Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T05:39:37.093Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The North American Fur Trade: Bargaining to a Joint Profit Maximum under Incomplete Information, 1804–1821

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Elizabeth Hoffman
Affiliation:
Assistant Professor of Economics, Huron College, London, Ontario N6G 1H3; Elizabeth Hoffman is Associate Professor of Economics, Purdue University and the University of Wyoming, Laramie, Wyoming 82071.

Abstract

We examine bargaining between the Northwest Company and the Hudson's Bay Company using recent models of bargaining under incomplete information. Two previously undisturbed bodies of correspondence are analyzed: letters between the two companies and letters between the Hudson's Bay Company and its London committee. Through merger the companies achieved a joint maximum, but the lengthy and costly bargaining process dissipated much of the potential gain through depletion of animal stocks. Achievement of a joint maximum was hindered by incomplete information, commitment to a strategy which led to bargaining breakdowns, delineation of each party's rights under law, and environmental changes.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1986

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 See, for example, Wallace, W. Stewart, Documents Relating to the Northwest Company (Toronto, 1934);Google ScholarInnis, H. A., The Fur Trade in Canada (Toronto, 1970);Google ScholarMorton, Arthur S., A History of the Canadian West to 1870–1871 (London, 1939);Google ScholarRich, E. E., History of the Hudson's Bay Company, 1670–1870, 2 vols. (London, 1959).Google Scholar

2 The few analytical works include the work of Carlos, Ann, The North American Fur Trade,1804–1821: A Study in the Life Cycle of a Duopoly (New York, 1986);Google ScholarThe Causes and Origins of the Canadian Fur Trade Rivalry, 1804–1821,” this JOURNAL, 41 (12. 1981), pp. 777–94;Google Scholar and The Birth and Death of Predatory Competition in the North American Fur Trade: 1810–1821,” Explorations in Economic History, 19 (07 1982), pp. 156–83.CrossRefGoogle ScholarAnother recent paper by Enders, Alice T. and Macleod, W. Bentley, “Competition and Collusion in the North-American Fur Trade: 1804–1821” (unpublished manuscript, Queens University, 1984) also looks at the fur trade from a bargaining perspective. However, their analysis differs from ours in two important respects. First, they do not use the primary source material. Second, they do not consider models of bargaining under incomplete information.Google Scholar

3 Myerson, Roger B., “Two-person Bargaining Problems with Incomplete Information,” Econometrica, 52 (03 1984), pp. 461–87;CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Cooperative Games with Incomplete Information,” International Journal of Game Theory, 13(1984), pp. 6996;Google ScholarCrawford, Vincent P., “A Theory of Disagreement in Bargaining,” Econometrica, 50 (05 1982), pp. 607–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

4 The Northwest Company trade in the interior was divided into districts known as departments Over each department there was a Wintering partner.Google Scholar

5 Lamb, W. K., ed., Journals and Letters of Sir Alexander MacKenzie. (Toronto, 1970).Google Scholar

6 Ibid., pp. 416–17.

7 Minutes of Transactions Between Hudson's Bay Company and the Northwest Company 1804–06, Public Archives of Canada [henceforth PAC] Hudson's Bay Company MG20AI reel 18, para. 6.Google Scholar

8 The Northwest Company had been formed by the merger of Alexander Mackenzie's company and the old Northwest Company. The rivalry leading up to this merger was particularly intense and bitter. The Hudson's Bay Company letters at this time speak of “Canadian traders who respect neither justice nor equity but commit open acts of violence….” Hudson's Bay Company Records, Minute Books, MG20AI/219 (PAC, p. 6).Google Scholar

9 Minutes of Transactions, letter of May 1805.Google Scholar

10 Ibid., Letter of 19 February 1806.

11 Ibid., letter of 31 January 1806.

12 Ibid., letter of 19 February 1806.

13 Ibid., letter of 22 February 1806.

14 This period is discussed at length in Carlos, “Causes and Origins.”Google Scholar

15 Hudson's Bay Company Records, London Correspondence Outward—Official—Albany 1800, PAC MG20A6.Google Scholar

16 Course, Elliot, ed., New Light on the Early History of the Greater Northwest: The Manuscript Journals of Alexander Henry and of David Thompson (New York, 1897).Google Scholar

17 Lord Selkirk conceived the idea of a colony at Red River from the description of the area provided by Sir Alexander Mackenzie in his book.Google Scholar

18 A full discussion of the effect of this fall in demand can be found in Carlos, “Causes and Origins.”Google Scholar

19 Coues, New Light, Alexander Henry noted in 1808 that the Blackfeet“brought in wolves, but I sent them to my neighbours [Hudson's Bay Company] as wolves were not in season,” i.e., not in demand, p. 558.Google Scholar

20 In a zero-sum game there are no benefits from cooperation. Anything one firm wins is at the expense of the other firm.Google Scholar

21 Papers Relating to the Red River Settlement, Selkirk Papers, PAC MG19, pp. 1–3000, letter of 3 June 1811.Google Scholar

24 Ibid., letter of 26 June 1811.

26 Ibid., letter of 24 July 1811.

27 Ibid., letter of 6 August 1811.

29 See Carlos, “Birth and Death,” for a discussion of the animal stock depletion.Google Scholar

30 Ray, Arthur, Indians in the Fur Trade (Toronto, 1974), p. 121. The muskrat was affected by changes in the level of precipitation. Any significant increases or decreases in the water levels in rivers decimated the population.Google Scholar

31 London Correspondence Outward, para. 38, 1814.Google Scholar

32 Wallace, Documents, p. 273.Google Scholar

33 Selkirk Papers, August 1815 instructions to Lord Selkirk, p. 1631 n.Google Scholar

36 In spite of the fact that the Hudson's Bay Company was negotiating with the Northwest Company to leave Athabasca under Northwest Company control, the Hudson's Bay Company had already sent an outfit to Athabasca.Google Scholar

37 Selkirk Papers, August 1815 instructions to Lord Selkirk.Google Scholar

38 Ibid., negotiations of 10 December 1815, p. 217n. The actual details of the Northwest Company counterproposal were put forward on 12 December.

39 Ibid., negotiations of 12 December.

43 Ibid., negotiations of 23 December (p. 244).

44 At this point the threats and counterthreats became directly physical. The use of such tactics as bully boys, trading each others' debts, and the kidnapping business is discussed at length in Carlos, “Birth and Death.”Google Scholar

45 London Correspondence Outward, 1817.Google Scholar

46 Rich, E. E., ed., Journal of Occurrence in the Athabasca Department by George Simpson, 1820 and 1821 Report (Toronto, 1938) states that the Hudson's Bay Company trading loss had been 12,000 pounds sterling over a long period (p. 394).Google Scholar

47 The Northwest Company position was severely weakened by the capture of Fort William in 1817 by Lord Selkirk. The Company lost two years' trade, furs in 1817 and trade goods in 1818.Google Scholar

48 Rich, Journal, p. 356.Google Scholar

49 Ibid., p. 361.

50 Selkirk Papers, p. 6960.Google Scholar

51 Agreement for carrying on the fur trade by the Hudson's Bay Company exclusively under the terms within mentioned and Deed Poll, 26 March 1821. See Wallace, Documents, p. 321.Google Scholar

52 The actual personnel on the Hudson's Bay Company committee had also changed. By 1810 the composition of the committee was quite different from what it had been in 1804.Google Scholar

53 There is already some other work in economic history which uses bargaining theory. We have already mentioned Enders and Macleod, “Competition and Collusion.” There is also the work of Liebcap, Gary D. and Wiggins, Steven N., “The Influence of Private Contractual Failure on Regulation: The Case of Oil Field Unitization,” Journal of Political Economy, 93 (08 1985), pp. 690714;CrossRefGoogle ScholarJohnson, Ronald N. and Libecap, Gary D., “Contracting Problems and Regulation: The Case of the Fishery,” American Economic Review, 72 (12 1982), pp. 1005–22;Google Scholar and Wiggins, Steven N. and Libecap, Gary D., “Oil Field Unitization: Contractual Failure in the Presence of Imperfect Information,” American Economic Review, 75 (06 1985) pp. 368–85.Google Scholar