Volatility.” Review of Financial Studies, 6 (3, 1993), 659681.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chan, L. K. C., and Lakonishok, J.. “Are the Reports of Beta's Death Premature?The Journal of Portfolio Management, 19 (1993), 5162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chopra, N.; Lakonishok, J.; and Ritter, J.. “Performance Measurement Methodology and the Question of Whether Stocks Overreact.” Journal of Financial Economics, 31 (1992), 235268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J. C.; Ingersoll, J.; and Ross, S.. “A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates.” Econometrica, 53 (2, 1985), 385408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J. C.; Ross, S. A.; and Rubinstein, M.. “Option Pricing: A Simplified Approach.” Journal of Financial Economics, 7 (1979), 229263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Bondt, W. F. M.Stock Price Reversals and Overreaction to News Events: A Survey of Theory and Evidence.” Working Paper, Univ. of Wisconsin (1988).Google Scholar
De Bondt, W. F. M., and Bange, M.. “Inflation, Money Illusion, and Time Variation in Term Premia.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 27 (4, 1992), 479496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Bondt, W. F. M., and Thaler, R.. “Does the Stock Market Overreact? Journal of Finance, 40 (1985), 793805.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Bondt, W. F. M., and Thaler, R.. “New Evidence on Investor Overreaction and January Excess Returns?Journal of Finance, 42 (1987), 557581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Bondt, W. F. M., and Thaler, R.. “A Mean Reverting Walk down Wall Street.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3 (1, 1989), 189202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Bondt, W. F. M., and Thaler, R.. “Do Security Analysts Overreact?“” Working Paper, Cornell Univ. (1989).Google Scholar
De Long, J.; Shleifer, A.; Summers, L.; and Waldmann, R.. The Survival of Noise Traders in Financial Markets.” Working Paper, Univ. of Chicago (1988).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Long, J.; Shleifer, A.; Summers, L.; and Waldmann, R.. “The Size and Incidence of the Losses from Noise Trading.” Journal of Finance, 44 (3, 1989), 681696.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Long, J.; Shleifer, A.; Summers, L.; and Waldmann, R.. “Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets.” Journal of Political Economy, 98 (4, 1990a), 703738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Long, J.; Shleifer, A.; Summers, L.; and Waldmann, R.. “Positive Feedback Investment Strategies and Destabilizing Rational Expectations.” Journal of Finance, 45 (2, 1990b), 379395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffie, D., and Huang, C.. “Implementing Arrow-Debreu Equilibria by Continuous Trading of a Few Long-Lived Securities.” Econometrica, 53 (6, 1985), 13371356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Einhorn, H. J., and Hogarth, R.. “Confidence in Judgment: Persistence in the Illusion of Validity.” Psychological Review, 85 (5, 1978), 395416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, E., and French, K.. “Permanent and Temporary Components of Stock Prices.” Journal of Political Economy, 96 (1988), 246273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, E., and French, K.. “The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns.” The Journal of Finance, 47 (2, 1992), 427465.Google Scholar
Feller, W.An Introduction to Probability Theory and its Applications, Third Edition. New York, NY: Wiley (1967).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferson, W., and Harvey, C.. “The Variation of Economic Risk Premiums.” Journal of Political Economy, 99 (1991), 385415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figlewski, S.Market ‘Efficiency’ in a Market with Heterogeneous Information.” Journal of Political Economy, 86 (1978), 581597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figlewski, S.Information Diversity and Market Behavior.” Journal of Finance, 37 (1982), 87102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, M. “The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates.” In Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press (1953).Google Scholar
Gallant, A. R.; Rossi, P.; and Tauchen, G.. “Stock Prices and Stock Volume.” Review of Financial Studies, 5 (2, 1992), 199242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, M., and Ramaswamy, K.. “A Test of the Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross Model of the Term Structure.” Review of Financial Studies, 6 (3, 1993), 619658CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilovich, T.; Vallone, R.; and Tversky, A.. “The Hot Hand in Basketball; on the Misperception of Random Sequences.” Cognitive Psychology, 17 (1985), 295314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffe, J.Special Information and Insider Trading.” Journal of Business, 47 (3, 1974), 410428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffe, J., and Winkler, R.. “Optimal Speculation against an Efficient Market.” Journal of Finance, 39 (1976), 4961.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D.; Slovic, P.; and Tversky, A.. Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press (1982).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karpoff, J.A Theory of Trading Volume.” Journal of Finance, 41 (5, 1986), 10691088.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karpoff, J.The Relation between Price Changes and Trading Volume: A Survey.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 22 (1, 1987), 109123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleidon, A.Anomolies in Financial Economics: Blueprint for Change?Journal of Business, 59 (2, 1986), 469499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, A.A Direct Test of the Cognitive Bias Theory of Share Price Reversals.” Working Paper, New York Univ. (1990).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kyle, A.Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading.” Econometrica, 53 (1985), 13151336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lang, L. H.; Litzenberger, R.; and Madrigal, V.. “Testing Financial Market Equilibrium under Asymmetric Information.” Journal of Political Economy, 100 (2, 1992), 317348.Google Scholar
Lee, C.; Shleifer, A.; and Thaler, R.. “Investor Sentiment and the Closed-End Puzzle.” Journal of Finance, 46 (1991), 75109.Google Scholar
LeRoy, S., and Porter, R.. “The Present Value Relation: Tests Based on Implied Variance Bounds.” Econometrica, 49 (1981), 555674.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lo, A., and McKinley, A. C.. “Stock Market Prices Do Not Follow Random Walks: Evidence from a Simple Specification Test.” Review of Financial Studies, 1 (1988), 4146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madan, D.; Milne, F.; and Shefrin, H.. “The Multinomial Option Pricing Model and Its Brownian and Poisson Limits.” Review of Financial Studies, 2 (2, 1989), 251265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marsh, T., and Meiton, R.. “Dividend Variability and Variance Bounds Tests for the Rationality of Stock Market Prices.” American Economic Review, 76 (3, 1986), 483498.Google Scholar
Mayshar, J.On Divergence of Opinion and Imperfections in Capital Markets.” American Economic Review, 73 (1983), 114128.Google Scholar
Mehra, R., and Prescott, E. C.. “The Equity Premium Puzzle.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 40 (1985), 145161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radner, R.On the Existence of Plans, Prices, and Price Expectations.” Econometrica, 15 (1972), 289303CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritter, J.The Buying and Selling Behavior of Individuals at the Turn of the Year.” Journal of Finance, 43 (3, 1988), 701716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogalski, R., and Tinic, S.. “The January Size Effect: Anomaly or Risk Mismeasurement? Financial Analysts Journal, 42 (1986), 6370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P.The ‘Fallacy’ of Maximizing the Geometric Mean in Long Sequences of Investing or Gambling.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 68 (1971), 207210.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Seyhun, H.Insiders Profits, Costs of Trading, and Market Efficiency.” Journal of Financial Economics, 16 (2, 1986), 189212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shefrin, H.On the Combinatorial Structure of Bayesian Learning with Imperfect Information.” Discrete Mathematics, 37 (1981), 245254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shefrin, H.Markov Chains, Imperfect State Information, and Bayesian Learning.” Mathematical Modelling, 4 (1983), 17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shefrin, H.Inferior Forecasters, Cycles, and the Efficient-Markets Hypothesis: A Comment.” Journal of Political Economy, 92 (1984), 156161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shefrin, H., and Statman, M.. “How Not to Make Money in the Stock Market.” Psychology Today, 20 (02 1986), 5257.Google Scholar
Shiller, R. J.Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to be Justified by Subsequent Changes in Dividends?American Economic Review, 71 (1981), 421436.Google Scholar
Shiller, R. J.Stock Prices and Social Dynamics.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, (1984), 457498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solt, M., and Statman, M.. “How Useful is the Sentiment Index? Financial Analysts Journal, 44 (1988), 4555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solt, M., and Statman, M.. “Good Companies, Bad Stocks.” Journal of Portfolio Management, 15 (1989), 3944.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stein, J.Overreactions in the Options Market.” Journal of Finance, 44 (4, 1989), 10111023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Summers, L. H.Do We Really Know that Financial Markets are Efficient?Journal of Finance, 41 (1986), 591602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tinic, S., and West, R.. “Risk and Returns: January vs. Rest of the Year.” Journal of Financial Economics, 13 (1984), 561574.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trueman, B.A Theory of Noise Trading in Securities Markets.” Journal of Finance, 43 (1, 1988), 8395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D.. “Belief in the Law of Small Numbers.” Psychological Bulletin, 76 (1971), 105110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D.. “Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases.” Science, 185 (1974), 11241131.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Varian, H.Divergence of Opinion in Complete Markets: A Note.” Journal of Finance, 40 (1, 1985), 309317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
West, K. D.Bubbles, Fads, and Stock Price Volatility Tests: A Partial Evaluation.” Journal of Finance, 43 (1988), 639656.CrossRefGoogle Scholar