Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T11:31:27.136Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

What Did Merchants Do? Reflections on British Overseas Trade, 1660–1790

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Jacob M. Price
Affiliation:
Professor of History, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Ml 48109.

Extract

The relative dynamism of English and Scottish foreign trade from 1675 to 1775 can largely be explained by the interrelated phenomena of the growing domestic demand for American and Asian consumer goods and North European raw materials; the growing market in northern and western Europe for re-exports of American and Asian consumables; and the growing protected market for British manufactures in the American colonies and Africa. Trade growth depended on development of a wide variety of credit practices, supported primarily by big wholesalers and export merchants. Wholesalers and merchants also accounted for important institutional innovations.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1989

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 See Harte, N. B., “Trends in Publication on the Economic and Social History of Great Britain and Ireland, 1925–1974.” The Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 30 (02 1977), pp. 2041;CrossRefGoogle ScholarChaloner, W. H. and Richardson, R. C., Bibliography of British Economic and Social History (Manchester, 1984).Google Scholar

2 Cannadine, David, “The Past and Present in the English Industrial Revolution, 1880–1980,” Past & Present, 103 (05 1984), pp. 131–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 Deane, Phyllis and Cole, W. A., British Economic Growth, 1688–1959 (Cambridge, 1962), pp. 4150, 82–89.Google Scholar

4 Rostow, W. W., The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto (Cambridge, 1960).Google Scholar See also two contemporary articles: Berrill, K., “International trade and the rate of economic growth,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 12 (04 1960), pp. 351–59;CrossRefGoogle ScholarHabakkuk, H. J. and Deane, Phyllis, “The Take-off in Britain,” in Rostow, W. W., ed., The Economics of Take-Off into Sustained Growth (London, 1963), pp. 6382.Google Scholar

5 See, for example, Frank, André Gunder, World Accumulation, 1492–1789 (London, 1978);CrossRefGoogle ScholarWallerstein, Immanuel, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600–1750 (New York, 1980).Google Scholar For a critique, see O'Brien, Patrick, “European Economic Development: the Contribution of the Periphery,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 35 (02 1982), pp. 118;CrossRefGoogle Scholar and the exchange of comments between O'Brien and Wallerstein in Ibid., 36 (Nov. 1983), pp. 580–85.

6 See in particular McKendrick, Neil, “Home Demand and Economic Growth: A New View of the Role of Women and Children in the Industrial Revolution,” in McKendrick, Neil, ed., Historical Perspectives: Studies in English Thought and Society in Honour of J. H. Plumb (London, 1974). pp. 152210;Google Scholaridem, , “The Consumer Revolution of Eighteenth-Century England,” in McKendrick, Neil, Brewer, John and Plumb, J. H., eds., The Birth of a Consumer Society: The Commercialization of Eighteenth-Century England (London, 1982), pp. 933.Google Scholar It should be noted, however, that recent quantitative work has failed to demonstrate any measurable increase in total consumption per head before 1800. See Feinstein, C. H.. “Capital Accumulation and the Industrial Revolution” in Floud, Roderick and McCloskey, Donald, eds., The Economic History of Britain since 1700, 2 vols. (Cambridge, 1981). p. 136.Google Scholar

7 The current standing of the “main line” approach to the problem is very ably presented and interpreted in Crafts, N. F. R., British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution (Oxford, 1985).Google Scholar especially chap. 7, and—on a briefer scale—in Lee, C. H., The British Economy since 1700: A Macroeconomic Perspective (Cambridge, 1986), especially chap. 6.Google Scholar See also Thomas, R. P. and McCloskey, D. N., “Overseas Trade and Empire, 1700–1860,” in Floud, and McCloskey, , eds., The Economic History of Britain, chap. 5.Google Scholar

8 Crafts, Economic Growth. pp. 147–48.Google Scholar No comparable data are available for the eighteenth century, but see McCusker, John J., “The Current Value of English Exports, 1697 to 1800,” William and Mary Quarterly, 3rd ser., 28 (10 1971), pp. 607–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9 Unless otherwise specified, all foreign trade data in this paper are from (in order of preference): Davis, Ralph, “English Foreign Trade, 1700–1774,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 15 (10 1962), pp. 285303;Google Scholaridem, , The Industrial Revolution and British Overseas Trade (Leicester, 1979);Google ScholarHamilton, Henry, An Economic History of Scotland in the Eighteenth Century (Oxford, 1963), pp. 410–20;Google ScholarMitchell, B. R. and Deane, Phyllis, Abstract of British Historical Statistics (Cambridge, 1962);Google ScholarSchumpeter, Elizabeth Boody, English Overseas Trade Statistics, 1697–1808 (Oxford, 1960).Google Scholar All English population data in the article are from Wrigley, E. A. and Schofield, R. S., The Population History of England, 1541–1871 (Cambridge, MA, 1981), pp. 208–9.Google Scholar

10 For example, Smith, Adam, The Wealth of Nations, 2 vols. (Oxford, 1976), vol. 1, pp. 424, 448–49. For Pitt's speech of 9 03 1759, see British Library Add. MSS. 32, 888 ff. 428–429.Google Scholar

11 For British legislation affecting trade with Ireland, see Cullen, L. M., Anglo-Irish Trade, 1660–1800 (Manchester, 1968), passim.Google Scholar

12 Between about 1670 and about 1770, population can be roughly estimated to have risen as follows: England and Wales: 5.3 to 6.9 million; Scotland: 1 to 1.3 million; Ireland: 2 to 3.6 million; British West Indies: 96.000 to 480,000; Thirteen Colonies: 112,000 to 2.148 million (with 117,000 extra for Canada at the latter date). See fn. 9, Mitchell and Deane, Abstract, p. 5;Google ScholarSmout, T. C., A History of the Scottish People, 1560–1830 (New York, 1969), chap. 11;Google ScholarMokyr, Joel and Gráda, Cormac ó, “New Developments in Irish Population History, 1700–1850,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 37 (11 1984), pp. 473–88;CrossRefGoogle ScholarBureau, U.S. of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States … to 1970 (Washington, D.C., 1975), vol. 2, p. 1168;Google ScholarMcCusker, John J. and Menard, Russell R., The Economy of British America, 1607–1789 (Chapel Hill, 1985), pp. 111, 154.Google Scholar

13 Feinstein suggests considerable stability in later eighteenth century per capita consumption. See fn. 6.Google Scholar

14 Price, Jacob M., “A Note on the Value of Colonial Exports of Shipping,” this Journal, 36 (09 1976), pp. 704–24.Google Scholar

15 Robert Brenner develops this theme in the opening chapters of his forthcoming Merchants and Revolution: Commercial Change and Political Conflict in the London Merchant Community, 1550–1660 (Princeton University Press).Google Scholar

16 Extensive literature on this subject includes Glamann, Kristof, Dutch-Asiatic Trade, 1620–1740 (Copenhagen, 1958), especially chap. 3;Google ScholarChaudhuri, K. N., “The East India Company and the Export of Treasure in the Early Seventeenth Century,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 16 (08 1963), pp. 2338;CrossRefGoogle Scholaridem, , “Treasure and Trade Balances: the East India Company's Export Trade, 1660–1720,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 21 (12 1968), pp. 480502;Google ScholarAttman, Artur, The Bullion Flow between Europe and the East, 1000–1750 (Göteborg, 1981);Google Scholaridem, , American Bullion in the European World Trade, 1600–1800 (Göteborg, [1986]).Google Scholar

17 Buck, Norman Sydney, The Development of the Organisation ofAnglo-Amnerican Trade, 1800–1850 (New Haven, 1925), especially pp. 131–51;Google ScholarWesterfield, Ray B., Early History of American Auctions (New Haven, 1920), pp. 159210, esp. pp. 172–79;Google ScholarPrice, Jacob M., Capital and Credit in British Overseas Trade: the View from the Chesapeake, 1700–1776 (Cambridge, MA, 1980), pp. 143–46, 202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

18 References to the 2.5 percent freight charge can be found scattered in invoices in surviving eighteenth-century commercial papers, including Library of Congress, John Glassford & Co. Papers, vol. 31 ff. 15–;24, 55v, 72v–80v, 89v, 109v– 16v, 149v–50v, 17–76v, as well as in vols. 122, 123, 124. See also Price, Capital and Credit, pp. 156–57, in which freight on outbound goods is equated with commission (both 2.5 percent) but waived if goods ordered are paid on time.Google Scholar

19 Price, Capital and Credit, chap. 6, especially p. 119;Google ScholarHope, John, Letters on Credit (2d edn., London, 1784), pp. 910.Google Scholar There were, of course some trades where shorter credits were common and some—for example, guns—where no credit might be offered. See Robinson, Eric, “Boulton and Fothergill, 1762–1782, and the Birmingham export of hardware,” University of Birmingham Historical Journal, 7 (19591960), pp. 6079;Google ScholarChapman, S. D., “Financial Restraints on the Growth of Firms in the Cotton Industry, 1790–1850,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 32 (02 1979), pp. 5152.Google Scholar

20 Price, Capital and Credit, pp. 112–13;Google Scholar[Defoe, Daniel], A Brief State of the Inland or Home Trade of England (London, 1730), pp. 2122.Google Scholar

21 See Davis, Ralph, “English Foreign Trade. 1660–1700,” Economic History, 2nd ser., 7 (12 1954), p. 151. In 1699–1701, trade with America, Africa, and Asia came to 15.4 percent of total English imports and exports; it seems unlikely that they came to more than 10 percent in 1651–1660.Google Scholar

22 On such bill operations, see Price, J. M., “Multilateralism and/or Bilateralism: the Settlement of British Trade Balances with ‘The North,’ c. 1700,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 14 (12 1961), pp. 254–74.Google Scholar

23 Malone, Joseph J., Pine Trees and Politics: The Naval Stores and Forest Policy in Colonial New England, 1691–1775 (London, 1964), pp. 2627, passim;Google ScholarPrice, J. M., “The Map of Commerce,” The New Cambridge Modern History, (Cambridge, 1970), vol. 6, pp. 839–44.Google Scholar

24 Warden, Alex J., The Linen Trade Ancient and Modern (London, 1864), pp. 663–66;Google ScholarGill, Conrad, The Rise of the Irish Linen Industry (Oxford, 1925), p. 71;Google ScholarHomer, John, The Linen Trade of Europe during the Spinning-Wheel Period (Belfast, 1920);Google ScholarDune, Alastair J., The Scottish Linen Industry in the Eighteenth Century (Edinburgh, 1979), pp. 52, 146–48, 151–55;Google ScholarHarte, N. B., “The Rise of Protection and the English Linen Trade, 1690–1790,” in Harte, N. B. and Ponting, K. G., eds., Textile History and Economic History (Manchester, 1973), pp. 74112.Google ScholarSee Davis, “English Foreign Trade, 1700–1774,” p. 303, for decline in English woolen exports to northwest Europe and rise in English exports of British linen.Google Scholar

25 For the woolen trade's awareness of the linen problem, see Bischoff, James, A Comprehensive History of the Woolen and Worsted Manufactures …, 2 vols. (London, 1842), vol. 1, pp. 179206.Google Scholar

26 McCusker and Menard. The Economy of British America. p. 284; Schumpeter, Trade Statistics, pp. 63–69. In the woolen-worsted group, the American colonies took 70.4 percent of English exports of “Spanish cloth,” 42.6 percent of flannel, 36.8 percent of “short cloths,” and lesser quantities of other varieties. Some additional English cloth was exported to America from Scotland.Google Scholar

27 For English, see fn. 9; for Scottish, see Hamilton, Henry, An Economic History of Scotland in the Eighteenth Century (Oxford, 1963), pp. 414–15.Google Scholar

28 Price, Jacob M., France and the Chesapeake: A History of the French Tobacco Monopoly, 1674–1791 …, 2 vols. (Ann Arbor, 1973), especially vol. 2, pp. 845–49.Google ScholarFor coffee and rum re-exports, see Schumpeter, Trade Statistics, pp. 60–61. For rice, see PRO C.O.390/5 f. 119 (England, 17171723), T.70/1205/A.16 (England, 17311745), C.O.390/9 if. 4, 56 (England, 17521753), T.36/13 f. 258 (Scotland, 17561762).Google Scholar

29 McCusker and Menard, The Economy of British America, chap. 10.Google Scholar

30 Shepherd, James F. and Walton, Gary M., Shipping. Maritime Trade and the Economic Development of Colonial North America (Cambridge, 1972). pp. 9495.Google Scholar

31 Historical Statistics of the United States, vol. 2, p. 1190. For coffee, re-exports were over 90 percent then: for rice, re-exports were 86.8 to 89.3 percent of English imports about 1717 to 1762; and 92.8 to 95.4 percent of Scottish imports about 1756 to 1768. See fn. 28.Google Scholar

32 Based on “official values” as given in Davis, “English Foreign Trade, 1700–1774,” and Hamilton, An Economic History of Scotland. The figures in Mitchell and Deane, British Historical Statistics, p. 281, give the re-export percentage as 40 percent, using values “adjusted” by Deane and Cole (British Economic Growth, p. 318).Google Scholar

33 Asian trade was, of course, confined exclusively to London because of the monopoly of the East India Company. For port concentration in the sugar and tobacco trades, see Price, Jacob M. and Clemens, Paul G. E., “A Revolution of Scale in Overseas Trade: British Firms in the Chesapeake Trade, 1675–1775,” this JOURNAL, 47 (03 1987), pp. 33, 39–40.Google Scholar

34 For the operation of a counting house, see Price, Jacob M., ed., “Directions for the Conduct of a Merchant's Counting House, 1766,” Business History, 28 (07 1986), pp. 134–50.Google Scholar

35 There is a rich correspondence between an African-West Indian merchant and his suppliers in the James Rogers papers in PRO C.107/3–15.Google Scholar

36 Price, Capital and Credit, pp. 107–8;Google Scholaridem, , “One Family's Empire: the Russell-Lee-Clerk Connection in Maryland, Britain, and India, 1707–1857,” Maryland Historical Magazine, 72 (Summer 1977), p. 177.Google Scholar Almost nothing has been published on commodity brokers, but there are some references to them in Joshua Johnson's Letterbook, 1771–1774 …, ed. Price, Jacob M., London Record Society Publications 15 (London, 1979).Google Scholar

37 For general discussion, see Thornton, Henry, An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain (1802), ed. von Hayek, F. A. (London, 1939), pp. 7577;Google Scholarfor credit in export trades, see Price, Capital and Credit, chap. 6;Google Scholar for credit in woolen manufacture, see Hudson, Pat, The Genesis of Industrial Capital: A Study of the West Riding Wool Textile Industry, c. 1750–1850 (Cambridge, 1986), pp. 17, 111–19, 122, 124, 128, 156–60, 217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

38 Balance sheets can be inferred from merchant's inventories which can be found in considerable number in the records of London “Orphans' Court” in the London Corporation Record Office, Guildhall, and—in less accessible form—in the Prerogative Court of Canterbury postmortem inventories in PRO Prob. 3, 4 and 5. For other examples, see Price, Capital and Credit chap. 3, and idem, “Buchanan & Simson, 1759–63: …” William and Mary Quarterly, 3rd ser., 40 (Jan. 1983), pp. 3–41; and idem, “The Last Phase of the Virginia-London Consignment Trade: James Buchanan & Co., 1758–1768.” William and Mary Quarterly, 3d ser., 43 (Jan. 1986), pp. 64–98.Google Scholar

39 The American commission was sometimes given as 10 percent, incorporating 5 percent for sale of outbound cargo, and 5 percent for purchase of return cargo. This was convenient when the outbound cargo was sold for return commodities. See Mair, John, Book-keeping Methodiz'd… (5th edn., Dublin, 1754), p. 224. However, in the slave trade a 10 percent commission was charged when the selling factor was expected to guarantee collections on credit sales.Google Scholar

40 The author expects to publish a paper on the credit conventions in the slave trade in 1990 for the W. E. B. DuBois Center of Harvard University.Google Scholar

41 Price, Capital and Credit, chap. 4.Google Scholar

42 Thornton, Paper Credit, pp. 81–85, 88–94, 104–105;Google ScholarHolden, J. Milnes, The History of Negotiable Instruments in English Law (London, 1955), passim.Google Scholar

43 Bank of England Archives, Court of Directors Minutes, 1694–1790; Committee of Treasury Minutes, 1779–1781.Google Scholar

44 See Hudson, The Genesis of Industrial Capital.Google Scholar

45 Ibid., pp. 156–60; Westerfield, Ray Bert. “Middlemen in English Business Particularly Between 1660 and 1760,” Transactions of the Connecticut Academy ofArts and Sciences, 19 (05 1915), pp. 296306;Google ScholarPrice, Capital and Credit. pp. 102–12;Google ScholarAtkinson, Frank, Some Aspects of the 18th Century Woollen & Worsted Trade in Halifax (Halifax, 1956), pp. 3539.Google Scholar

46 Examples of such direct credit marketing by Manchester manufacturers in the 1780s can be found in the Rogers papers (fn. 35). Earlier, a few exceptionally large firms like Touchet & Co. combined the function of export merchants, warehousemen. and manufacturers. See Wadworth, Alfred P. and de Lacey Mann, Julia, The Cotton Trade and Industrial Lancashire, 1600–1780 (Manchester, 1931), pp. 243–48, passim;Google ScholarEdwards, Michael M., The Growth of the British Cotton Trade, 1780–1815 (Manchester, 1967), pp. 178–79, 226–30.Google Scholar

47 Price and Clemens, “A Revolution in Scale.”Google Scholar

48 The Rogers papers contain references to underwriting at Liverpool by Rogers of Bristol. For underwriting at Glasgow, see Price, “Buchanan & Simson,” pp. 33–34.Google Scholar

49 Price, Capital and Credit, chap. 5:Google ScholarPrice, F. G. Hilton, A Handbook of London Bankers (London, 1876; enlarged edn., 18901891), passim.Google Scholar

50 For examples, see Devine, T. M., The Tobacco Lords: A Study of the Tobacco Merchants of Glasgow … c. 1740–90 (Edinburgh, 1975), chap. 3:Google Scholaridem, , “The Colonial Trades and Industrial Development in Scotland, c. 1700–1815,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 29 (02 1976), pp. 113;Google ScholarAtkinson, Michael and Baber, Cohn, The Growth and Decline of the South Wales Iron Industry, 1760–1880 (Cardiff, 1987), especially pp. 4852;Google ScholarCrouzet, François, The First Industrialists: the Problem of Origins (Cambridge, 1985), chap. 7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

51 Rubinstein, W. D., “The Victorian Middle Classes: Wealth, Occupation and Geography,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser. 30 (11 1977), pp. 602–23:Google Scholaridem, , Men of Property (London, 1981), especially chap. 3.Google Scholar

52 Crafts, British Economic Growth, p. 131. For other estimates, see Lee, British Economy, p. 109.Google Scholar

53 Foodstuffs declined from 17.6 percent of English domestic exports in 1722–1724 to 5.8 percent in 1772–1774. Davis, “English Foreign trade, 1700–1774,” p. 302.Google Scholar

54 Crafts, British Economic Growth, p. 132.Google Scholar

55 Ibid., p. 143; Hyde, Charles K., Technological Change and the British Iron Industry, 1700–1787 (Princeton, 1977), pp. 4950;Google ScholarDavis, R., Industrial Revolution, p. 66;Google ScholarHarris, J. R., The Copper King: A Biography of Thomas Williams of Llanidan, (Liverpool, 1964), pp. 812;Google ScholarPrice, Jacob M., “Colonial Trade and British Economic Development, 1660–1775,” Lex et Scientia, 14 (0709. 1978), pp. 120–21.Google Scholar

56 Robinson, Eric, “Boulton and Fothergill, 17621782, and the Birmingham export of hardware,” p. 63;Google ScholarHamilton, Henry, The English Brass & Copper Industries to 1800 (London, 1926), pp. 29192;Google ScholarBischoff, , Woollen and Worsted Industry, vol. I, p. 189;Google Scholar