Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T18:48:18.247Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Ora et Guberna. The Economic Impact of the Rule of St Benedict in Medieval England

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 October 2024

Domenico Rossignoli
Affiliation:
Assistant Professor, DISEIS and CSCC, Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Largo Gemelli, 1 20123 Milano. E-mail: [email protected].
Federico Trombetta*
Affiliation:
Assistant Professor, DISEIS, Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Largo Gemelli, 1 20123 Milano.
*
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Within the turmoil of the Norman Conquest, did religious institutions affect the economic outcomes of their land? Exploiting historical data about the changes in holdings’ lordship that occurred after the Conquest, we compare the economic performance of estates controlled by different types of lords. Holdings controlled by Benedictine monasteries (vis-à-vis secular lords) experienced a better performance, although, once accounting for the unchanging upper level of the feudal structure, we cannot fully disentangle this effect from the persistence of Benedictine Overlordship. A comparison with Celtic monasteries, with a different organizational structure, suggests a role for the governance structure of Benedictine monasteries.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Economic History Association

The Norman Conquest (1066) has been acknowledged as a turning point in the history of England, affecting many dimensions of its subsequent history, from the societal structure (Barlow 1999) to the military organization (Hollister Reference Hollister1961). Further, the huge land reallocation that followed the Conquest was accompanied by a considerable variation in land value between 1066 and 1086 (Loyn Reference Loyn2013, p. 333). Within this political, social, and economic turmoil, did religious institutions play a role in affecting the economic outcome of the lands they controlled? In particular, did Benedictine monasteries, which controlled about one-sixth of the land in 1066 (Burton Reference Burton1994), perform differently from their secular counterparts, given their peculiar institutional and governance structures?

In the English countryside of that period, two types of land ownership prevailed. One is where the land was owned by the secular gentry, in some cases the King himself or people connected to him. The second is where the land was owned by religious figures, who can be further divided into two categories: the first includes Benedictine monasteries (the set of monasteries that are committed to following the Rule written by Benedict of Nursia in the early Middle Ages; see Quartiroli (Reference Quartiroli and Monastici2002)) as well as Celtic monasteries;Footnote 1 the second includes other ecclesiastical landlords such as bishops, canons, and deacons.

The structure of landownership was complex. The upper layer of the institutional structure were the Overlords (in 1066) or Tenants-in-Chiefs (in 1086). The lower layer consisted of lords. We use “ownership” in an extensive way, including both levels of the structure (hence both the Tenant-in-Chief and the lord holding land from him are “owners”). In this paper, when we refer to changes in lordship, we mean changes in the lower level of the feudal structure only. All combinations of lordship and Overlordship are possible (Benedictine Overlord and secular lord, secular Overlord and secular lord, and so on).

In this paper, we exploit the historical consequences of the Norman Conquest in medieval England to study the effect of the different institutional arrangements, both religious and secular, on economic outcomes. We use fine-grained data from England around the time of the Norman Conquest (1066) that allows us to exploit institutional variation at a local level. We compare the productivity of estates controlled by different types of landlords.

Using for identification purposes the biggest change in land control in British history that followed the Norman Conquest and running our analysis at the lowest possible level of the feudal structure, that is, “lords,”Footnote 2 we show that in the sample of holdings whose lord was secular in 1066, land owned by Benedictine monasteries after the Conquest performed better economically than land under secular ownership. However, results are not robust in the reduced samples where we exclude ambiguously identified lords or where we exclude holdings whose upper level of the feudal structure remained unchanged. In contrast, our analysis also shows that estates governed by non-monastic ecclesiastical lords did not outperform those with a secular lord. An analysis of the heterogeneity of our results across the different levels of the feudal structure suggests that the effect we find is driven by holdings whose upper level of the feudal structure was already Benedictine in 1066 and became a direct lord in 1086, suggesting a role for institutional persistence at the Overlord level that cannot be fully disentangled from Benedictine identity. Finally, we provide suggestive evidence showing that Benedictines tended to perform better than monastic communities of Celtic tradition (i.e., not subject to Benedict’s Rule) and to use better “technology” (plows and mills). Benedictine monasteries had a unique governance structure, different from both secular and other ecclesiastical landlords: their head was an elective office, and monks held regular meetings through an assembly, called “Chapter,” to discuss important matters without the need to be summoned by the Abbot. We suggest that this “democratic” organizational structure provided a managerial advantage to the Benedictine monasteries.

Our dataset merges information from the Domesday Book (henceforth DDB), Footnote 3 the English Monastic Archive, and a variety of other sources for geographic and historical controls. Our basic units of analysis are holdings. Footnote 4 As we have information on the economic performance of these holdings (in terms of their productive capacity) and the landlord’s name, we can compare the productivity of land controlled by secular landlords with that of the land controlled by Benedictine monasteries and other types of landlords.

We focus on the subsample of holdings whose lordship in 1066 was secular and whose lordship changed between 1066 and 1086 (moving to a new secular lord or a religious one). Applying a difference-in-difference (DID) approach, we find that holdings controlled by religious lords tended to perform better, but the estimated coefficient is not always statistically significant. Consequently, guided by the different institutional structures that differentiated Benedictine monasteries from the other religious lords, we run the comparison for the two subgroups separately. In this way, we find that holdings switching from a secular lord to a Benedictine one experienced a higher 20-year growth rate in productive capacity, compared with holdings controlled by secular landlords. This result is robust to the inclusion of time-invariant covariates interacted with time-fixed effects and to alternative estimations with matching techniques, but not to the exclusion from the sample of holdings whose upper level of the feudal structure did not change (almost all of them having a Benedictine monastery as Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief), or whose lordship attribution in 1066 was ambiguously defined.

The aforementioned caveats on the “Benedictine” effect suggest that observations with an ambiguous lord in 1066 and whose Overlord was already Benedictine are driving the result. Hence, it is hard to assess whether the governance of those holdings has really changed and whether this change was strategic. To shed some light on this issue, we conduct a heterogeneity analysis exploiting information on the different levels of the feudal structure contained in the DDB, using information on the upper level of the feudal structure (the one above the lord and below the King, defined in the data as Overlord and Tenant-in-Chief for 1066 and 1086, respectively. Note that the lord may or may not coincide with the Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief). This analysis shows that the “Benedictine” effect is driven by holdings whose monastic lord in 1086 was also the upper level of the feudal structure both in 1066 and in 1086. In this subsample, the credibility of the parallel trend assumption is weaker: these holdings did not change the upper level of the feudal structure and the change in the lower level of the feudal structure may be due to the strategic initiative of the higher level, rather than to the Conquest. To alleviate this concern, we first introduce in the regression a “Benedictine Overlord” fixed effect showing that, reassuringly, our results are robust. Second, we show that these Benedictine holdings were better than those switching from a secular landlord to the Crown, having the Crown as the upper level of the feudal structure both in 1066 and in 1086: for those holdings, the possibility of a strategic re-claim of the land was probably even stronger. One limitation of this test is that it does not allow us to separate a “Benedictine” effect with the effect of institutional persistence, as the Crown violently changes hands after Hastings.

The correlation we find in the least restrictive subsample may be due to several factors. To support our claim that the Benedictine organizational structure played an important role, we first provide several tests to rule out alternative potential explanations. Second, we provide positive evidence suggesting that Benedictine monasteries were different, in terms of land performance, from monasteries that did not share the same organizational rule. In particular, we exploit the contemporaneous presence of two different monastic traditions in medieval England: Benedictine and Celtic (Dell’Omo Reference Dell’Omo2011). Footnote 5 The latter were monks living in monasteries, but the most ancient rule coming from this tradition is silent (as far as we know) in terms of governance and organization. Using newly coded data from Knowles and Hadcock (1971), we were able to find holdings arguably controlled by to Celtic monasteries (existing in 1066) mentioned in the DDB, comparing their performance with holdings controlled by Benedictine houses. Due to data limitations, this comparison relies on a different and noisier sample and employs only the outcome variable referring to 1086. Still, land controlled by Benedictine monasteries seemingly performed better in most of the specifications. Overall, if we focus our attention only on changes in lordship, it seems that Benedictine monasteries were better landlords than their secular counterparts. We argue that any positive effect of Benedictine control on economic outcomes was not just due to the presence of monks. Benedictine monasteries performed better when compared to monastic communities of different traditions. Although we are not able to fully distinguish between the effect of organizational continuity and the organizational and governance structures in a full sample, our results indicate that Benedictine monasteries had better outcomes compared to Celtic monasteries, suggesting that the Benedictine organizational structure might have contributed to that. It was probably able to guarantee institutional persistence through the difficulty of replacing abbots and their strong legitimization, and to create incentives for a better decision-making process.

Our paper makes two contributions. First, our analysis finds some evidence of a Benedictine advantage in economic performance. In a period of intense political turmoil, such as the Norman Conquest, Benedictine monasteries may have protected institutional persistence and created the conditions for better decision-making. In this sense, we are consistent with Roehl (Reference Roehl1986), who stresses the importance of the “corporate character” of Benedictine monasteries. This may have been important beyond England in the eleventh century. Grzymala-Busse (Reference Grzymala-Busse2020) highlights the role of the medieval Catholic Church as a “template for institutional innovation.” Doucette and Møller (Reference Doucette and Møller2021) highlight how the proximity to Cluniac monasteries facilitated the “imitation” of their institutional features by local political communities, promoting the emergence of self-governance within an age of the collapse of state institutions. Again, our contribution particularly fits the age of political transition we are observing. Second, we contribute with a case study of the interaction between religious legitimacy, political power, and economic outcomes, the importance of which has been suggested by Iyer (Reference Iyer2016). We analyze the historical economic impact of religious institutions acting as economic and political players, stressing the importance of looking at the interaction between religious legitimacy and the specific governance structure of those institutions.

RELATED LITERATURE

Some papers have looked at the impact of monasteries (or their suppression) on economic outcomes from a long-term perspective. Heldring, Robinson, and Vollmer (Reference Heldring, Robinson and Vollmer2021) look at the impact of the dissolution of monasteries on the industrial revolution in England. They find that places strongly affected by their dissolution are associated positively with innovation and agricultural yields, industrialization, and the number of gentries in a parish, and negatively with the share of labor force in agriculture. Our research question is different from theirs, and they look at a different time frame. Andersen et al. (Reference Andersen, Bentzen, Dalgaard and Sharp2017) use county-level English data to show the long-term impact of Cistercian monasteries on cultural values and population growth. We use variation at a much finer level to test the contemporaneous impact of different institutional structures, looking at an earlier historical period. Differently from them, we find weak evidence of a larger population stock on Benedictine estates, and we show that there is a strong and positive effect on productive capacity, observable in the short term (less than 20 years). As the “work-ethic factor” takes time to develop, our results suggest that other mechanisms were at play, such as a different institutional decision-making process. We are also not the first to compare the outcomes of secular and ecclesiastical holdings, but other studies focus on much smaller and less representative samples (McDonald and Snooks Reference McDonald and Snooks1986) or look at a different period (Heldring, Robinson, and Vollmer Reference Heldring, Robinson and Vollmer2021). Results are very mixed. Heldring, Robinson, and Vollmer (Reference Heldring, Robinson and Vollmer2021) note that monastic land was characterized by “inefficient types of customary tenures,” pointing toward a lower productivity of ecclesiastical holdings. Campbell (Reference Campbell1983) finds no significant differences between ecclesiastic and secular holdings, and Campbell (2006) points to two competing effects. On the one hand, “on conventual and collegiate estates inertia rather than enterprise could all too easily rule” (p. 421). On the other hand, “such landlords were also in a uniquely privileged position to develop the management of their estates on a long-term sustainable basis” (p. 421).

A few other recent papers use data from the DDB. Angelucci, Meraglia, and Voigtländer (Reference Angelucci, Meraglia and Voigtländer2017) look at the long-term effect of farm grants (id est self-governing municipalities) on political support for more inclusive institutions. They also use data from the DDB, but they focus only on boroughs, while we look at countryside holdings. Moreover, the Norman Conquest is the starting point for their long-term analysis, while we look at short-term impact before and after that event. Delabastita and Maes (Reference Delabastita and Maes2023) use the whole depth of the DDB to analyze the economic effects of the feudal structure of the society, modeled as a network, finding evidence of its importance. Wieland (Reference Wieland2022) studies the effect of Viking settlements in Eastern England on economic outcomes, using data from the DDB as an outcome variable. We see those papers as complementary to ours, leading to a better quantitative understanding of institutions in medieval England and their economic role. In our work, we use the entire DDB for an analysis of the economic effects of secular and religious landlords.

In terms of religion and economic history, we contribute to the literature by studying the political and economic role of the Catholic Church in the Middle Ages (Belloc, Drago, and Galbiati Reference Belloc, Drago and Galbiati2016; Richardson Reference Richardson2005; Blaydes and Paik Reference Blaydes and Paik2016; Becker, Rubin, and Woessmann Reference Becker, Rubin, Woessmann, Alberto and Giovanni2021). Specifically, we look beyond the role of the Church as a “legitimizing agent” (Greif and Rubin Reference Greif and Rubin2024; Rubin Reference Rubin2017), and we focus on its economic performance as a local landlord compared to its secular counterparts. Moreover, we highlight differences between religious rulers and suggest the importance of the internal organization of religious institutions. Further, Doucette and Møller (Reference Doucette and Møller2021) related the proximity to Benedictine monasteries of Cluniac tradition to the emergence of self-governance at an age of collapse of state institutions, as they promoted religious autonomy from secular lords and lord-bishops. Our paper complements these findings by suggesting the importance of Benedictine monasteries as elements of institutional persistence through political and social turmoil and transitions.

Finally, few papers in the management literature (Inauen et al. Reference Inauen, Katja Rost, Frey and Osterloh2010a; Rost et al. Reference Rost, Inauen, Osterloh and Frey2010; Inauen et al. Reference Inauen, Rost, Osterloh and Frey2010b; Rost and Graetzer Reference Rost and Graetzer2014) looked at Benedictine monasteries, finding that their high survival rate may be due to their better governance structure (including, among other things, the election of the abbot and the participation of their members in the decision-making process). Our findings are consistent with their analysis. However, those papers focus mainly on one or, at most, a few case studies and only look at comparisons within Benedictine monasteries, rather than between monasteries and other types of landlords, or between Benedictine monasteries and other types of monasteries, as we do in this paper.

HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

The Norman Conquest and the DDB

In 1066, William, Duke of Normandy, invaded England, conquering it at the Battle of Hastings. He claimed he was the legitimate heir of the Anglo-Saxon King Edward, Footnote 6 who was his cousin once removed. Upon Edward’s death, however, the kingdom passed to his brother-in-law, Harold, triggering the Norman invasion and the end of the Anglo-Saxon era. William’s arrival was not good news for Benedictine monasteries: they were historically well aligned with the Anglo-Saxon monarchy (Knowles Reference Knowles1963; Barlow Reference Barlow1979).

Having seized power, William replaced the Anglo-Saxon elite with his own noblemen in order to secure his position (Finn Reference Finn1963). Land belonging to Anglo-Saxons was re-distributed, mainly to Norman noblemen loyal to William and, in some cases, to monasteries or other ecclesiastical rulers. Fleming (1991) and Thomas (Reference Thomas2008) discuss the methods behind the redistribution. According to Thomas (Reference Thomas2008, ch. 3), the four methods were the following. First, direct succession, id est William appointed a Norman landlord as the successor of a dispossessed Anglo-Saxon landlord. Second, military protection. Third, “in some areas, William lumped together all or most of the lands of minor landholders that were ‘left over’ after the redistribution of major estates and gave them to a single Norman lord.” Finally, “Norman nobles, particularly sheriffs, also simply grabbed new lands.”

The redistribution process that started after the Conquest was not limited to the highest level of the feudal structure, but it kicked off a further process of “subinfeudation” at lower levels of the hierarchy (Barlow 1999, p. 92). The upper level of the feudal structure was composed, in Norman times, by “Tenant-in-chiefs.” They received the land from the King, sometimes keeping it under their direct control (hence the Tenant-in-Chief is also the direct lord of an estate), sometimes granting it to other people (McDonald and Snooks Reference McDonald and Snooks1986). In those cases, the lord of an estate is different from its Tenant-in-Chief. Given the complexity of the DDB, lordship attribution is not always unambiguous. Some holdings are shared between multiple lords, hence the need to find a rule to harmonize those observations, as explained later. In some cases, the lordship is unclear (i.e., “20 freemen”). Finally, there are dependencies of manors and “non-manorial units,” which are typically “vills” without a manor in them (Palmer Reference Palmer and Holt1987). In all those cases, the degree of autonomy of the local lord (or lords) in terms of governance with respect to the Tenant-in-Chief is unclear.

Twenty years after the Conquest, William commissioned a complete survey of the land ownership under his reign, grouping the counties into seven circuits with groups of commissioners responsible for each one of them. The result is known as the DDB, “because its decisions, like those of the last judgement, are unalterable.” Footnote 7 Several scholars (Darby Reference Darby1977; McDonald and Snooks 1987; McDonald Reference McDonald1997) have looked at the content of the DDB and how the data were gathered. The objective of this data collection is still debated, but according to McDonald and Snooks (Reference McDonald and Snooks1986), it was a combination of two elements: an assessment of the ability to pay taxes and a clarification of the feudal structure of the kingdom. William dispatched royal commissioners throughout his kingdom, and the data they gathered (a holding’s “value to its owner,” id est our measure of productive capacity, in 1066 and 1086, name of its landlord in 1066, and 1086 and so on and so on) were then verified in open court (McDonald and Snooks 1987). Valuations of a holding’s productive capacity were collected in pounds and shillings, which, at the time, existed only as units of accountancy (Finn Reference Finn1963). Overall, the DDB seems to provide a reliable measure of land “value” and tax assessment (McDonald and Snooks Reference McDonald and Snooks1986), and its data are suitable for cliometrics analysis (McDonald and Snooks 1987).

Other Ecclesiastical and Secular Landlords

The manorial economy that prevailed in Western Europe, as well as in England, in the tenth and eleventh centuries was essentially based on private contracts between landlords and peasants. In such a system, the most efficient way for the King to enforce political power lay in granting large estates “to be organised as petty kingdoms” (North and Thomas Reference North and Thomas1973, p. 32). In exchange for protection, peasants provided some fixed labor to the landlord through a form of serfdom that was alternative and different from pure slavery: landlords (of all types) were the supreme local authority of the estate, monopolizing the use of force to administer justice and secure protection for all the people living there (North and Thomas Reference North and Thomas1973). According to Postan (Reference Postan1973, p. 82), “manors functioned as a local police authority.” However, while the governance of Benedictine houses was constrained by Benedict’s Rule, secular lords did not face such a constraint, neither in their selection process nor in the obligation to listen to an “advisory board.”

Large manors were also held by bishops. They enjoyed a powerful religious legitimacy that ultimately rested on the authority of the Pope, and a more structured organization. Importantly, the roles of bishops as heads of Dioceses and as landlords did not necessarily overlap, meaning that bishops could hold land in places that were not part of their Diocese. Those religious figures, however, were also free from the constraints of the Rule.

Benedictine Monasteries and Their Governance

The Benedictine order was (and still is) composed of a set of monasteries that are committed to following the Rule written by Benedict of Nursia in the early Middle Ages (Knowles Reference Knowles1963). They quickly became the most important monastic order in Europe, at least until the Cistercian reform in the twelfth century. They arrived in England in 597 AD and built a monastery at Canterbury. English Benedictine monasteries grew rapidly and acquired control of several holdings (Aston Reference Aston1958; Ayton and Davis Reference Ayton and Davis1987). Importantly, the management of those holdings was highly centralized and was kept controlled by the monastic community until the twelfth century (Knowles Reference Knowles1963).

Each individual monastery was an autonomous entity run by an abbot (there was no “head of the order”); therefore, common membership in the same order was granted by adherence to the Rule. As Knowles (Reference Knowles1963, p. 101) notes, by the time of the Conquest, monastic houses were substantially independent from each other, with no kind of federation or formal interdependence in place.

Even though the main purpose of the Rule was ascetic, it contained detailed and comprehensive instructions for the community of monks (prayer times, kitchen duties, and so forth). Its importance for the efficiency of monastic life has been noted by scholars of management science (Rost and Graetzer Reference Rost and Graetzer2014; Ehrmann, Rost, and Inauen Reference Ehrmann, Rost and Inauen2013; Rost Reference Rost, Robert and Buchmann2017). Inevitably, some of the rules were dedicated to the way the community was governed (Rost Reference Rost, Robert and Buchmann2017). Chapter 64 of the Rule explains that the abbot is an elective office (elected for life by the monks) and that unanimity in the community is not necessary.

Peasants were not allowed to vote or to participate in the political decision-making process, and the accountability of the abbot to the community was limited, as he was expected to be in charge for the rest of his life. However, the selection method mentioned earlier seems quite different from the standard feudal institutional arrangements, where a lord was not elected but simply appointed by the King or by the Tenant-in-Chief. This is also different from the way in which bishops were chosen. It is important to note, however, that we should not think about abbatial elections as we conceive them in the twenty-first century. They were not always free from external interference, especially by different kings (Burton Reference Burton1994). More details in Online Appendix G. William was able to impose abbots of his choice, but the process was longer and more difficult than in the case of secular lords or bishops (Knowles Reference Knowles1963, pp. 103, 106). Another important feature of monastic governance was the Chapter, the assembly of all the monks in the community. The Rule of St. Benedict (ch. 3) already mentioned it, although it stated that the final decision lied with the abbot. Consent of the Chapter was important, especially for the acquisition or alienation of properties, to avoid future controversies (Knowles Reference Knowles1963, p. 413). King William’s appointees “no doubt disposed of all things within and without their houses with very little reference to the wishes of their subjects” (Knowles Reference Knowles1963, p. 412), but the formal consent of the Chapter was already required, on some matters, before the Conquest (p. 412). Unlike ancient Parliaments, the Chapter did not need formal consent from the Abbot to meet.

Celtic Monasteries

Although most of the monasteries in our sample are Benedictine, a few of them belong to a different tradition: the Celtic one. According to Dell’Omo (Reference Dell’Omo2011), both traditions were present at the same time on English soil, although eventually virtually every monastery became Benedictine. The Celtic monastic tradition developed in Ireland during its Christianization. According to Dell’Omo (Reference Dell’Omo2011), this monastic tradition had important differences with respect to the “Benedictine” one in terms of liturgy and calendar, clothing, and architecture. We do not know the exact content of the rules that were followed in individual Celtic monasteries, but something can be learned from the most ancient rule of this tradition: the Rule of St. Columbanus, which was completely silent about how an abbot should be chosen; there was no explicit mention of elections nor of monastic Chapters and their advisory roles.Footnote 8

DATA

We assembled an original dataset (Rossignoli and Trombetta 2024) by gathering information from a variety of different sources, as briefly outlined in Table E1 (Online Appendix E), creating a dataset consisting of more than 9,000 observations at the level of holdings. Footnote 9 The main source of information is the DDB.Footnote 10 The most important information included in the DDB is the name of the lord of the holding in 1066, during the reign of King Edward (i.e., before the Norman Conquest), and the name of the lord in 1086, at the time the DDB was compiled during the reign of King William. As carefully studied in Delabastita and Maes (Reference Delabastita and Maes2023), the feudal structure described in the DDB is quite complex and has multiple levels. For every holding, the data allow us to identify two levels of the feudal structure: the upper one, immediately below the King (defined as Overlord in 1066 and Tenant-in-Chief in 1086), and the lower one, defined as “lord” in both time periods. We run our analysis at the lord level, to attribute performance to whoever was managing the land. More specifically, by “lord” or “landlord” in this analysis, we mean what Palmer (2008) codes as “Lord 66” and “Lord 86,” respectively, that is, “lord of the estate in 1066, in receipt of the profits of the holding” (for Lord 66) and “the immediate lord of the peasantry, either the Tenant-in-Chief himself or a tenant to whom he had granted the estate” (for Lord 86). This implies that, when we define whether an estate changed its landlord or remained with the same one, we look at the “lord” name only. Overlords and Tenant-in-Chiefs, the upper levels of the feudal structure (in his codebook, Palmer (2008) defines them as “Overlord of the 1066 estate; Overlord of the ‘men’ in possession in 1066” and “Tenant-in-Chief of the estate, holding directly of the Crown”),Footnote 11 may or may not coincide with the Lord, and may or may not change after the Conquest. The King himself appears both as Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief and as lord. To keep track of the full structure without losing many observations, we use the “lord 66” name (if available) to replace missing Overlords’ names. The DDB reports 48 different landlord names referring to a monastery in 1066 (before the Conquest) and 80 in 1086 (after the Conquest). Footnote 12 To identify whether the landlord is a Benedictine monastery, we matched landlord names, as recorded in the DDB, with the names of Benedictine houses retrieved from the English Monastic Archive (D’Avray Reference D’Avray2015). Through the investigation of landlord names, we also identified holdings held by bishops and other non-monastic ecclesiastical landlords.

Thus, we classify all the entries in our dataset according to the following three types, at two points in time (before and after the Norman Conquest): Benedictine, when the landlord is a Benedictine monastery; Other Ecclesiastic, when the landlord is a bishop, the canon of a cathedral church, a deacon, or other non-monastic ecclesiastical figure; Secular, when the landlord is none of the ones previously noted, mostly a nobleman or the King himself. We also identified a few non-Benedictine monasteries of Celtic tradition, that are excluded from our main analysis and only included in the direct comparison with Benedictine as they usually do not have two data points for their valuation.

Note that the structure of the DDB is very complex and entails both holdings shared by multiple landlords and holdings spanning different locations. Footnote 13 Therefore, we needed to devise a rule to obtain a unique observational unit for our analysis. Since our focus is on holdings, we decided to collapse multiple observations based on the largest value attributed to a single landlord in the holding. The DDB reports this value for both 1066 and 1086. When this information is not available, or in the event of ties, we assign the land to the landlord who has not changed between 1066 and 1086. In case of further ties between landlords of different types, in 1086 we assign the holding to a secular landlord or an “Other ecclesiastical” landlord if a secular is not present. In 1066, we assign priorities in reverse order, that is to a monastery, or an “Other ecclesiastical” landlord if no lord is a monastery; in the event of further ties, we assign a random number to rows and pick the landlord with the lowest random number attached. We keep the “randomized” holdings in the sample, showing robustness checks for their exclusion in Online Appendix D (Tables D5–D9). Benedictine coefficients are somewhat smaller and sometimes lose statistical significance, but the broad picture is consistent with the main result.

In attributing landlords to holdings, we assign a missing value to a landlord whose name, for the year 1086, is a general expression such as “one Englishman,” “two thanes,” or the like, rather than an actual name. Although we include these holdings in our dataset, unambiguously attributing their “type” and attaching to them all the relevant control variables, we did not compute a landlord-specific identifier for such items. Hence, we coded those cases as “ambiguous landlords in 1086” and excluded them from the sample in the main analysis. However, including them does not affect the results, as shown in Online Appendix D. Lords ambiguously defined in 1066 are typically included in the sample.

We always exclude from the sample holdings codified as boroughs to get a homogeneous sample of rural holdings. We exclude from the sample about 0.4 percent of holdings attributed to Benedictine nuns to obtain a homogeneous “treatment” group composed of male Benedictine monasteries.Footnote 14 We further exclude from our sample 90 observations (about 0.5 percent of total “raw” observations) that we classify as outliers, whose difference in the log-transformed value is larger than 4, id est larger than the 99th percentile in the distribution of “raw” observations.

A few monastic houses were created toward the end of our observation range (e.g., Shrewsbury or Durham). We exclude these holdings from the main specification, as it is hard to attribute the change in performance between 1066 and 1086 to their ownership. However, their inclusion does not affect the results (Online Appendix D).

Figures 1a and 1b provide a graphical representation of the geographical distribution of holdings by type of lord before (1066) and after (1086) the Conquest.

Figure 1 LORD TYPES IN ENGLAND BEFORE AND AFTER THE CONQUEST

Sources: See text and Online Appendix E.

Outcome Variable

As explained previously, some of the information in DDB is available at two points in time: the first refers to the last moment before the Norman Conquest, thus we label it 1066; the second refers to the time the DDB was written, after the Conquest, thus we label it 1086.Footnote 15 Exploiting this feature, we obtain from the DDB the main outcome variable of our analysis, id est the holding’s “value” in 1066 and 1086, from which we calculate the overall growth rate. Footnote 16 Historians have widely debated the actual meaning of the information on “values” recorded in the DDB (McDonald and Snooks Reference McDonald and Snooks1986; Roffe Reference Roffe2000). We interpret them as measures of income or productivity, similarly to Delabastita and Maes (Reference Delabastita and Maes2023),Footnote 17 as these data have been shown to be highly consistent with all the related variables reported in the DDB (McDonald and Snooks 1987), as well as when compared to subsequent historical surveys of some regions of England (Wareham Reference Wareham2000). Roffe (2007, p. 241), instead, interprets them as cash payments from the tenants to the owner, hence excluding other forms of payments.

To study additional economic and social mechanisms, we also include information about the estate’s total population. This information is available only at one point in time and only for a limited subsample; therefore, it cannot be used to fully replicate our main analysis. Population is calculated as the sum of all categories of people living on the estate, namely: villagers, smallholders, freemen, cottagers, slaves, burgesses, and cases listed as “other population.” Furthermore, we include information about the presence of mills and plows. The source is always the DDB.

Controls

The most important difference between holdings is likely to depend on their geographical location. The digitized version of the DDB includes important geographical information related to each entry: Ordinance Survey Grid positions that we converted into Latitude and Longitude; County and Hundred (local district). Using this information, we can also match our holdings with data on various features that may influence the outcome. As summarized in Table E1, we group those controls into three sets: geography (latitude, terrain quality, and so on), history (distance to Roman road, Viking influence, and so on), and market access (distance to boroughs, fairs, and so on). A more detailed description of all the controls is in Online Appendix E.

EMPIRICAL STRATEGY

The objective of this paper is to study the role of religious institutions, and Benedictine monasteries in particular, and their economic impact on the land they controlled. The first explanatory variable is a dummy equal to 1 if a holding was controlled by a religious landlord (either a Benedictine monastery or an “Other Ecclesiastic”). Then we consider the two types of religious lords separately, comparing them with the same benchmark (secular lords). The outcome variable is the holding’s value in 1066 and 1086. The relationship between these two variables is likely to be spurious for many reasons. Monasteries (and hence their estates) tended to be located in the southern part of England, and in the most ancient settled areas (Postan Reference Postan1973). Moreover, monasteries or bishops may have been granted systematically better (or worse) holdings. Indeed, historical evidence has shown that some of the most strenuous opponents William faced after he landed in England were Benedictine monasteries, since most of the monks were part of the Anglo-Saxon aristocracy (Knowles Reference Knowles1963). Furthermore, monasteries remained active both before and after the Conquest, while the secular aristocracy was almost entirely replaced. To isolate the effect of the institutional structure, we employ two different strategies. The first uses the post-1066 change in control of holdings formerly owned by the Anglo-Saxon nobility as a historical caesura, comparing holdings whose direct lord changed from secular to one of the several types of owners (secular, religious, Benedictine, “other ecclesiastical”) between 1066 and 1086. The second consists of the application of a matching estimation technique to focus the analysis on the most similar holdings, as outlined in Online Appendix B. Furthermore, we exploit the geographical information contained in our dataset, which allows us to compare holdings of different ownerships located in the same small administrative area. This further strategy is reported in Online Appendix A.

Changes in Direct Management and DID Estimation

Following the Norman Conquest, many holdings belonging to Anglo-Saxon landlords were re-assigned by King William and by his Tenants-in-Chiefs. Of course, land could change ownership for other reasons during the same period. In this specification, we focus on the sub-sample of holdings owned by Anglo-Saxon lords that changed their lord after the Norman Conquest, using those that ended up under the control of religious lords (and then by Benedictine monasteries and by “Other ecclesiastic” in separate models) as the “treatment group” and the rest as the “control group.”

Figure 2 CHANGE IN LORD TYPES

Notes: Holdings with changing lords between 1066 and 1086 are depicted. Gray dots: secular to secular lords (likely Anglo-Saxon to Norman nobleman). Blue dots: secular to “Other ecclesiastic.” Maroon dots: secular to monastery. Black crosses: monasteries. Map excludes holdings with missing value and outliers.

Sources: See text and Online Appendix E.

The fact that the lordship of every holding in this sample has changed allows us to disentangle the effect of a change in direct control from the effect of being controlled by a religious ruler.

Using the panel structure of the dataset, we are estimating a DID specification, where we compare pre- and post-Conquest (log of one plus) value for holdings moving from an Anglo-Saxon secular landlord to a religious ruler and holdings moving from an Anglo-Saxon secular landlord to a Norman landlord. Footnote 18 In practice, we estimate

(1) $${{\text{Y}}_{i,t}} = {\tau _t} + {\mu _i} + \varphi Religiou{s_{i,t}} + {\lambda ^{\text{'}}}{x_{i,t}} + { \in _{i,t}}$$

where Y i,t is the log of one plus the annual value of holding i at time t, τ t is the time fixed effect, µ i is the holding fixed effect, Religious i,t is a dummy equal to 1 if holding i is controlled by a religious lord at time t, and x i,t is a vector of time varying and time invariant controls interacted with the time fixed effect. Note that in our sample, Religious i,t is always equal to 0 in 1066. Under the assumptions of parallel trends and that nothing else happens at the same time that affects the treatment and control groups differently, φ captures the causal effect of being controlled by a religious landlord on our measure of land productive capacity. Note that we are taking account of every time invariant holding-specific characteristic. A similar model is used to compare separately holdings whose new landlord was a Benedictine monastery or an “Other ecclesiastic” with those whose new landlord was secular. Religious i,t is replaced by Benedictine i,t or by OthEccl i,t, respectively, and holdings ending up with the other religious landlord type are excluded from those samples. Standard errors are clustered at the “Lord 1086” level, but all our results are robust to different clustering strategies (Online Appendix A).

Threats to Identification

Given that we are using historical data and we have only two time periods, unfortunately, we cannot test the parallel trend assumption directly. However, as explained in the historical background section, we are not aware of any historical evidence that reports King William systematically favoring religious figures, especially monasteries, when he re-assigned land. Looking at the balance tests, which we summarize in Figures A1, A2, and A3, reported in Online Appendix A, we note that most of the observables are not statistically different between the treatment (however this is defined) and control groups. Table 2 displays the coefficients and p-values of the balance tests for Benedictine and Other Ecclesiastic. In both cases, most of the control variables are balanced. Among those that are different, those related to agricultural productivity and pasture suitability, if anything, work “against” estates owned by religious landlords; some others (latitude, but also distance to Roman settlements, Roman roads, Anglo-Saxon settlements, and London) arise from the well-known tendency of monasteries to be in Southern England. This is clearly due to pre-existing historical reasons (as pointed out earlier, Fleming (Reference Fleming1985) shows a difference in ecclesiastic landholding above and below “Viking Street”) that are time invariant and hence unlikely to induce a systematic bias in the coefficient. New monasteries spread all over England, starting in Canterbury, maintaining cultural and religious ties with Rome and the continental European application of the Rule of St Benedict. Distance to markets is also lower in all the treatment groups. To deal with those unbalances, we interact all the controls with the time dummy, adding them to the estimation. Finally, the levels of the holdings’ values pre-Conquest are never statistically different between groups.

While the re-assignment procedure was clearly not random, it is possible that the King could have chosen not to re-assign holdings with a higher growth prospect to his allies. Historians seem to agree that the main reasons driving the land reshuffle were internal and external security, something that was already a concern in Anglo-Saxon times (Fleming Reference Fleming1985). On top of that, the King could have assigned those high-prospect estates directly to himself. We do not find conclusive evidence in support of this case, as a comparison between the King’s and secular landlords’ holdings, summarized in Table A5, shows a figure that is most of the time negative (or close to zero) and just once weakly positive. This noisy outcome does not provide conclusive evidence supporting the claim of a systematic pattern in William’s land reassignment to himself. Furthermore, if we look at the holdings whose Tenant-in-Chiefs were the most important followers of the King, we do not observe a stable pattern, especially in terms of agricultural productivity (graphic summaries of these tests are reported in the Online Appendix; see Figures A4–A8). Overall, the data are consistent with the idea that William conducted the re-assignment without discriminating in favor of religious rulers.

Although some of the changes in the identity of those controlling the land are probably direct or indirect consequences of the re-assignment procedure put in place by William, we can only observe whether the direct lord of the estate is the same in 1066 and 1086 or not. We do not have full information about the reasons behind this change, and sometimes the lordship changes without modifications in the name of the Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief. In those cases, the upper level of the feudal structure remained unchanged, while the lower level changed. This may have been a strategic choice of the Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief. If this is the case, this could be a violation of the parallel trend assumption. Moreover, holdings experiencing this type of lordship change typically had a Benedictine Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief, as very few secular Overlords remained in place in 1086. Furthermore, when the attribution of the 1066 lordship is unclear, it is particularly challenging to assess whether a change in governance has actually happened. To deal with this, we do four things. (1) We run the basic DID, excluding from the sample holdings whose lordship in 1066 is ambiguously attributed. The effect is no longer statistically significant, except for the first column. Hence, the effect is not robust to this more restrictive sample, but it remains significant if, instead of removing observations with an ambiguous lord in 1066, we add a fixed effect interacted with time fixed effect (FE). (2) We perform a heterogeneity analysis by interacting our main “treatment” dummy with a dummy equal to 1 if the Lord in 1086 was different from the one in 1066 but was the same as the Overlord in 1066 and the Tenant-in-chief in 1086 (including those remaining under the Crown). This analysis shows that the positive effect of Benedictine control is mostly driven by those estates. (3) We show that the main result is robust to the introduction of a dummy equal to 1 if the Overlord (pre-determined at the time of the treatment) was a Benedictine monastery, interacted with time fixed effect. (4) We show that those specific monastic holdings driving the result are better than those experiencing a similar pattern in ownership change, that is, those whose 1086 landlord became the Crown, which was also the Overlord and the Tenant-in-chief, but not the 1066 landlord. This last result is robust to the exclusion of holdings whose lord in 1066 was ambiguously defined, although it is driven by very few observations in this restricted sample. It does not allow us to disentangle the “Benedictine effect” from the fact that they do not change across the Conquest (while the person holding the Crown changes).

Another potential threat to the identification may come from a differential effect in the tax treatment of the land. In this respect, the analysis from Pratt (Reference Pratt2013) is reassuring. Land tax was introduced in Anglo-Saxon times to pay for tributes and, more generally, for the war effort against the Danish invaders (Wareham 2012). In Norman times, it seems that all the demesne land of Tenant-in-Chiefs, both secular and ecclesiastical, was exempt (Pratt Reference Pratt2013, p. 2). We use this fact as a robustness check, showing that our results are still true in the subsample of “demesne only” land, based on observations where tax treatment was the same. Footnote 19 Finally, we are not aware of other events that systematically affected one of the two groups of holdings.Footnote 20

RESULTS

Change of Landlord Types and DID Estimation

RELIGIOUS VERSUS SECULAR LANDLORDS

Table 1 describes in detail the sample we use for our main empirical strategy (our DID analysis), showing group-specific summary statistics, while statistics for the full sample are shown in Table E2. As mentioned, we keep only estates that were held by secular landlords in 1066 and whose owners changed between 1066 and 1086. In this case, we are exploiting the panel structure of our dataset, and the outcome variable is the log of one plus value in 1066 and 1086. Therefore, we can interpret the results as the differential effect on the (approximate) productive capacity growth rate calculated over 20 years. As most of the control variables are time-invariant, we add them to the specification after multiplying them by the time fixed effect. Table 1 shows that Benedictine holdings display on average a positive growth rate in their value between 1066 and 1086, “secular” holdings have a negative growth over the same period, and “Other ecclesiastic” holdings experience a small decrease.

Table 1 SUMMARY STATISTICS (SUBSAMPLE) BY GROUPS

Notes: Summary statistics by treatment group. The t-stats for differences are computed by clustering standard errors at landlord level (1086).

* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Sources: See text and Online Appendix E.

The results of Model (1) are reported in Panel A of Table 2. We report only the estimated values for φ.

Table 2 HOLDING VALUE: DIFFERENT RELIGIOUS LEADERS RELIGIOUS VS. SECULAR LANDLORD

Notes: Diff-in-Diff analysis, two periods (1066, 1086). Sample: 7151 secular holdings, 404 Religious holdings (Panel A); 160 Benedictine holdings (Panel B), 244 Oth. Eccl. Holdings (Panel C). Dependent variable: log(1+value). Standard errors clustered at 1086 landlord level. Excluded: ambiguous lords (1086), female monasteries, non-Benedictine monasteries, post-1076 monasteries, outliers (growth rate > 4). Panel B: “Other ecclesiastic” lords (1086) estates excluded. Panel C: Benedictine lords (1086) estates excluded.

1 Geography controls include geographic/agriculture related features, namely: latitude, longitude, latitude×longitude, median altitude, crop suitability, ruggedness, pasture suitability, agricultural suitability, animal husbandry suitability, distance to mines, and (log of) size.

2 Market access controls include proxies for access to markets: distance (in km) to: rivers, coast, London, nearest borough, and markets.

3 History controls include proxies for the ancientness of the settlement, namely: distance (in km) to Roman settlements, to Roman roads, and to Anglo-Saxon settlements; Viking influence in tenth century.

* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Sources: See text and Online Appendix E.

All the coefficients are positive, although not all the specifications are significant, suggesting the existence of heterogeneous effects that need to be explored. Therefore, guided by the important institutional differences described, we divide the analysis of religious properties into two groups: holdings controlled by Benedictine monasteries and those controlled by non-monastic figures, such as bishops, deacons, and canons. The formers were constrained by the Rule of St Benedict and its institutional structure. The latter were not.

DIFFERENT RELIGIOUS LANDLORDS

In this section, we estimate the same model described in Equation (1), but we change the “treatment” dummy comparing Benedictine monasteries and Other ecclesiastical landlords with secular rulers in separate estimations.

Panel B of Table 2 reports the results of the comparison between holdings whose new landlord was a Benedictine monastery and those whose new landlord was secular. The estimates are broadly consistent across all the columns: holdings that end up being controlled by Benedictine monasteries experienced a higher 20-year productive capacity growth rate (approximately 5 to 12 percentage points more). As shown in Table A10, results are similar if we use the doubly robust DID estimator proposed by Sant’Anna and Zhao (2020). Hence, our parallel trend assumption needs only to be satisfied conditional on covariates.

In Panel C of Table 2, we report the estimates of the same model, but here the “treatment” dummy is equal to one when the land owned by an Anglo-Saxon nobleman (secular) in 1066 was controlled by a non-monastic other ecclesiastical landlord in 1086. Interestingly, we find no statistically significant difference, meaning that changing landlord and being controlled by an “Other ecclesiastic” landlord did not lead to a statistically significant change in productive capacity growth rate. The dimension of the coefficients is about one-third of those associated with monasteries, but the difference between the two is not statistically significant. Note that bishops and other non-monastic ecclesiastical landlords were usually educated, and their authority was based on a religious element, as in the case of abbots.

Results in Table 2, Panel B, are robust to a wide range of checks (e.g., different levels of clustering, exclusion of “randomized” holdings, etc.), as discussed in the Online Appendix. They are not, however, fully robust to a few sample restrictions. In particular, the coefficient is smaller and remains statistically significant only in the baseline specifications if we exclude holdings that changed lord but not Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief, or holdings whose lord in 1066 was “ambiguous” (Tables D10 and D12, Online Appendix D. Those groups partially overlap). If instead we add an “ambiguous lord 1066 fixed effect” interacted with time, the Benedictine coefficient remains significant (Table D11, Online Appendix D). In the restricted samples, the number of “Benedictine” observations is reduced by roughly one-third. Taken together, those restrictions seem to suggest that the effect we find is mostly driven by holdings that do not change Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief and whose lordship attribution is partially unclear. As the credibility of the parallel trend assumption is lower in this subsample, we explore these heterogeneities in greater detail.

Heterogeneity across Overlordship

In this section, we explore the heterogeneity of the Benedictine effect across different levels of the feudal structure. We define the dummy variable “Stable OL/TC” equal to 1 for those holdings where the lord in 1086 was the same as the Tenant-in-Chief in 1086 and the same as the Overlord in 1066, but different from the lord in 1066. Importantly, for this variable (and for this section), we consider the stability of the institution of the Crown, rather than of the actual person who holds it. Hence, holdings whose Overlord was King Edward and whose lord and Tenant-in-Chief in 1086 was King William are coded as 1. Extending this notion to the “lord” level changes the definition of the sample we are using, as holdings whose landlord was King Edward in 1066 and King William in 1087 would now be considered “stable,” and hence excluded. To show what happens when we consider the “Stable OL/TC” variable irrespective of changes in the definition of the sample, we present our results in Table 3 in two panels. In Panel A, we add “Stable OL/TC” using the same sample as in the earlier analysis. In Panel B, we exclude from the sample holdings whose lord was Edward in 1066 and William in 1086. Results remain very similar. In Table 3, we perform the usual DID analysis, but we add “Stable OL/TC” interacted with the time dummy, with the Benedictine i,t dummy and with all the controls. From this analysis, we can learn two lessons. First, the “Benedictine” effect is stronger among holdings whose lord was secular in 1066 and ended up being controlled by a landlord (and Tenant-in-Chief) in 1086, who was already the Overlord in 1066. Second, the “Benedictine effect” among holdings where Stable OL/TC is equal to 0 is always positive, although it loses significance once we introduce the usual set of controls. Hence, the overall effect we find in Table 3, Panel B, is driven mainly by holdings with a secular lord and a Benedictine Overlord in 1066 that ended up being controlled (both at lord and TC level) by the same Benedictine house in 1086. For this subgroup, the parallel trend assumption is questionable: the highest level of the feudal structure remained the same before and after the Conquest; hence, the change in the lower layer may be due to its strategic initiative rather than to the Conquest. To alleviate this concern, we perform two more tests, whose results are shown in Tables 4 and 5.

Table 3 HOLDING VALUE: BENEDICTINE VS. SECULAR LANDLORD, HETEROGENEITY ANALYSIS

Notes: Diff-in-Diff analysis, two periods (1066, 1086). Sample: 7,151 (Panel A), 7,058 (Panel B) secular holdings, and 160 Benedictine holdings (both panels). Panel A: main results. Panel B: excludes observations with Crown holding same estate in 1066 and 1086. Dependent variable: log(1+value). Standard errors clustered at 1086 landlord level. Excluded: ambiguous lords (1086), female monasteries, non-Benedictine monasteries, post-1076 monasteries, outliers (growth rate > 4), and “Other ecclesiastic” lords (1086).

1 Geography, Market, and History control variables are the same as listed in the note to Table 2. All specifications also include Stable OL/TC *time and control variables are also interacted with Stable OL/TC.

* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Sources: See text and Online Appendix E.

Table 4 shows that our main results, presented in Table 2, Panel B, hold when we add to all regressions a dummy equal to 1 if the Overlord was a Benedictine Monastery of any genderFootnote 21 interacted with the time dummy. This alleviates the concern described previously, as we are now conditioning on the monastic identity of the upper level of the feudal structure as defined before the Conquest. As shown, “Benedictine” coefficients are a bit smaller, but they maintain their statistical significance.

Table 4 HOLDING VALUE: BENEDICTINE VS. SECULAR LANDLORD, ADDING BENEDICTINE OVERLORD DUMMY

Notes: Diff-in-Diff analysis, two periods (1066, 1086). Sample: 7151 secular, 160 Benedictine holdings. Dependent variable: log(1+value). Standard errors clustered at 1086 landlord level. Excluded: ambiguous lords (1086), female monasteries, non-Benedictine monasteries, post-1076 monasteries, outliers (growth rate > 4), and “Other ecclesiastic” lords (1086).

1 Geography, Market, and History control variables are the same as listed in the note to Table 2.

* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Sources: See text and Online Appendix E.

Table 5 shows a comparison, within “constant Overlordship,” between holdings whose landlords were secular in 1066 (excluding those already having the King as 1066 lord) and those that ended up in Benedictine or royal hands in 1086, both at lord and Tenant-in-Chief levels.Footnote 22 This is done to partially address the concern that the effect captured by the interaction term in Table 3 is driven by the possibility of strategically choosing which holdings to control in 1086. This possibility may have occurred for estates whose Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief has always been the same monastery, while it surely was present for estates whose Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief was the Crown. Despite this, the coefficient of Benedictine i,t is positive, significant (with the exception of the last column, probably due to the large number of controls with few observations), and fairly sizeable. Furthermore, this result is robust, in most of the models, to the sample restriction that excludes lords ambiguously defined in 1066, where the main coefficient of Table 2 loses significance. However, note that this result is driven by very few observations.

Of course, this analysis presents several limitations: the sample size is quite small; the identity of the Overlord could correlate with the outcome through unobservable confounders; and, of course, the person holding the Crown changes between 1066 and 1086. Figure A9 in Online Appendix A shows the balance between “treated” and “control” observations in this further subsample. They tend to be different on many dimensions, but it is reassuring to note that the outcome variable for 1066 is smaller for the treatment group than for the control group, hence they were not better ex ante.

Table 5 HOLDING VALUE: BENEDICTINE VS. ROYAL LANDLORD, STABLE OL/TC HOLDINGS SUBSAMPLE

Notes: Diff-in-Diff analysis, two periods (1066 and 1086). Sample: 26 secular, 37 Benedictine holdings. Sample: Tenant-in-Chief same in 1086 as 1086 landlord, but not 1066 landlord. Overlord/Tenant-in-Chief: King or Benedictine monastery. Dependent variable: log(1+value). Robust standard errors clustered at the holding level, due to limited number of 1086 landlords. Excluded: ambiguous lords (1086), female monasteries, non-Benedictine monasteries, post-1076 monasteries, outliers (growth rate > 4), and estates with “Other ecclesiastic” lords (1086).

1 Geography, Market, and History control variables are the same as listed in the note to Table 2.

* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Sources: See text and Online Appendix E.

Other Mechanisms

In this section, we try to shed light on what additional mechanisms might explain the overperformance of monasteries. As discussed in the second section, there are a few possible reasons that have been highlighted. However, we can rule out those that are not related to the institutional structure of the Rule. More specifically, we control for the historical presence of Roman settlements in the area and for a wide range of other geographic characteristics. Hence, the effect we find is not due to those elements. The availability of cheap labor as a channel for prosperity, stressed by Ekelund et al. (Reference Ekelund, Hébert, Tollison, Anderson and Davidson1996), plays no role here, as conversi were not yet present in the period we are observing. We also show that geographical proximity to a monastery (as a proxy for its “hard work ethic” suggested by Andersen et al. Reference Andersen, Bentzen, Dalgaard and Sharp2017) had no effect on economic growth. Furthermore, older monasteries did not overperform more recent ones (as a proxy for human capital), and Benedictines performed better than holdings that did not change their lord between 1066 and 1086 (hence it is not just a matter of stability in lordship). Finally, excluding holdings close to their Benedictine lord or focusing only on holdings whose lord was also their Tenant-in-Chief in 1086 does not change our baseline result, ruling out the possibility that it is explained by the monks working directly on their land or by a different fiscal treatment. All those tests are discussed in detail in Online Appendix F.

Table 6 explores whether holdings with a Benedictine landlord in 1086 were different from holdings with secular landlords in 1086 in terms of population, plows, and mills. We use the same sample as in Equation (1), but in this case, we cannot estimate a DID because the outcome variable is referring to 1086 only (and only for a subset of observations). Consequently, we run an ordinary least squares (OLS) regression with Hundred fixed effects, like the exercise we describe in Online Appendix A. Given that the dependent variable is, at least partly, an outcome of who oversaw the land, we are not truly testing a “mechanism” here. Moreover, since we do not know the level of those outcome variables in 1066, it is impossible to know whether this result is due to pre-existing conditions or not. Despite this, Table 6 shows that on average, Benedictine holdings in 1086 had a larger population, number of plows and mills. We believe these results, and the latter, although based on a limited sample, are consistent with previous historical evidence, especially White’s (1958) and Knowles’ (Reference Knowles1963) idea of monasteries as “agricultural capitalists” (Knowles Reference Knowles1963, p. 441). Furthermore, mills have been proven to be important determinants of growth in human capital and industrialization (Mokyr, Sarid, and van der Beek Reference Mokyr, Sarid and van der Beek2022). As shown in Panels B and C, results are broadly robust to controlling for “Stable OL/TC” (both without changing the subsample (Panel B) and excluding holdings where the King is the landlord in 1066 and 1086 (Panel C)).

Table 6 ALTERNATIVE OUTCOMES, BENEDICTINES VS. SECULAR LANDLORDS

Notes: OLS cross-section. The number of observations is different due to limited availability of alternative dependent variables. Panel A: main results. Panel B: adds “stability” control (1066 Overlord same as 1086 Tenant-in-Chief). Panel C: excludes observations where King holds estate in both 1066 and 1086. Col (1): 7148 (Panels A and B), 7,055 (Panel C) secular, 160 Benedictine holdings. Col (2): 7,123 (Panels A and B), 7,030 (Panel C) secular, 159 Benedictine holdings. Col (3): 1,780 (Panels A and B), 1,727 (Panel C) secular, 43 Benedictine holdings. Dependent variables per column headings. Standard errors clustered at 1086 lord level. Excluded: ambiguous lords (1086), female monasteries, non-Benedictine monasteries, post-1076 monasteries, outliers (growth rate > 4), and holdings with “Other ecclesiastic” lords (1086).

1 Geography, Market, and History control variables are the same as listed in the note to Table 2.

* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Sources: See text and Online Appendix E.

Having ruled out all the channels that are not related to the institutional structure and the way leaders were chosen, we try to provide a more direct test of the institutional mechanism. One way to do so is to compare the performance of Benedictine-controlled holdings with those whose lord belongs to different monastic orders. Unfortunately, there was not much variation at the time of the Norman Conquest. However, Knowles and Hadcock (1971, p. 356) list a few non-Benedictine houses active in England around 1066 that belonged to the Celtic monastic tradition. The precise history of those houses is complicated. Knowles and Hadcock (1971) clarify that their list includes houses “thought to have existed until after 1066” and includes both Celtic monasteries and “Clas,” that is, communities of canons living under an abbot. Some of them became parochial soon after the Norman Conquest; others were re-founded as Benedictine monasteries, and so on. Given the restriction in our dataset, we code as “Celtic” all the houses mentioned as such (at any point in time between 1066 and 1086) in Knowles and Hadcock (1971) that we could find in our data, even when they are described as “canons” in the DDB. Unfortunately, for the vast majority, “values” are available only for 1086; hence, we cannot use panel data methods. Therefore, we run a simple OLS on a cross-sectional dataset where we compare them to holdings of Benedictine monasteries in 1086. To avoid losing any observations and given the fact that missing values for “Holding value (1066)” are not an issue in this specification, we use all the available observation with non-missing values recorded in 1086, including holdings that do not change landlord. We obtain a sample of 892 Benedictine holdings and 24 “Celtic” holdings. Given the small number of “control” observations, we decided not to include fixed effects for Hundreds nor Counties. Results are described in Table 7. They are somehow noisy because of the very small sample, but Benedictine holdings outperform those whose lords were Celtic monasteries both in the basic and in the full specification. Despite being weakened by the limitations in the available data, we interpret this result as suggesting that Benedictine monasteries tended to perform better than non-Benedictine monasteries, hence in some sense “controlling for” everything that makes monks a selected sample. As explained previously, one important point about the Rule of St. Benedict is its attention to the internal governance structure of a monastery, which is different from the Rule of St. Columbanus. Hence, we argue that this organizational structure may have been one of the reasons behind Benedictine’s success. Finally, note from Panel B that our results do not change much if we also control for a dummy variable equal to 1 if the Overlord and the Tenant-in-Chief do not change. Footnote 23 The p-value of Column (5) Panel B is 0.142.

Table 7 HOLDING VALUE: BENEDICTINES VS. CELTIC MONASTIC LANDLORDS

Notes: OLS cross-section based on 1086 outcomes. Sample: 892 Benedictine holdings and 24 Celtic monastery holdings, regardless of 1066 status. Panel A: main results. Panel B: adds control for Overlord stability (same in 1066 and 1086) in all columns. Dependent variable: log(1+value in 1086). Standard errors clustered at 1086 landlord level. Excluded: ambiguous lords (1086), female monasteries, post-1076 monasteries, outliers (growth rate > 4). Stability control added in Columns (2) and (5).

1 Geography, Market, and History control variables are the same as listed in the note to Table 2.

*p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Sources: See text and Online Appendix E.

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

Our results indicate that, conditional on a change in lordship between 1066 and 1086, holdings held by a secular lord in 1066 that end up being controlled by Benedictine monasteries performed significantly better than those that end up in the hands of a (different) secular lord. This result, however, is not fully robust to different ways of dealing with ambiguous lordship attribution in 1066 and is driven by holdings whose Overlord was already Benedictine in 1066, and remained such in 1086. As this choice can be strategic and it is unclear the extent to which the actual governance changed in these holdings, we compare these holdings with those whose Overlord was the Crown and that ended up under direct control of King William in 1086 (without having King Edward as landlord in 1066). Even in this case, where, in a sense, we control for the (realized) strategic choice, Benedictines performed better. The limitation of this case is the fact that we cannot separate Benedictine control from the absence of institutional change at the upper level of the feudal structure. Finally, we provide suggestive evidence showing that Benedictines tended to perform better than monastic communities of Celtic tradition.

Taken together, these results suggest that, in the most restrictive sample, a positive causal effect of Benedictine governance on productive capacity is statistically different from zero in the baseline specification, while significance is mostly lost in more demanding model specifications. A robust correlation exists in a less demanding sample, where we cannot fully disentangle Benedictine control from a higher probability of institutional persistence at the upper level of the feudal structure. By comparing Benedictine holdings with those of Celtic traditions, our results also suggest that the institutional structure of Benedictine monasteries could have played a role in driving our results.

This could have mattered in two ways. First, in protecting institutional stability in a period of great turmoil. Replacing a living abbot was not an easy task, as the position of abbots was legitimized by the Rule, and they had to interact with the Chapter. In fact, as stressed by Knowles (Reference Knowles1963), the “normanization” of monastic houses took longer than for bishops or secular landlords. In many cases, William had to wait for the death of an abbot before being able to impose one of his choices. The best example is given by the Abbey of Bury St Edmunds, which turns out to be the major contributor to the group of Benedictine holdings driving the result. Here, the abbot, Baldwin, was in power since before the Norman Conquest and survived King William as head of his monastic house. Second, better-selected or better-advised abbots may have been able to make better choices. As discussed, the decision-making power of an abbot was relevant and may have been translated into better economic outcomes or choices leading to those outcomes (e.g., in terms of technology, agricultural organization, and so on).

This paper sheds new light on the active role of the Catholic Church as a big landlord and a local political player in the aftermath of the Norman Conquest and assesses the economic results of “early democratic” institutional arrangements within the Catholic Church in the Middle Ages. Some of those practices have sometimes been adopted as a model by secular institutions (Stasavage Reference Stasavage2020; Grzymala-Busse Reference Grzymala-Busse2020). Moreover, we focus on the development of countryside areas, which are considerably less studied than cities and villages (Becker, Rubin, and Woessmann Reference Becker, Rubin, Woessmann, Alberto and Giovanni2021).

Footnotes

This work was supported by the Economic and Social Research Council [grant number DTC - ES/J500203/1]. An earlier version of this work appears as a chapter in the PhD thesis of one of the authors. A previous version of this paper circulated under the title “To appoint or to elect when an office is for life. Lessons from medieval England.” We acknowledge valuable comments and feedback from the editors, Dan Bogart and Bishnupriya Gupta, three anonymous referees, Sascha O. Becker, Carlo Beretta, Simona Beretta, Dan Bernhardt, Nina Brooks, Peter Buisseret, Bruce M. Campbell, Jonathan Chapman, Nick Crafts, Yannick Dupraz, James Fenske, Tony Gill, John Hatcher, Helios Herrera, Larry Iannaccone, Taylor Jaworski, Erik Kimbrough, Ben Lockwood, Mario A. Maggioni, Eric Melander, Guido Merzoni, Martina Miotto, Joel Mokyr, Ola Ollson, John Palmer, Giacomo Ponzetto, Jared Rubin, Richard Smith, the participants of the CAGE AMES seminar (University of Warwick), 15th Conference of the Scottish Economic Society, 2019 IRES Graduate Workshop in Economics of Religion (Chapman University), VI Sowing the Seeds workshop (LSE), 2019 EPSA Conference, 2019 APSA Conference, 2020 ASREC24 conference, 2020 Economic History Society Conference, and 2021 Royal Economic Society Conference. We thank Costanza Marconi for her excellent research assistance. Any errors in the paper are entirely our own.

1 Monasteries of Celtic tradition are excluded from our main analysis and only included in the direct comparison with Benedictine, as they usually do not have two data points for their valuation.

2 We typically use “lord” and “landlord” interchangeably.

3 An extensive survey of productivity and land allocation during its reign was commissioned by William in 1086. More in the Historical Background section and Online Appendix G.

4 Most of these holdings are manors, id est the smallest administrative unit and the basic unit of inquest in the DDB (Finn Reference Finn1963), but there are also dependencies and non-manorial units. Online Appendix E provides a detailed description of how units of analysis are defined. They are identified in the DDB dataset as “Entries” through a unique Entries StructIdx code.

5 We are grateful to Sascha Becker for suggesting this comparison.

6 Interestingly, the DDB collected data for 1086 as well as for 1066, id est the last moment in time when King Edward was alive, precisely for this reason.

7 Richard Fitz Nigel (treasurer of Henry II), Dialogus de Scaccario, cited in Roffe (Reference Roffe2000, p. 5).

8 If anything, the Rule of St. Columbanus seemed to discourage discussion: “But if someone contradicts [the superior], he is guilty of insubordination, and therefore he is not only guilty of disobedience but is to be reckoned the destroyer of many because he opened the door of contradiction to others” (Ch. 1 of the rule, Kardong Reference Kardong2018).

9 The actual number of observations in the analysis depends on sparse missing data within each individual variable.

10 The DDB has been digitized by Palmer and colleagues, and a downloadable version is freely available at the Hydra repository of the University of Hull. Please see http://www.domesdaybook.net/ and https://hydra.hull.ac.uk/resources/hull:domesdayDisplaySet.

11 The similarities between the Norman and Anglo-Saxon feudal structures are debated. However, there may have been some continuity (Roffe 2007).

12 In our analysis, we use 31 and 43 monasteries as we had to restrict the sample to observations where the outcome variable is available for both 1066 and 1086.

13 In this case, when attributing the control variables, we usually take the average across the locations. See Online Appendix E for a detailed description.

14 “Other ecclesiastic” are all men. Only two nunneries would be relevant for our DID, accounting for eight observations. Excluding female secular landlords would only marginally change our coefficients (Online Appendix Table D13). The inclusion of Benedictine nunneries slightly reduces the magnitude of the “Benedictine” coefficient. P-values are below 0.1 in most of the specifications and 0.106 in the main one (Online Appendix Table D14).

15 The original dataset sometimes codes as “Value 1066” entries that are not precisely dated but refer to an “unspecified date before 1086.” In our analysis, we assign those observations to 1066. Adding a fixed effect for those ambiguous cases only marginally reduces the magnitude of the coefficients, as shown in Table C4.

16 The actual approximate growth rate is computed as Growth = log(V alue1086 + 1) − log(V alue1066 + 1).

17 Unlike them, we do not divide “values” by the number of non-slave workers, as this information is available for only one point in time.

18 We do not have information about the exact origin of all the 1066 and 1086 landlords. We assume that those in control before the Conquest were much more likely to be Anglo-Saxon, and those appearing after the Conquest were much more likely to be Normans.

19 It is important, however, to keep in mind that Palmer (2008) codes as “demesne” holdings where the lord coincides with the Tenant-in-Chief. We do not have information on further subdivisions within each estate.

20 A few Viking raids are known to have hit the northwestern part of England around 1070, but the potential detrimental effects of these events are already captured by the geographical control variables. Furthermore, we control explicitly for the area of land that ended up under direct Danish control in Anglo-Saxon times.

21 Either a male or female monastery, hence without excluding female Benedictine Overlords.

22 This sample almost overlaps with the “Stable OL/TC=1” sample in Table 3.

23 We control for this one, rather than for the full “Stable OL/TC” (which is 1 only if, on top of having the same Overlord and Tenant-in-Chief, the landlord in 1066 is different from the Overlord), because the latter would always be 0 for “Celtic” observations.

References

REFERENCES

Allen, Martyn, Nathan Blick, Tom Brindle, Tim Evans, Michael Fulford, Neil Holbrook, Lisa Lodwick, Richards, Julian D., and Smith, Alex. The Rural Settlement of Roman Britain: An Online Resource [data-set] . York: Archaeology Data Service, 2018. Available at https://doi.org/10.5284/1030449.Google Scholar
Andersen, Thomas B., Bentzen, Jeanet, Dalgaard, Carl-Johan, and Sharp, Paul. “Pre-Reformation Roots of the Protestant Ethic.” Economic Journal 127, no. 604 (2017): 1756–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angelucci, Charles, Meraglia, Simone, and Voigtländer, Nico. “The Medieval Roots of Inclusive Institutions: From the Norman Conquest of England to the Great Reform Act.” NBER Working Paper No. 23606, Cambridge, MA, July 2017.Google Scholar
Aston, Trevor H.The Origins of the Manor in England.” Transactions of the Royal Historical Society 8 (1958): 5983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayton, Andrew, and Davis, Virginia. “Ecclesiastical Wealth in England in 1086.” Studies in Church History 24 (1987): 4760.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barlow, Frank. The English Church 1066–1154. London, UK: Longman, 1979.Google Scholar
Barlow, Frank. The Feudal Kingdom of England: 1042–1216. Abingdon, Oxfordshire, UK: Routledge, 1999.Google Scholar
Beck, Jan, and Sieber, Andrea. “Is the Spatial Distribution of Mankind’s Most Basic Economic Traits Determined by Climate and Soil Alone?PloS one 5, no. 5 (2010): e10416.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Becker, Sascha O., Rubin, Jared, and Woessmann, Ludger. “Religion in Economic History: A Survey.” In The Handbook of Historical Economics, edited by Alberto, Bisin and Giovanni, Federico, 585639. London, UK: Academic Press, 2021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belloc, Marianna, Drago, Francesco, and Galbiati, Roberto. “Earthquakes, Religion, and Transition to Self-Government in Italian Cities.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 131, no. 4 (2016): 1875–926.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaydes, Lisa, and Paik, Christopher. “The Impact of Holy Land Crusades on State Formation: War Mobilization, Trade Integration, and Political Development in Medieval Europe.” International Organization 70, no. 3 (2016): 551–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burton, Janet. Monastic and Religious Orders in Britain, 1000–1300. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, Bruce M. S. “Arable Productivity in Medieval England: Some Evidence from Norfolk.” Journal of Economic History 43, no. 2 (1983): 379404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, Bruce M. S. English Seignioral Agriculture, 1250–1450. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Darby, Henry C. Domesday England. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1977.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D’Avray, David. “English Monastic Archive.” Revue Mabillon 27 (2015): 225–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delabastita, Vincent, and Maes, Sebastiaan. “The Feudal Origins of Manorial Prosperity: Social Interactions in Eleventh-Century England.” Journal of Economic History 83, no. 2 (2023): 464500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dell’Omo, Mariano. Storia del monachesimo occidentale dal medioevo all’et‘a contemporanea: il carisma di San Benedetto tra VI e XX secolo. Milano: Jaca Book, 2011.Google Scholar
Ditchburn, David, MacLean, Simon , and MacKay, Angus (eds.) Atlas of Medieval Europe, 2nd ed. London and New York: Routledge, 2007.Google Scholar
Doucette, Jonathan S., and Møller, Jørgen. “The Collapse of State Power, the Cluniac Reform Movement, and the Origins of Urban Self-Government in Medieval Europe.” International Organization 75, no. 1 (2021): 204–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dyer, Christopher. Making a Living in the Middle Ages. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2003.Google Scholar
Ehrmann, Thomas, Rost, Katja, and Inauen, Emil. “Location of Decision Rights in Catholic Religious Orders.” Managerial and Decision Economics 34 (2013): 2939.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B., Hébert, Robert F., Tollison, Robert D., Anderson, Gary M., and Davidson, Audrey B.. Sacred Trust: The Medieval Church as an Economic Firm. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1996.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finn, R. Welldon. An Introduction to Domesday Book. London, UK: Longman, 1963.Google Scholar
Fleming, Robin. “Monastic Lands and England’s Defence in the Viking Age.” English Historical Review 100, no. 395 (1985): 247–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleming, Robin. Kings and Lords in Conquest England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner, and Rubin, Jared. “Endogenous Political Legitimacy: The Tudor Roots of England’s Constitutional Governance” Journal of Economic History, forthcoming 2024.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. “Beyond War and Contracts: The Medieval and Religious Roots of the European State.” Annual Review of Political Science 23 (2020): 1936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamerow, Helena. Rural Settlements and Society in Anglo-Saxon England. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, 2012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heldring, Leander, Robinson, James A., and Vollmer, Sebastian. “The Long-Run Impact of the Dissolution of the English Monasteries.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 136, no. 4 (2021): 2093–145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollister, C. W.The Norman Conquest and the Genesis of English Feudalism.” American Historical Review 66, no. 3 (1961): 641–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IIASA/FAO. Global Agro-Ecological Zones (GAEZ v3.0), 2012.Google Scholar
Inauen, Emil, Katja Rost, Bruno S. Frey, Fabian Homberg, and Osterloh, Margit. “Monastic Governance: Forgotten Prospects for Public Institutions.” American Review of Public Administration 40, no. 6 (2010a): 631–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Inauen, Emil, Rost, Katja, Osterloh, Margit, and Frey, Bruno S.. “Back to the Future: A Monastic Perspective on Corporate Governance.” Management Revue (2010b): 3859.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iyer, Sriya. “The New Economics of Religion.” Journal of Economic Literature 54, no. 2 (2016): 395441.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kardong, Terrence G. Saint Columban: His Life, Rule, and Legacy . Collegeville, MN: Liturgical Press, 2018.Google Scholar
Knowles, David. The Monastic Order in England. A History of Its Development from the Times of St. Dunstan to the Fourth Lateran Council, 940–1216. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knowles, David, and Neville Hadcock, R.. Medieval Religious Houses England and Wales. London, UK: Longman, 1971.Google Scholar
Letters, S. “Gazetteer of Markets and Fairs in England and Wales to 1516.” British History Online, 2005. Available from http://www.british-history.ac.uk/list-index-soc/markets-fairs-gazetteer-to-1516.Google Scholar
Loyn, H. R. Anglo-Saxon England and the Norman Conquest. London, UK: Routledge, 2013.Google Scholar
McCormick, Michael, Guoping Huang, Kelly Gibson, et al. “The Digital Atlas of Roman and Medieval Civilizations (darmc).” Stanford, CA: SearchWorks catalog, Stanford Libraries, 2010.Google Scholar
McDonald, John. “Manorial Efficiency in Domesday England.” Journal of Productivity Analysis 8 (1997): 199213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonald, John, and Snooks, Graeme D.. Domesday Economy: A New Approach to Anglo-Norman History. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, 1986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonald, John, and Snooks, Graeme D.. “The Suitability of Domesday Book for Cliometric Analysis.” Economic History Review 40, no. 2 (1987): 252–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, Joel, Sarid, Assaf, and van der Beek, Karine. “The Wheels of Change: Technology Adoption, Millwrights and the Persistence in Britain’s Industrialisation.” Economic Journal 132, no. 645 (2022): 1894–926.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Thomas, Robert P.. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1973.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palmer, John. “The Domesday Manor.” In Domesday Studies, edited by Holt, J.C., 139–54. Woodbridge, Suffolk, UK: The Boydell Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Palmer, John. “Domesday Statistics Database.” Hull, UK: University of Hull, 2008.Google Scholar
Postan, Michael M. The Medieval Economy and Society: An Economic History of Britain, 1100–1500, volume 1. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1973.Google Scholar
Pratt, David. “Demesne Exemption from Royal Taxation in Anglo-Saxon and Anglo-Norman England.” English Historical Review 128, no. 530 (2013): 134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quartiroli, A. M. La regola di San Benedetto. Ed. Monastici, Scritti, 2002.Google Scholar
Richardson, Gary. “Craft Guilds and Christianity in Late-Medieval England: A Rational-Choice Analysis.” Rationality and Society 17, no. 2 (2005): 139–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roehl, Richard. “The Ecclesiastical Economy of Medieval Europe.” Journal of Economic History 46, no. 1 (1986): 227–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roffe, David. Domesday: The Inquest and the Book. New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roffe, David. Decoding Domesday. Woodbridge, UK: Boydell & Brewer Ltd, 2007.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rossignoli, Domenico, and Trombetta, Federico. “Ora et Guberna. The Economic Impact of the Rule of St Benedict in Medieval England.” Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2024-05-17. https://doi.org/10.3886/E203081V1 Google Scholar
Rost, Katja. “Introduction to the Corporate Governance of Religion.” In Emerging Trends in the Social and Behavioral Sciences: An Interdisciplinary, Searchable, and Linkable Resource, edited by Robert, A. Scott and Buchmann, Marlis, 1–10. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley Online, 2017.Google Scholar
Rost, Katja, and Graetzer, Gitte. “Multinational Organizations as Rule-Following Bureaucracies: The Example of Catholic Orders.” Journal of International Management 20, no. 3 (2014): 290311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rost, Katja, Inauen, Emil, Osterloh, Margit, and Frey, Bruno S.. “The Corporate Governance of Benedictine Abbeys.” Journal of Management History 16, no. 1 (2010): 90115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, Jared. Rulers, Religion, and Riches: Why the West Got Rich and the Middle East Did Not. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sant’Anna, Pedro H., and Jun, Zhao. “Doubly Robust Difference-in-Differences Estimators.Journal of Econometrics 219, no. 1 (2020): 101–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stasavage, David. The Decline and Rise of Democracy: A Global History from Antiquity to Today. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2020.Google Scholar
Talbert, Richard J. Barrington Atlas of the Greek and Roman World: Map-by-Map Directory, volume 1. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Thomas, Hugh M. The Norman Conquest: England after William the Conqueror. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield, 2008.Google Scholar
Wareham, Andrew. “The Feudal Revolution in Eleventh-Century East Anglia.” Anglo-Norman Studies 22 (2000): 293321.Google Scholar
Wareham, Andrew. “Fiscal Policies and the Institution of a Tax State in Anglo-Saxon England within a Comparative Context.” Economic History Review 65, no. 3 (2012): 910–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, Lynn. “Dynamo and Virgin Reconsidered.” American Scholar 27, no. 2 (1958): 183–94.Google Scholar
Wieland, Anders G. “The Long-Run Effects of Weak States: Evidence from the Viking Settlement of Eastern England.” Working Paper, 2022. Available at https://congress-files.s3.amazonaws.com/2022-07/The_Long_Run_Effects_of_Weak_States_Evidence_from_the_Viking_Settlement_of_Eastern_England.pdf.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 LORD TYPES IN ENGLAND BEFORE AND AFTER THE CONQUESTSources: See text and Online Appendix E.

Figure 1

Figure 2 CHANGE IN LORD TYPESNotes: Holdings with changing lords between 1066 and 1086 are depicted. Gray dots: secular to secular lords (likely Anglo-Saxon to Norman nobleman). Blue dots: secular to “Other ecclesiastic.” Maroon dots: secular to monastery. Black crosses: monasteries. Map excludes holdings with missing value and outliers.Sources: See text and Online Appendix E.

Figure 2

Table 1 SUMMARY STATISTICS (SUBSAMPLE) BY GROUPS

Figure 3

Table 2 HOLDING VALUE: DIFFERENT RELIGIOUS LEADERS RELIGIOUS VS. SECULAR LANDLORD

Figure 4

Table 3 HOLDING VALUE: BENEDICTINE VS. SECULAR LANDLORD, HETEROGENEITY ANALYSIS

Figure 5

Table 4 HOLDING VALUE: BENEDICTINE VS. SECULAR LANDLORD, ADDING BENEDICTINE OVERLORD DUMMY

Figure 6

Table 5 HOLDING VALUE: BENEDICTINE VS. ROYAL LANDLORD, STABLE OL/TC HOLDINGS SUBSAMPLE

Figure 7

Table 6 ALTERNATIVE OUTCOMES, BENEDICTINES VS. SECULAR LANDLORDS

Figure 8

Table 7 HOLDING VALUE: BENEDICTINES VS. CELTIC MONASTIC LANDLORDS

Supplementary material: File

Rossignoli and Trombetta supplementary material

Rossignoli and Trombetta supplementary material
Download Rossignoli and Trombetta supplementary material(File)
File 993 KB