Article contents
What Did Unions Do in Nineteenth-Century Britain?
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 03 March 2009
Abstract
The article examines the development of the insurance function of trade unions. It analyzes how such policies worked, and why union benefit packages differed across occupations. It also addresses the impact of insurance policies on union organization. Insurance benefits increased the ability of unions to attract and retain members. They did not, however, significantly increase the power of union leaders relative to employers or union rank and file.
- Type
- Papers Presented at the Forty-Seventh Annual Meeting of the Economic History Association
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © The Economic History Association 1988
References
1 Williams, Karel, From Pauperism to Poverty (London, 1981), pp. 68–75.Google Scholar
2 MacKinnon, Mary, “English Poor Law Policy and the Crusade against Outrelief,” this JOURNAL, 47 (09 1987), pp. 603–25.Google Scholar
3 Board of Trade, “Statistical Tables and Report on Trade Unions (1887),” Parliamentary Papers, 1887, vol. 89, p. 7.Google Scholar
4 Webb, Sidney and Webb, Beatrice, Industrial Democracy (London, 1897), p. 158.Google Scholar
5 Data for 1893 from Board of Trade, “Seventh Annual Report on Trade Unions,” Parliamentary Papers, 1895, vol. 107, p. 3. The numbers for unemployment and sickness benefits were adjusted to make them consistent with the 1908 data.Google Scholar
6 Board of Trade, “Report on Trade Unions in 1908–1910,” Parliamentary Papers, 1912–13, vol. 47, p. xxxv.Google Scholar
7 Johnson, Paul, Saving and Spending (Oxford, 1985), p. 57.Google Scholar
8 Gilbert, Bentley B., “The Decay of Nineteenth-Century Provident Institutions and the Coming of Old Age Pensions in Great Britain,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 17 (12 1964), pp. 556–57.Google Scholar
9 Harris, Jose, Unemployment and Politics (Oxford, 1972), p. 295.Google Scholar
10 Board of Trade, “Agencies and Methods for Dealing with the Unemployed,” Parliamentary Papers, 1893–1894, vol. 82, pp. 42–43.Google Scholar
11 From 1891 to 1911, nominal (real) annual earnings of engineers increased by 17 percent (10 percent), while nominal (real) earnings of skilled workers in the building trades increased by 15 percent (8 percent). The cost of living increased by 5.8 percent from 1892 to 1908. Williamson, Jeffrey G., Did British Capitalism Breed Inequality? (Boston, 1985), pp. 29, 220.Google Scholar
12 Board of Trade, “Trade Unions in 1908–10,” p. xxxvi.Google Scholar
13 Rowntree, Benjamin Seebohm, Poverty: A Study of Town Life (2nd edn., London, 1902), p. 110. The cost of living in 1899 was 4.3 percent below the cost of living in 1892, and 9.5 percent below the cost of living in 1908. Williamson, Did British Capitalism Breed Inequality?, p. 220.Google Scholar
14 Beveridge, William H., Unemployment: A Problem of Industry (London, 1909), p. 225.Google Scholar
15 Board of Trade, “Agencies and Methods,” pp. 22–24.Google Scholar
16 Beveridge, Unemployment, p. 227. Similar conclusions were reached by the Webbs (Industrial Democracy, pp. 160–61) and by the minority report of the Royal Commission on Trades Unions (Parliamentary Papers, 1868–69, vol. 31, p. xliii).Google Scholar
17 Beveridge, Unemployment, pp. 220–21.Google Scholar
18 Porter, J. H., “Wage Bargaining under Conciliation Agreements, 1860–1914,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 23 (12 1970), pp. 466–75.Google Scholar
19 Ibid., p. 473.
20 Members of the Yorkshire Miners' Association were entitled to benefits only if 25 percent of the workers at the seam had been unemployed for three weeks. This suggests that work sharing was used during all but the most severe recessions. Including the Yorkshire Miners increases to 25 percent the share of miners eligible for unemployment benefits only when the mine was shut down.Google Scholar
21 Webb, Sidney and Webb, Beatrice, The History of Trade Unionism (London, 1894), p. 415.Google Scholar
22 Cole, G.D.H., A Short History of the British Working Class Movement (New York, 1927), vol. 2, p. 162.Google Scholar
23 Wage data for gas stokers from Popplewell, Frank, “The Gas Industry,” in Webb, Sidney and Freeman, Arnold, eds., Seasonal Trades (London, 1912), p. 191.Google Scholar Wage data for laborers in the building trades from Board of Trade, “Report into the Earnings and Hours of Labour. III— Building and Woodworking Trades,” Parliamentary Papers, 1910, vol. 84, p. 25.Google Scholar
24 Rowntree Poverty, p. 244;Google ScholarReeves, Maud Pember, Round About a Pound a Week (London, 1913), pp. 80–88.Google Scholar
25 Popplewell, “Gas Industry,” p. 196.Google Scholar
26 Monthly unemployment data for builders' laborers from Webb, Augustus, “The Building Trade,” in Webb and Freeman, eds., Seasonal Trades, p. 334.Google Scholar Unemployment data for workers from Royal Commission on the Poor Laws, “Appendix, Vol. IX, Unemployment,” Parliamentary Papers, 1910, vol. 49, p. 647.Google Scholar
27 Seasonality also was a problem for skilled workers in the building trades. The fact that these workers commanded occupation-specific human capital explains why their unions were able to provide unemployment insurance while unions of low-skilled workers were not. Still, the high cost of unemployment insurance restricted the provision of benefits. Only one union in the building trades, the Amalgamated Society of Carpenters and Joiners, allowed members to collect benefits for more than 13 weeks per year.Google Scholar
28 Webb, Sidney and Webb, Beatrice, The Minority Report of the Poor Law Commission Part II (London, 1909), p. 196.Google Scholar
29 Hobsbawm, Eric, Labouring Men (London, 1964), p. 187.Google Scholar
30 Webb and Webb, Industrial Democracy, p. 158.Google Scholar
31 Benefits were not vested. A union member expelled for any reason “forfeit[ed] all claim” to benefits (Webb and Webb, Industrial Democracy, p. 154).Google Scholar
32 Ibid., pp. 161–63.
33 Ibid., p. 158.
34 The prospect of losing sickness and funeral benefits had a much smaller impact on workers' decisions, since such benefits could be obtained from friendly societies.Google Scholar
35 Data on the size of balances of Post Office Savings Bank accounts are given in Johnson, Saving and Spending, p. 101. Assuming that no working-class households had balances larger than £50, the data suggest that the median household balance was less than £4. If balances increased with age, the typical young worker's balance must have been no more than £2–3.Google Scholar
36 Several miners' unions paid an additional ls. per week for each child under 13. Several branches of the Amalgamated Association of Operative Cotton Spinners also paid additional benefits to workers with young children.Google Scholar
37 Royal Commission on Trades Unions, “Eleventh and Final Report,” Parliamentary Papers, 1868–69, vol. 31, p. 218.Google Scholar
38 Rowntree, Poverty, p. 357.Google Scholar
39 The existence of such rules is discussed in Webb and Webb, Industrial Democracy, pp. 164–65.Google Scholar
40 Royal Commission on Trades Unions, “Eleventh Report,” p. 217.Google Scholar
41 Royal Commission on Trades Unions, “Minority Report,” Parliamentary Papers, 1868–69, vol. 31, p. xlix.Google Scholar
42 Quoted in Webb and Webb, Industrial Democracy, p. 160.Google Scholar
43 The adoption of mutual insurance policies by many “new” unions in the 1890s is not evidence that union leaders changed their opinion on this issue. New unions adopted insurance policies in order to attract and retain members (Hyman, Richard, The Workers' Union [Oxford, 1971], pp. 14–16, 34).Google Scholar
44 The average male aged 20 to 29 lost less than one week of work per year due to sickness (Money, L. G. Chiozza, Insurance versus Poverty [London, 1912], p. 169). Young workers mainly needed insurance against unemployment, and strikes generally did not threaten unemployment benefits. According to the Webbs, “[a] Trade Union… gives a preference, in effect, to its Out of Work payments, usually continuing them at the full rate, even when its funds are being rapidly exhausted …”(Industrial Democracy, p. 161). Thus, the expected cost of strikes (in terms of benefits lost) was low for young workers.Google Scholar
45 Ibid., p. 160.
46 It is not possible to determine the proportion of unions in which benefit funds were controlled by the central leadership. In the Amalgamated Engineers, a model for many unions, branches retained their own funds (Webb and Webb, History of Trade Unionism, pp. 220–21).Google Scholar
- 12
- Cited by