Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gbm5v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T19:03:14.924Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Transparent Corruption: The Effect of Illicit Connections and Trusted References on the Demand for Bureaucratic Intermediation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 October 2024

José Ramon Morales-Arilla*
Affiliation:
Escuela de Gobierno y Transformacion Publica, Tecnologico de Monterrey, Mexico City, Mexico
Ana Ibarra
Affiliation:
School of Economics, Universidad Católica Andrés Bello, Caracas, Venezuela
*
Corresponding author: José Ramon Morales-Arilla; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This article investigates the effect of priming the existence of corrupt connections to the bureaucracy and of trusted references on the demand for intermediary services. We performed an experimental survey with undergraduate students in Caracas, Venezuela. Participants are presented with a hypothetical situation in which they need to obtain the apostille of their professional degrees in order to migrate and are considering whether to hire an intermediary (“gestor”) or not. The survey randomly reveals the existence of an illicit connection between the gestor and the bureaucracy and whether a trusted individual referred the intermediary. Our findings are not consistent with the “market maker” hypothesis that revealing the existence of illicit connections increases demand. Consistent with the view that trust is a key element in inherently opaque transactions, we find that the demand for intermediaries is price inelastic when gestores are referred by trusted individuals.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of American Political Science Association

Introduction

Bureaucratic corruption remains a key government failure in developing countries. Its high prevalence is a consequence of weak institutions that distort public and private resource allocation (Fisman and Golden, Reference Fisman and Golden2017; Svensson, Reference Svensson2005; Tanzi, Reference Tanzi1998). From a citizen’s perspective, however, bureaucratic corruption is often seen as a second-best strategy to “grease the wheels” of the bureaucracy and overcome constraints on the provision of government services. While bureaucratic intermediation services are not inherently corrupt (Graf Lambsdorff, Reference Graf Lambsdorff2013), intermediaries seem to play a relevant part in magnifying bureaucratic corruption in the developing world (Wiehen, Reference Wiehen1999; Bertrand et al., Reference Bertrand, Djankov, Hanna and Mullainathan2007). Beyond their potential role as “market makers” that match citizens to bureaucrats, intermediaries can also reduce the “moral costs” of ultimately corrupt acts by allowing citizens to remain detached from – and potentially unaware of – bribes (Hasker and Okten, Reference Hasker and Okten2008; Hamman et al., Reference Hamman, Loewenstein and Weber2010; Bartling and Fischbacher, Reference Bartling and Fischbacher2012; Coffman, Reference Coffman2011). These two theories yield opposing predictions whenever intermediaries are transparent about their illicit connections to the bureaucracy: While their role as “market makers” requires these connections, transparency over their existence should increase perceived risks and “moral costs”.

This article investigates the effect of priming the existence of corrupt connections to the bureaucracy on the demand for intermediary services and on its price elasticity. Moreover, we assess whether the effects of corruption suggestions are contingent on trusted references to the intermediary and whether such references attenuate price elasticities. We focus on the case of “gestores” (intermediaries) for the apostille of professional degrees in Venezuela. This setting is appropriate to tackle this question, due to the high demand from young professionals choosing to migrate out of the country and low state capacity for the timely certification of degrees by Venezuela’s Foreign Ministry. We propose an experimental survey on Venezuelan undergraduate students. In a hypothetical scenario in which the students need to have their degrees certified in a narrow window of time, and they consider hiring a gestor, we randomly reveal the presence of an illicit bureaucratic connection, the intermediary service fee and whether the gestor was referred by a trusted individual.Footnote 1

Anecdotal evidence from Venezuela suggests that intermediaries often reveal that their work operates through an illicit connection to the bureaucracy in an attempt to market the “quality” of their services to potential clients. We believe gestores follow this “market maker” logic because it dominates “moral” considerations in the Venezuelan institutional environment. For this reason, we preregistered three hypotheses consistent with the “market maker” perspective. First, we hypothesized that gestores that reveal their illicit connections to the bureaucracy should observe a higher demand for their services. Second, we conjectured that the demand for intermediary services should be relatively price inelastic when gestores reveal an illicit connection to the bureaucracy, as we believe such connections represent a marker for the “quality” of the service. Finally, we posited that the effect of revealing an illicit connection to the bureaucracy on intermediary demand should be strongest (or contingent on) when the gestor is referred to the client by a trusted individual, as such references may resolve the credibility concerns raised by unknown intermediaries offering an inherently illicit service. Our results regarding these three preregistered hypotheses are inconclusive.Footnote 2 However, in a non-preregistered analysis, we find that trusted references to the gestor erode the price elasticity of the demand for their services. This important result is consistent with the view that trust plays a crucial role in the demand for opaque and illegal services.Footnote 3

Our study contributes to the experimental literature on corruption by assessing critical determinants in the demand for intermediary services in the developing world.Footnote 4 Given the ubiquity of intermediaries in the developing world and their apparent role in the mechanics of petty corruption (Bertrand et al., Reference Bertrand, Djankov, Hanna and Mullainathan2007), the empirical literature on the topic is scant. Setting an important precedent, Drugov et al. (Reference Drugov, Hamman and Serra2014) found that intermediaries induce higher levels of corruption by “normalizing” or “institutionalizing” corruption.Footnote 5 We contribute to this literature by studying the determinants of the demand for intermediary services in institutionally underdeveloped environments. We compare the take-up of gestor services for groups receiving different information about the service. In particular, we evaluate whether the demand for gestores is affected by suggestions of corruption and by the presence of a trusted reference and find that the latter is an important determinant of the demand for intermediaries and its price elasticity. Focusing on college students in the Venezuelan context is essential, as this segment of the population has a high demand for migration-related documents and certifications from a government with limited capacities to process that demand. Moreover, while our experiment is hypothetical, gestores do play a key role in participants’ actual institutional environment. This makes our results prescient for settings in which intermediaries are seen as ubiquitous and necessary to gain access to services from the bureaucracy.

Context

Venezuela currently stands as the country with the fourth highest perception of corruption worldwide (Transparency International, 2022). We focus on the study of petty corruption in bureaucratic services on the case of intermediaries or gestores in the apostille process for professional degrees. Given infrastructure and resource limitations, Venezuelans face multiple obstacles that prevent them from gaining access to government services, including those that are part of their fundamental rights as citizens. According to Bolivar and Rodríguez (Reference Bolivar and Rodríguez2021):

The exercise of many rights depends on obtaining certain documents, such as the identity card or birth certificate for identification; the passport for free international transit; […] among others. The restrictions on the enjoyment of rights begin for many Venezuelans in their own country, to the extent that the State does not produce the documents that it is obliged to issue or does so extremely slowly, which generates access barriers that only seem to be surmountable through acts of corruption. (p. 4)

Due to the economic, political, and humanitarian crises that intensified in the country between 2016 and 2017, many Venezuelans have chosen to emigrate in search of better opportunities (Transparencia Venezuela, 2021). For citizens whose emigration is oriented toward achieving their academic or professional career, the apostille of documents is an essential requirement. According to Bolivar and Rodríguez (Reference Bolivar and Rodríguez2021):

For most documents to be valid outside the country, their veracity must be certified by means of an apostille. In Venezuela, this procedure is carried out through the Ministry of Foreign Affairs. As in the case of identification documents, the apostille process lost transparency […] during the last decade, due to excessive delays that led to the use of agents and acts of corruption. Consequently, the apostille became a difficult procedure to carry out. (p. 9)

Regardless of the efforts made to automate the apostille process in Venezuela to avoid corruption and the use of gestores, obstacles to carrying out the procedures continue to be a significant constraint for citizens, creating a market for intermediaries.Footnote 6 In addition, access to virtual platforms remains limited and unstable, as Venezuela has the worst quality of internet services in the region.Footnote 7

While gestores’ services are legal in principle – as long as they limit their actions to carrying out the process of requesting appointments or withdrawing client documents – the use of contacts within the bureaucracy to “speed up” a process implies corrupt and illegal behavior.Footnote 8 Given the secretive nature of such corrupt behavior, the links between private clients and gestores are often established through direct recommendations from an individual’s social circle. Therefore, the market for intermediation in Venezuela usually spreads through direct references, helping gestores and their associated bureaucrats keep a low profile.

Research design

Survey characteristics

We performed an experimental survey around a hypothetical situation between a client and an intermediary. The survey was distributed through Qualtrics to students at Universidad Católica Andrés Bello (UCAB) in Caracas, Venezuela. Importantly, faculty authorities were contacted to request their support in disseminating the survey through institutional e-mails and official communication channels to all undergraduate students. Additionally, kiosks were placed in different areas of the university, where willing participants were provided the participation link for them to respond to the survey.Footnote 9

Survey protocol

In the initial step of the data collection process, undergraduate students from each faculty received an invitation and were encouraged to submit their answers remotely. The participant who started the survey was presented with an informational consent form in which all the implications and disclosable information of the study were displayed.Footnote 10 Participants were told that the project was about the demand for intermediation services in the procurement of bureaucratic services without explicitly referencing corruption.Footnote 11 Upon acceptance, participants filled out three main survey sections.

  1. 1. In the first part, the participant was presented with a hypothetical situation. In this situation, the participant was accepted for a job abroad and needed to apostille her academic documents, but due to time and information constraints, she is considering using intermediary services. Participants are shown a random script of her conversation with a possible gestor, in which they are presented with information about the intermediary’s fee, the suggestion of an illicit connection within the bureaucracy, whether an acquaintance introduced the intermediary, the speed of the process and the intermediary’s experience. These treatments were independently randomized across surveyees (see Table A1 for a description of each treatment). After being presented with the situation, the participant was asked if she would pay for the intermediary’s service in a “take-it-or-leave-it” scenario. Additionally, the participant was asked if she would have bargained and the highest price she would have been willing to pay for the service.

  2. 2. The second part consisted of three questions regarding the participant’s desire to emigrate, previous experience with intermediaries, and whether she would characterize the prior experience as good, neutral, or bad.

  3. 3. The third part consisted of questions regarding the demographic and academic characteristics of the participant.

Participants filled out their responses over a two-week period between September 21 and October 5, 2022. Survey information was collected in a fully anonymous manner. Fig. A1 outlines the intervention procedure for the control and treatment groups.

Power calculations and sample size

We conducted power calculations to assess the sample sizes necessary to achieve 80% statistical power under sensible assumptions for the minimum detectable effects (MDE) in our estimations. Our initial test evaluates the effect of random, balanced binary treatments on a binary take-up outcome. Our calculations suggest that in order to detect a 10 percentage point effect of such a treatment under a baseline take-up of 70%, we required a sample size of at least 146 observations. In our subsequent tests, we consider two-way interactions between random, balanced, and binary treatments on a binary take-up outcome. We leverage the methodology outlined in Sommet (Reference Sommet2022) to perform power calculations in this context. In order to be sufficiently powered to detect the effect of an interaction term, we require a sample of 502 observations. Our main sample of 567 observations captures information from all participants who finished the survey.Footnote 12 In order to gain further precision in our causal estimates, we also incorporate surveyees’ demographic and academic covariates into our estimation methodology.

Results and analysis

Each survey participant was randomly assigned to either a treatment group or a control group in each of the treatment branches.Footnote 13 In this section, we outline our three main hypotheses and the results of our analyses.Footnote 14 Table A2 provides summary statistics for variables connected to the first two sections of the survey. Table A3 provides balance tests over sociodemographic variables, confirming that our procedures effectively randomize all five treatment branches. Finally, Table A4 shows that participants who did not finish the survey after being assigned a script were balanced across treatment and control groups for all treatment branches, suggesting that differential attrition is not a concern in our study.

Effects of corruption suggestions on take-up

Since the outcome of interest is whether the participant decides to pay for the intermediary’s service, we assessed the average effect of corruption suggestions on take-up by performing the following linear probability model (LPMs):Footnote 15

(1) $${Y_i} = {\beta _0} + {\beta _1}Corruptio{n_i} + {\varepsilon _i}$$

${Y_i}$ is a binary marker for whether participant $i$ decides to take the service, and $Corruptio{n_i}$ is a binary marker for the corruption suggestion treatment. ${\beta _1}$ captures the average effect of a suggestion of corruption on the probability of agency service take-up. We assess the statistical significance of our estimates using robust standard errors.

Consistent with the “market maker” view of intermediaries, we hypothesize that estimates for ${\beta _1}$ should be positive and significant. Table 1 provides four estimates for ${\beta _1}$ . Column (1) provides the simplest specification described in Equation (1). Column (2) adds sociodemographic covariates. Column (3) controls for other treatment branches. Finally, Column (4) controls both for covariates and other treatment branches. Our estimates for ${\beta _1}$ are all negative and statistically insignificant, suggesting that they are inconsistent with the “market maker” hypothesis, but also not conclusively consistent with the “moral cost” perspective. Fig. 1 confirms the statistically indistinguishable take-up rates across treatment branches.

Table 1. Effect of corruption suggestions on take-up

Notes: Table shows estimates for ${\beta _1}$ in Equation (1). Column (1) provides the simplest specification described in Equation (1). Column (2) adds sociodemographic covariates. Column (3) controls for other treatment branches. Finally, Column (4) controls for both covariates and other treatments. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. Standard errors are specified in parentheses, and exact p-values are reported between brackets. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01$ .

Figure 1. Take-up rate by corruption suggestion category.

Notes: Figure shows the intermediary service take-up rate for individuals in each of the corruption treatment branches, corresponding to the model specified in Equation (1) consistent with estimates from Column (1) in Table 1. Dark line captures the confidence interval for the take-up rate under a corruption suggestion.

Effects of corruption on demand price elasticity

We also hypothesize that, given the uncertainty and time constraints in the hypothetical situation presented to participants, corruption priming should erode the sensibility of demand for higher service fees. To test this hypothesis, we estimated the following LPM:Footnote 16

(2) $${Y_i} = {\beta _0} + {\beta _1}Corruptio{n_i} + {\beta _2}Pric{e_i} + {\beta _3}Corruptio{n_i}{\rm\;{*}\;}Pric{e_i} + {\varepsilon _i}$$

where $Pric{e_i}$ is a binary marker for whether or not the participant was assigned to a high price, ${\beta _1}$ captures the effect of a suggestion of corruption under a low price, ${\beta _2}$ captures the effect of a high price on demand under no suggestion of corruption, and ${\beta _3}$ captures how that effect changes with the suggestion of corruption. We hypothesize that ${\beta _1}$ should be positive and significant, ${\beta _2}$ should be negative and significant, and ${\beta _3}$ should be positive and of a similar absolute magnitude than ${\beta _2}$ . This combination of results would suggest that a suggestion of corruption makes the demand for intermediary services to become inelastic. However, Table 2 suggests that estimates of ${\beta _1}$ and ${\beta _3}$ are indistinguishable from 0, while ${\beta _2}$ is negative and statistically significant. These results suggest that while the demand for gestores is elastic to higher prices, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that corruption suggestions do not affect the demand for intermediary services or its price elasticity. Fig. 2 confirms the higher (but not statistically significant) price elasticity for individuals under the corruption suggestion treatment.

Table 2. Effect of corruption suggestions on price elasticity

Notes: Table shows estimates for $_1$ , ${\beta _2}$ and ${\beta _3}$ in Equation (2). Column (1) provides the simplest specification described in Equation (2). Column (2) adds sociodemographic covariates. Column (3) controls for other treatment branches. Finally, Column (4) controls for both covariates and other treatments. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. Standard errors are specified in parentheses and exact p-values are reported between brackets. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01$ .

Figure 2. Take-up rates by price levels and corruption suggestions.

Notes: Figure shows the intermediary service take-up rate for individuals in each of the corruption and price treatment branches, corresponding to the model specified in Equation (2) consistent with estimates from Column (1) in Table 2. Dark lines capture the confidence interval for the take-up rate under high prices in the sample of no corruption suggestion (Panel A), on the sample of corruption suggestion (Panel B), and of the effect of facing a high price on service take-up under a corruption suggestion (Panel C).

Does the effect of corruption travel through trusted references?

To further assess how corruption suggestions may make intermediary services more appealing to survey participants, we now evaluate whether the effects of corruption suggestions are contingent on instances in which gestores are referred by participants’ trusted networks. Anecdotally, this is a relevant margin in dealing with the inherent uncertainties associated with intermediary services in Venezuela. To assess whether suggestions of illicit contacts with the bureaucracy are contingent to gestores referred by trusted individuals, we perform the following LPM:Footnote 17

(3) $${Y_i} = {\beta _0} + {\beta _1}Corruptio{n_i} + {\beta _2}Referenc{e_i} + {\beta _3}Corruptio{n_i}\;{\rm{*}}\;Referenc{e_i} + {\varepsilon _i}$$

where $Referenc{e_i}$ stands for a binary marker of whether the script says that the link to the gestor came from a trusted individual. ${\beta _1}$ captures the effect of a suggestion of corruption from an agent found online, ${\beta _2}$ captures the effect of a trusted reference on demand under no suggestion of corruption, and ${\beta _3}$ captures how the effect of suggestions of corruption changes with a trusted reference. We hypothesize that ${\beta _1}$ should be either zero or negative, and both ${\beta _2}$ and ${\beta _3}$ to be positive and statistically significant. Importantly, we expected ${\beta _3}$ to be larger in absolute magnitude than ${\beta _1}$ . These results would suggest that intermediaries’ “market maker” role activates whenever gestores can leverage clients’ social networks for credibility in an inherently uncertain and opaque transaction. Table 3 provides estimates for ${\beta _1}$ , ${\beta _2}$ , and ${\beta _3}$ as described in Equation (3). While estimates for ${\beta _2}$ in Columns 1 and 2 suggest that trusted references may enable the demand for gestores in the absence of a corruption suggestion, estimates for ${\beta _1}$ are positive but insignificant, and estimates for ${\beta _3}$ are negative and statistically significant.Footnote 18 As in previous specifications, these results are broadly inconsistent with our hypotheses. Fig. 3 shows the positive effect of a trusted reference on service take-up under no suggestion of corruption and the absence of such effect under corruption suggestions.

Table 3. Effect of corruption suggestions and trusted reference to intermediaries

Notes: Table shows estimates for ${\beta _1}$ , ${\beta _2}$ and ${\beta _3}$ in Equation (3). Column (1) provides the simplest specification described in Equation (3). Column (2) adds sociodemographic covariates. Column (3) controls for other treatment branches. Finally, Column (4) controls for both covariates and other treatments. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. Standard errors are specified in parentheses, and exact p-values are reported between brackets. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01.$

Figure 3. Take-up rates by reference type and corruption suggestion.

Notes: Figure shows the intermediary service take-up rate for individuals in each of the corruption and reference treatment branches, corresponding to the model specified in Equation (3) consistent with estimates from Column (1) in Table 3. Dark lines capture the confidence interval for the take-up rate under a trusted reference in the sample of no corruption suggestion (Panel A), on the sample of corruption suggestion (Panel B), and of the effect of having a trusted reference on service take-up under a corruption suggestion (Panel C).

Heterogeneities over sociodemographic covariates

The “market maker” role for intermediaries may be contingent on specific client characteristics, making them more likely to engage in transactions that involve an illicit contact with the bureaucracy. Studies have empirically found that women tend to be less likely to engage in corrupt activities (Agerberg, Reference Agerberg2014; Alatas et al., Reference Alatas, Cameron, Chaudhuri, Erkal and Gangadharan2009; Barnes and Beaulieu, Reference Barnes and Beaulieu2014) and that people with higher income levels are more likely to engage in bribery to preserve their privilege and status (Jong-Sung and Khagram, Reference Jong-Sung and Khagram2005). Moreover, this role may be most relevant for individuals who find the hypothetical case prescient for their current situation. For instance, in the context of this study, we presume that participants close to finishing their undergraduate studies should easily relate to the hypothetical situation presented in our experimental survey.

To assess whether the effects of corruption suggestions are contingent on these margins, we evaluate heterogeneities over specific participant sociodemographic characteristics. We perform the following LPM:Footnote 19

(4) $${Y_i} = {\beta _0} + {\beta _1}Corruptio{n_i} + {\beta _2}{X_i} + {\beta _3}Corruptio{n_i}\;{\rm{*}}\;{X_i} + {\varepsilon _i}$$

where ${X_i}$ is a sociodemographic covariate hypothesized to activate the “market maker” role of intermediaries according to the references and the discussion above (Males, High income, or Late stage of their undergraduate studies). We hypothesize that ${\beta _1}$ is zero or negative, and ${\beta _3}$ should be positive and larger in absolute magnitude than ${\beta _1}$ .Footnote 20 This combination of results would suggest that the effect of a corruption suggestion is stronger and positive for individuals co-variate characteristics hypothesized to activate the “market maker” role of intermediaries.

In unreported results, we find that estimates of the effect of corruption are not heterogeneous along the gender and income margins. Table A8 assesses the heterogeneity in the effects of corruption along the stage of participants’ undergraduate studies on a restricted sample of responses that comply with Qualtrics’ automatic quality filters. Our estimates of ${\beta _1}$ indicate that the effect of a corruption suggestion is negative for students at the early stages of their undergraduate studies. Estimates for ${\beta _2}$ suggest that late-stage students are less likely to take the intermediary services in the absence of corruption suggestions. Finally, estimates for ${\beta _3}$ suggest that the effect of corruption suggestions grows for students in the later stages of their careers. Interestingly, estimates of ${\beta _3}$ across specifications are larger in absolute magnitude than those observed for ${\beta _1}$ . These results suggest that “moral cost” considerations may dominate decisions for younger students, but that such considerations are eroded for respondents at later stages of their undergraduate studies.Footnote 21 Students in later career stages may find the hypothesized case to be prescient to their current situation, as they are closer to graduating and may be considering migrating as young professionals in the near future. Similarly, students at later career stages are more likely to have experience procuring bureaucratic services for different motives, potentially through the services of gestores.

Trusted references and the price elasticity of demand for gestores

Results shown in Table 3 hinted at the possibility that trusted references to gestores may have an independent positive effect on the demand for their services. This is consistent with the view that references solve the inherent uncertainty associated with intermediary services in which illicit connections to the bureaucracy are implied, and with anecdotal evidence about the spread of information about intermediaries in Venezuela. We test the effect of references on price elasticity through the following LPM:Footnote 22

(5) $${Y_i} = {\beta _0} + {\beta _1}Pric{e_i} + {\beta _2}Referenc{e_i} + {\beta _3}Pric{e_i}\;{\rm{*}}\;Referenc{e_i} + {\varepsilon _i}$$

We hypothesize that ${\beta _1}$ is negative, ${\beta _2}$ is zero or positive, and ${\beta _3}$ is positive and of a similar absolute magnitude as ${\beta _1}$ , which would suggest that the demand for intermediary services becomes inelastic for gestores whose information came from trusted individuals. Table 4 shows estimates for each of these coefficients. Negative and significant estimates for ${\beta _1}$ suggest a precise price elasticity of demand in the absence of a trusted reference. Estimates of ${\beta _2}$ suggest that trusted references do not magnify the demand for gestores at low prices. Finally, estimates for ${\beta _3}$ suggest that the negative effects of prices on take-up are almost fully eroded whenever a gestor was introduced to the participant by a trusted reference – that is, the demand for such intermediaries is price-inelastic. Fig. 4 shows the reversion in the price elasticity of demand between intermediaries with and without a trusted reference to the client.

Table 4. Demand price elasticity and intermediaries referred by trusted individuals

Notes: Table shows estimates for ${\beta _1}$ , ${\beta _2}$ and ${\beta _3}$ in Equation (5). Column (1) provides the simplest specification described in Equation (5). Column (2) adds sociodemographic covariates. Column (3) controls for other treatment branches. Finally, Column (4) controls for both covariates and other treatments. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. Standard errors are specified in parentheses, and exact p-values are reported between brackets. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01$ .

Figure 4. Take-up rate by price levels reference type.

Notes: Figure shows the intermediary service take-up rate for individuals in each of the price and reference treatment branches, corresponding to the model specified in Equation (5) consistent with estimates from Column (1) in Table 4. Dark lines capture the confidence interval for the take-up rate under a high price in the sample of online references (Panel A), on the sample of trusted references (Panel B) and of the effect of facing a high price on service take-up under a trusted reference (Panel C).

Discussion

While the estimates in Table A8 suggest that “market maker” considerations might be relatively prescient for late-stage undergraduate students, the overall findings from our work are not consistent with that perspective. While mostly insignificant, the majority of our estimates on the effects of corruption suggestions on the demand and the price elasticity of demand for intermediary services are negative. Most importantly, Table 3 shows a positive estimate of the effect of a trusted reference on demand for intermediary services in the absence of corruption suggestions, which is absent whenever intermediaries signal an illicit connection to the bureaucracy. These results are consistent with the view that advertising illicit connections undermines intermediaries’ trustworthiness in the eyes of clients to the point of reversing the credibility gains that come from being referred by a trusted individual. This interpretation would indeed make sense if clients perceived that revealing such connections meant a higher chance of either scam or entrapment. This may be the case for younger students for whom the hypothesized situation is not as prescient to their current situation and might prioritize safety.

However, if this were the case, we would expect that gestores would not reveal the existence of connections to the bureaucracy when advertising their services privately to the clients – something we believe to be the norm in the Venezuelan market for intermediaries. While it is entirely possible that inconclusive findings are driven by the absence of “market maker” considerations – or by them being conflated with “moral costs” considerations – they may also be driven by specific aspects of our empirical setting and our research design.

A key concern about experimental surveys leveraging hypothetical scenarios is that results may be driven by the inattention of participants. However, we believe that this is not the main driver of our results, as we find strong evidence that higher prices reduce the demand for gestores.Footnote 23 An alternative experimental design would consider mechanisms to elicit actual interest in procuring intermediary services as an outcome once participants have been exposed to their respective treatment branches.

Similarly, the experimental design may not have adequately conveyed the difference in the presence of corruption between the treatment and control groups. Chiefly, if most participants assume that intermediaries operate through illicit connections to the bureaucracy, then affirming such connections in the treatment scripts may not add information with respect to control scripts without any such explicit statements.Footnote 24 An alternative experimental design would explicitly mention the absence of illicit connections to the bureaucracy in the script for participants in the control group.

Finally, we chose the case of apostille certifications of professional degrees because it should have been salient for higher education students considering the possibility of migrating, which is a relevant consideration for young Venezuelans. Nevertheless, participants (especially at earlier stages of their studies) may have not been aware of the importance of such certifications at the time of the survey, leaving room for ambiguities in the interpretation of the treatment. An alternative experimental design would set up the hypothetical situation around the need to obtain a passport, which faces similar supply constraints and is equally necessary in order to migrate.

Conclusions

The purpose of this study was to determine how intermediaries’ transparency regarding the existence of illicit connections to the bureaucracy, and referral from a trusted reference, affected clients’ demand for their services. This question is important for understanding how intermediaries may affect corruption. If citizens value their services because they provide these connections, transparency should increase demand. On the contrary, if citizens value intermediation services because they allow them to remain detached from (and potentially unaware of) illicit connections to bureaucracy, then transparency should decrease the demand for intermediaries. Similarly, detecting the effects of trusted references on demand can provide experimental evidence about the diffusion and growth of corruption-enabling technologies.

We addressed this question by building on an experimental survey that studied the demand for gestores in the procurement of apostille certifications of professional degrees. We surveyed undergraduate students in Caracas, Venezuela – an ideal setting to tackle questions about the demand for intermediary services. While our findings are inconclusive on whether “market maker” or “moral cost” considerations regarding information about illicit connections to the bureaucracy dominate participants’ procurement decisions, we find that trusted references to intermediaries make the demand for their services become price inelastic. Finally, we highlight a number of potential revisions to our experimental design for future research on this topic.

This study contributes to the literature by providing experimental evidence on the determinants of demand for intermediaries – a consequential mechanism for bureaucratic corruption in the developing world. We observe citizens in a highly corrupt environment conditioning their choices about how to engage with the bureaucracy based on intermediary market characteristics. To the degree that such reactions are determined by inefficiencies in accessing bureaucratic services directly, our approach offers a window to citizens’ assessments of those inadequacies.

Replication materials

The data, code, and any additional materials required to replicate all analyses in this article are available in the Journal of Experimental Political Science Dataverse within the Harvard Dataverse Network, at doi:10.7910/DVN/HQ67I9 (Ibarra Luces and Morales-Arilla, Reference Ibarra Luces and Morales-Arilla2024).

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Omar Zambrano, Horacio Larreguy, Danila Serra, Ricardo Hausmann, and Douglas Barrios, Participants from Harvard’s Growth Lab Seminar and Texas A&M’s Bush School’s Quant Bag Seminar for valuable comments and suggestions. All errors are our own.

Competing interests

The authors report no relevant conflicts of interest with regard to this manuscript.

Ethics statement

This research project was qualified as exempt from additional IRB review by Harvard’s Human Research Protection Program (Protocol IRB22-0940). Moreover, this project adheres to APSA’s Principles and Guidance for Human Subjects Research. The experimental design does not use deception or potential harm, and participants were provided with a consent form at the beginning of the survey. Participants were not debriefed after completing the survey to minimize the possibility that the purpose of the experimental survey became known to later participants. Participants did not receive compensation for their participation.

Appendix

Figure A1. Diagram of treatment protocol.

Notes: Diagram shows the timing of the release of the survey and period of data collection, along with the protocol of information gathering for groups assigned to different treatment branches along the corruption suggestion dimension.

Figure A2. Script of conversation with gestor and treatment randomization.

Notes: Table shows each variable of interest in the experiment with their corresponding randomization alternatives. The first column corresponds to each treatment variable included in the script of the conversation with the gestor; the second column displays the possible randomization alternatives, with the first option for each variable being the treatment and the second option being the control; and the third column corresponds to the percentage of participants assigned to treatment for each of the variables of interest.

Figure A3. Heterogeneity in the effect of corruption suggestions in career stage – Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample.

Notes: Figure shows the intermediary service take-up rate for individuals in each of the corruption treatment branch and the career stage of the participants, following the model specified in Equation (4) consistent with estimates from Column (1) in Table A8. Dark lines capture the confidence interval for the take-up rate late-career participants in the sample of no corruption suggestion (Panel A), on the sample of corruption suggestion (Panel B) and of the effect of a corruption suggestion in the sample late-stage participants (Panel C).

Table A1. Randomized treatment branches

Notes: Table shows the specifics of each independent random treatment assigned in each participant’s script.

Table A2. Summary statistics

Notes: Table shows summary statistics for variables associated with the first two survey sections (treatment branches, take-up decision, answers to additional questions). $Y$ stands for the binary decision to either take the gestor services or not.

Table A3. Balance tests

Notes: Table shows the estimates of ${\beta _1}$ in performing the regression specification ${X_i} = {\beta _0} + {\beta _1}Treatmen{t_i} + {\varepsilon _i}$ for all treatment branches as independent variables and each of the sociodemographic co-variates of the study, measures of inattention and Qualtrics’ data quality measurement as dependent variables. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01$ .

Table A4. Attrition analysis

Notes: Table shows the estimates of ${\beta _1}$ in performing the regression specification ${A_i} = {\beta _0} + {\beta _1}Treatmen{t_i} + {\varepsilon _i}$ for all treatment branches as independent variables, where ${A_i}$ is a binary marker for whether the survey was not completed after being assigned to a treatment branch. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01$ .

Table A5. Effect of corruption suggestions on take-up – Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample

Notes: Table shows estimates for ${\beta _1}$ in Equation (1). Column (1) provides the simplest specification described in Equation (1). Column (2) adds sociodemographic covariates. Column (3) controls for other treatment branches. Finally, Column (4) controls for both covariates and other treatments. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. For the estimation of all regressions, we used the data that met the Qualtrics quality standards. Standard errors are specified in parentheses and exact p-values are reported between brackets. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01$ .

Table A6. Effect of corruption suggestions on price elasticity – Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample

Notes: Table shows estimates for ${\beta _1}$ , ${\beta _2},$ and ${\beta _3}$ in Equation (2). Column (1) provides the simplest specification described in Equation (2). Column (2) adds sociodemographic covariates. Column (3) controls for other treatment branches. Finally, Column (4) controls for both covariates and other treatments. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. For the estimation of all regressions, we used the data that met the Qualtrics quality standards. Standard errors are specified in parentheses and exact p-values are reported between brackets. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01$ .

Table A7. Effect of corruption suggestions and trusted references - Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample

Notes: Table shows estimates for ${\beta _1}$ , ${\beta _2},$ and ${\beta _3}$ in Equation (3). Column (1) provides the simplest specification described in Equation (3). Column (2) adds sociodemographic covariates. Column (3) controls for other treatment branches. Finally, Column (4) controls for both covariates and other treatments. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. For the estimation of all regressions, we used the data that met the Qualtrics quality standards. Standard errors are specified in parentheses and exact p-values are reported between brackets. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01.$

Table A8. Heterogeneity in the effect of corruption suggestions in career stage - Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample

Notes: Table shows estimates for ${\beta _1}$ , ${\beta _2},$ and ${\beta _3}$ in Equation (4). Column (1) provides the simplest specification described in Equation (4). Column (2) adds sociodemographic covariates. Column (3) controls for other treatment branches. Finally, Column (4) controls for both covariates and other treatments. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. For the estimation of all regressions, we used the data that met the Qualtrics quality standards. Standard errors are specified in parentheses and exact p-values are reported between brackets. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01$ .

Table A9. Demand price elasticity and intermediaries referred by trusted individuals - Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample

Notes: Table shows estimates for ${\beta _1}$ , ${\beta _2},$ and ${\beta _3}$ in Equation (5). Column (1) provides the simplest specification described in Equation (5). Column (2) adds sociodemographic covariates. Column (3) controls for other treatment branches. Finally, Column (4) controls for both covariates and other treatments. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors provided. For the estimation of all regressions, we used the data that met the Qualtrics quality standards. Standard errors are specified in parentheses and exact p-values are reported between brackets. ${{\rm{\;}}^{\rm{*}}}p \lt 0.1$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{**}}}}p \lt 0.05$ ; ${{\rm{\;}}^{{\rm{***}}}}p \lt 0.01.$

Footnotes

This article has earned badges for transparent research practices: Open data and Open materials. For details see the Data Availability Statement.

1 The language in the illicit connection treatment branch suggested that the gestor had “the right connection within the Ministry to guarantee that your certificates are procured on time.” This type of service is unequivocally illegal according to Venezuelan legislation. Indeed, there have been episodic government crackdowns against “gestores” in recent history. See TalCual (2018) and France24 (2021).

2 Participant inattention does not seem to drive the lack of conclusive results in our main analyses, as we can detect a robust negative effect of price on demand. However, several potential aspects of our experimental design may explain the absence of conclusive results. One key concern is that if most participants assume that all gestores work through illicit connections to the bureaucracy, then the implementation of our treatment would not be able to trigger a differential assessment about the corrupt nature of the intermediary service.

3 Moreover, preregistered heterogeneity analyses on a quality-filtered data sample show that suggestions of illicit connections to the bureaucracy reduced the demand for intermediary services for surveyees at the early stages of their studies and that these effects are reversed for students at later stages. We interpret this heterogeneity as possibly driven by initial “moral” considerations being eroded for senior students who are more likely to consider migrating in the short term.

4 A number of studies have focused on the “supply” side of corruption, studying whether changes to the competitive environment between bureaucrats affect patterns of corruption along the predictions of Shleifer and Vishny (Reference Shleifer and Vishny1993). Olken and Barron (Reference Olken and Barron2009) examined the extent to which the behavior of corrupt officials was consistent with standard predictions from industrial organization theory, finding that market structure affects the bribes and extortion payments demanded by officials. Similarly, Ryvkin and Serra (Reference Ryvkin and Serra2017) studied the effects of introducing competition between public officials and found that it significantly reduced the magnitudes and payments of bribes.

5 Drugov et al. (Reference Drugov, Hamman and Serra2014) compare patterns of corruption in settings with different levels of uncertainty to the introduction of an intermediary and find that intermediaries induce corruption even when they do not limit the uncertainties associated with a transaction between a client and a bureaucrat.

6 In April 2019, the Ministry of People’s Power for Foreign Affairs established a virtual portal for the Apostille System that includes the validation of documents through electronic means to avoid corruption and the use of managers (Arias, Reference Arias2019). However, the current “virtual platform” only allows the user to request documents on a given day of the week, depending on the terminal of their identity document. Moreover, constant technical problems result in platform collapse, which is a recurring problem in state service platforms. According to Garcia (Reference Garcia2021), “Users have reported errors in the Electronic Legalization and Apostille System, SAIME and GTU. People go to managers despite the risk of fraud that this might entail.”

8 In the Venezuelan Civil Code, art. 1.684 states that a mandate is a contract by which a person undertakes free of charge, or for a salary, the execution of one or more tasks on behalf of another who has commissioned it (Código Civil, 1982).

9 While Qualtrics prevents multiple participations from the same device, there exists the possibility that some users participate multiple times from different devices.

10 IRB approval was obtained considering that the full purpose of the research would be withheld from participants.

11 Similarly, participants were not debriefed about the survey’s motives after completing it. We believe that if participants were fully informed (debriefed) on the purpose of the project before (after) their participation, there would have been a high likelihood that the motives of the study would either influence their choices or spillover to later survey participants, potentially biasing the results of the experiment.

12 In the appendix, we report results based on a sample of 501 surveys that meet Qualtrics’ own quality criteria. Furthermore, we considered additional quality filters to the data to capture relative degrees of inattention in unreported results. Unless explicitly stated in the Results section, the conclusions of our analyses are indistinguishable across these samples.

13 See Table A1. Regarding corruption suggestions, scripts signaled that the service was being provided by the gestor and “the right contact” in the bureaucracy. Control scripts did not signal the presence of such contacts. The precise text shown to participants in each treatment brank is in Fig. A2.

14 The hypotheses for our three main analyses were preregistered with the AEA RCT Registry under the RCT ID 0009746. Additional details about intervention and the specific treatment scripts for each treatment branch can be found as part of the preregistration materials. See https://www.socialscienceregistry.org/trials/9746.

15 Tests in this subsection were preregistered.

16 Tests in this subsection were pre-registered.

17 Tests in this subsection were pre-registered.

18 Table A7 replicates this specification for a sample of observations that comply with Qualtrics’ quality criteria, showing estimates of ${\beta _3}$ that are smaller in absolute magnitude and statistically insignificant.

19 Tests in this subsection were preregistered.

20 We do not have a hypothesis regarding the effect of covariates in the absence of corruption suggestions ( ${\beta _2}$ ).

21 In unreported results, we perform the same specification on the unrestricted data sample. While estimates are similar in magnitude and direction, they are imprecisely measured and statistically insignificant in the unrestricted sample.

22 While analyses in this section are based on the interaction between two cross-randomized treatment branches, they were not part of the preregistered tests in our pre-analysis plan.

23 It is possible, however, that participants paying limited attention may be able to detect quantitative information about the script (such as service fees) but unable to appreciate qualitative differences that capture other treatment branches.

24 Still, as discussed in the introduction, the fact that gestores usually reveal the presence of these connections suggest that such messages should have informative value on their own.

References

Agerberg, M. 2014. Perspectives on gender and corruption.Google Scholar
Alatas, V., Cameron, L., Chaudhuri, A., Erkal, N., and Gangadharan, L.. 2009. “Gender, Culture, and Corruption: Insights from an Experimental Analysis.” Southern Economic Journal 75(3): 663–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arias, S. 2019. Nuevo sistema de legalización y apostilla electrónica evita corrupción e irregularidades en los trámites. URL: https://mppre.gob.ve/2019/06/14/apostilla-electronica-corrupcion/.Google Scholar
Barnes, T. D., and Beaulieu, E.. 2014. “Gender Stereotypes and Corruption: How Candidates Affect Perceptions of Election Fraud. Politics & Gender 10(3): 365–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartling, B. and Fischbacher, U.. 2012. “Shifting the Blame: On Delegation and Responsibility. The Review of Economic Studies 79(1): 6787.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertrand, M., Djankov, S., Hanna, R., and Mullainathan, S.. 2007. Obtaining a Driver’s License in India: An Experimental Approach to Studying Corruption. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(4): 1639–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolivar, L., and Rodríguez, C.. 2021. Defenseless: The impact of the absence of consular services on the rights of the venezuelan population abroad. UCAB’s Centro de Derechos Humanos.Google Scholar
Código Civil 1982. “Gaceta Oficial, 2990 (Extraordinario).” Julio 26: 1982.Google Scholar
Coffman, L.C. 2011. “Intermediation Reduces Punishment (and Reward). American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 3(4): 77106.Google Scholar
Drugov, M., Hamman, J., and Serra, D.. 2014. “Intermediaries in Corruption: An Experiment.” Experimental Economics 17: 7899.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, R. and Golden, M.A. (2017). Corruption: What everyone needs to know. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
France24 (2021). Más de 100 detenidos por gestionar documentos de identidad venezolanos “fraudulentos”. Accessed: December 12, 2022.Google Scholar
Garcia, M.S. 2021. Cronica Uno errores en las plataformas de atención impiden algunos trámites de documentos e incrementan los “gestores”.Google Scholar
Graf Lambsdorff, J. 2013. “Corrupt Intermediaries in International Business Transactions: Between Make, Buy and Reform.” European Journal of Law and Economics 35: 349–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamman, J. R., Loewenstein, G., and Weber, R. A.. 2010. “Self-Interest Through Delegation: An Additional Rationale for the Principal-Agent Relationship.” American Economic Review, 100(4): 1826–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hasker, K., and Okten, C.. 2008. “Intermediaries and Corruption.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 67(1): 103–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ibarra Luces, A.G. and Morales-Arilla, J.R.. 2024. Replication Data for: “Transparent corruption: The effect of illicit connections and trusted references on the demand for bureaucratic intermediation”.Google Scholar
Jong-Sung, Y., and Khagram, S.. 2005. “A Comparative Study of Inequality and Corruption.” American Sociological Review 70(1): 136–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olken, B.A. and Barron, P.. 2009. “The Simple Economics of Extortion: Evidence from Trucking in Aceh.” Journal of Political Economy 117(3): 417–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ryvkin, D., and Serra, D.. 2017. “The Industrial Organization of Corruption: Monopoly, Competition and Collusion.” Competition and Collusion (February 10, 2017).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R.W.. 1993. “Corruption.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(3): 599617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sommet, N. 2022. How many participants do i need to test an interaction? conducting an appropriate 5 power analysis and achieving sufficient power to detect an interaction.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, J. 2005. “Eight Questions About Corruption.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 19(3): 1942.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
TalCual 2018. Detenidos gestores de pasaportes que cobraban en dólares. Accessed: December 12, 2022.Google Scholar
Tanzi, V. 1998. “Corruption Around the World: Causes, Consequences, Scope, and Cures.” Staff Papers 45(4): 559–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Transparencia Venezuela 2021. Corrupción y pandemia agudizan el drama de la diáspora venezolana. URL: https://transparenciave.org/corrupcion-y-pandemia-agudizan-el-drama-de-la-diaspora-venezolana/.Google Scholar
Transparency International 2022. Corruption perceptions index 2022. URL: https://www.transparency.org/en/cpi/2022.Google Scholar
Wiehen, M. 1999. The integrity pact (ti-ip) the concept, the model and the present applications: a status report as of november 1, 1999, ed. IACC Council, Transparency International.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Effect of corruption suggestions on take-up

Figure 1

Figure 1. Take-up rate by corruption suggestion category.Notes: Figure shows the intermediary service take-up rate for individuals in each of the corruption treatment branches, corresponding to the model specified in Equation (1) consistent with estimates from Column (1) in Table 1. Dark line captures the confidence interval for the take-up rate under a corruption suggestion.

Figure 2

Table 2. Effect of corruption suggestions on price elasticity

Figure 3

Figure 2. Take-up rates by price levels and corruption suggestions.Notes: Figure shows the intermediary service take-up rate for individuals in each of the corruption and price treatment branches, corresponding to the model specified in Equation (2) consistent with estimates from Column (1) in Table 2. Dark lines capture the confidence interval for the take-up rate under high prices in the sample of no corruption suggestion (Panel A), on the sample of corruption suggestion (Panel B), and of the effect of facing a high price on service take-up under a corruption suggestion (Panel C).

Figure 4

Table 3. Effect of corruption suggestions and trusted reference to intermediaries

Figure 5

Figure 3. Take-up rates by reference type and corruption suggestion.Notes: Figure shows the intermediary service take-up rate for individuals in each of the corruption and reference treatment branches, corresponding to the model specified in Equation (3) consistent with estimates from Column (1) in Table 3. Dark lines capture the confidence interval for the take-up rate under a trusted reference in the sample of no corruption suggestion (Panel A), on the sample of corruption suggestion (Panel B), and of the effect of having a trusted reference on service take-up under a corruption suggestion (Panel C).

Figure 6

Table 4. Demand price elasticity and intermediaries referred by trusted individuals

Figure 7

Figure 4. Take-up rate by price levels reference type.Notes: Figure shows the intermediary service take-up rate for individuals in each of the price and reference treatment branches, corresponding to the model specified in Equation (5) consistent with estimates from Column (1) in Table 4. Dark lines capture the confidence interval for the take-up rate under a high price in the sample of online references (Panel A), on the sample of trusted references (Panel B) and of the effect of facing a high price on service take-up under a trusted reference (Panel C).

Figure 8

Figure A1. Diagram of treatment protocol.Notes: Diagram shows the timing of the release of the survey and period of data collection, along with the protocol of information gathering for groups assigned to different treatment branches along the corruption suggestion dimension.

Figure 9

Figure A2. Script of conversation with gestor and treatment randomization.Notes: Table shows each variable of interest in the experiment with their corresponding randomization alternatives. The first column corresponds to each treatment variable included in the script of the conversation with the gestor; the second column displays the possible randomization alternatives, with the first option for each variable being the treatment and the second option being the control; and the third column corresponds to the percentage of participants assigned to treatment for each of the variables of interest.

Figure 10

Figure A3. Heterogeneity in the effect of corruption suggestions in career stage – Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample.Notes: Figure shows the intermediary service take-up rate for individuals in each of the corruption treatment branch and the career stage of the participants, following the model specified in Equation (4) consistent with estimates from Column (1) in Table A8. Dark lines capture the confidence interval for the take-up rate late-career participants in the sample of no corruption suggestion (Panel A), on the sample of corruption suggestion (Panel B) and of the effect of a corruption suggestion in the sample late-stage participants (Panel C).

Figure 11

Table A1. Randomized treatment branches

Figure 12

Table A2. Summary statistics

Figure 13

Table A3. Balance tests

Figure 14

Table A4. Attrition analysis

Figure 15

Table A5. Effect of corruption suggestions on take-up – Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample

Figure 16

Table A6. Effect of corruption suggestions on price elasticity – Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample

Figure 17

Table A7. Effect of corruption suggestions and trusted references - Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample

Figure 18

Table A8. Heterogeneity in the effect of corruption suggestions in career stage - Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample

Figure 19

Table A9. Demand price elasticity and intermediaries referred by trusted individuals - Qualtrics’ Quality Filter Sample