Hostname: page-component-7bb8b95d7b-s9k8s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-09-07T13:47:36.888Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Authority and Efficiency: The Labor Market and the Managerial Revolution of the Late Nineteenth Century

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Abstract

The managerial revolution resulted in the concentration of production decisions in the hands of management. Radical economists and historians have disputed the conventional view that these changes in work organization were necessary to increase production efficiency. Yet curiously there seem to be few issues of fact in dispute between the radical and the conventional accounts. I offer here an interpretation of the radical position which explains why this is so, and why profitable and efficient organizations of work will differ in capitalist economies. The argument hinges on the conditions under which workers were able to act collectively.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1984

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 See David Montgomery, Workers' Control in America (Cambridge, 1976), pp. 11–15.

2 Ibid., pp. 11–12.

3 These works include Stone, Katherine, “The Origin of Job Structures in the Steel Industry,” Review of Radical Political Economics (Summer 1974);Google Scholar and Lazonick, William, “Production Relations, Labor Productivity and the Choice of Technique: British and U.S. Cotton Spinning,” this JOURNAL, 41 (09 1981), “Technological Change and the Control of Work,” Harvard Institute of Economic Research, Discussion Paper No. 821 (April 1981), and “Production Productivity and Development: Theoretical Implications of Some Historical Research,” Harvard Institute of Economic Research, Discussion Paper No. 876 (Jan. 1982).Google Scholar

4 Williamson, Oliver, “The Organization of Work,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 1 (03 1980), p. 32.Google Scholar

5 Marx, Karl, Capital, Volume I (New York, 1967), p. 636.Google Scholar

6 Davis, Lance et al. , American Economic Growth (New York, 1972), p. 225.Google Scholar

7 Ibid., p. 224.

8 Edwards, Richard, Contested Terrain (New York, 1979), p. 3.Google Scholar

9 Toharia, Luis, “The Division of Labor and the Historical Development of the Internal Labor Market: A Case Study of the McCormick Works of Chicago, 1848–1902” (Ph.D. diss., MIT, 1979), p. 24.Google Scholar

10 I assume throughout that employers do not combine to depress wages. Most modern studies find monopsony to be unimportant as a feature of labor markets. See for example Bunting, R., Employer Concentration in Local Labor Markers (Chapel Hill, NC., 1962);Google ScholarLandon, J. and Baird, R., “Monopsony in the Market for Public School Teachers,” American Economic Review, 61 (12 1971).Google Scholar

11 Nelson, Daniel, Managers and Workers: Origins of the New Factory System in the United States, 1880–1920 (Madison, 1975), p. 57.Google Scholar

12 See Lazonick, “Technological Change and the Control of Work.”Google Scholar

13 See Freeman, Richard and Medoff, James, “The Two Faces of Unionism,” The Public Interest 57 (1979), as an example.Google Scholar

14 Montgomery, David and Schatz, Ronald, “Facing Layoffs,” in Montgomery, Workers' Control in America, p. 139.Google Scholar

15 Matthewson, Stanley B., Restriction of Output Among Unorganized Workers (New York, 1931), p. 61.Google Scholar

16 Ibid., pp. 61–62.

17 Ibid., p. 135.

18 Scitovsky, Tibor, The Joyless Economy (Oxford, 1976), p. 95.Google Scholar

19 As Mancur Olson shows, the conditions for rational agents being able to achieve a collective benefit are quite strict. See Olson, Mancur, The Logic of Collective Action (Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1965).Google Scholar

20 Chandler, Alfred, The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business (Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1977), p. 123.Google Scholar

21 Chandler, The Visible Hand, p. 317.Google Scholar

22 See Leibenstein, Harvey, “Allocative vs. X-Efficiency,” American Econotnic Review, 56 (06 1966), p. 393.Google Scholar

23 Eleventh Special Report of the Commissioner of Labor, Regulation and Restriction of Output (Washington, D.C., 1904).Google Scholar

24 Lewis, L. E., “Extent of Incentive Pay in Manufacturing,” Monthly Labor Review, 83 (05 1960), pp. 460–63.Google Scholar

25 See Britain, Great, National Board for Prices and Incomes, Report No. 65, Payment by Results Systems (London, 1968).Google Scholar

26 Chandler, The Visible Hand, p. 142.Google Scholar

28 Josephson, Matthew, The Robber Barons (New York, 1934), p. 288.Google Scholar

29 Chandler, The Visible Hand, p. 334.Google Scholar

30 See Mitchell, Broadus, The Rise of the Cotton Mills in the South (Baltimore, 1921).Google Scholar

31 Heim, Carol, “Structural Transformation and the Demand for New Labor in Advanced Economies: Interwar Britain,” this JOURNAL, 44 (06 1984), points out this phenomenon in Britain in the 1930s. It is also true in recent years. Researchers at the National Institute for Economic and Social Research, investigating recruiting of labor by a large multinational in Britain, found that the firm hired only workers with no previous industrial experience for production-line tasks.Google Scholar

32 Peter Temin suggests that the early nineteenth-century American economy possessed much greater price flexibility. See Temin, General Equilibrium Models in Economic History,” this JOURNAL, 31 (03 1971), 5876,Google Scholar and The Jacksonian Economy (New York, 1969). In his famous Economica article Phillips argues that the relationship between wage changes and unemployment in Great Britain is stable from 1861 to 1957. This author's examination of the data underlying Phillips's demonstration finds instead greater wage inflexibility in the twentieth century in Britain. See “The Phillips' Curve Revisited” (mimeo).Google Scholar

33 Williamson, “The Organization of Work,” p. 33.Google Scholar

34 For a history of the British cooperative movement, see Boggis, Fred, “Workers's Cooperatives: A Vital Experiment,” in Participation in Industry, ed. Balfour, Campbell (Totowa, New Jersey, 1973).Google Scholar

35 Bowles, Samuel and Gintis, Herbert, Schooling in Capitalist America (New York, 1976), p. 62.Google Scholar

36 See Marglin, Stephen A., “Knowledge and Power,” Harvard Institute of Economic Research, Discussion Paper 901 (1982), for the complete argument.Google Scholar

37 Boggis, “Workers' Cooperatives,” pp. 35–38.Google Scholar

38 Potter, Beatrice, The Co-operative Movement in Great Britain (London, 1891), p. 153.Google Scholar

39 Jones, Benjamin, Co-operative Production (Oxford, 1894), p. 780;Google Scholar and Boggis, “Workers' Cooperatives,” pp. 35–38.Google Scholar

40 Jones, Co-operative Production, p. 780.Google Scholar

41 Oakeshott, Robert, The Case for Workers' Co-ops (London, 1978), p. 64.Google Scholar

43 Potter, The Co-operative Movement, p. 123.Google Scholar

44 Jones, Co-operative Production, p. 288.Google Scholar

46 Potter, The Co-operative Movement, p. 215.Google Scholar

47 Oakeshott, The Case for Workers' Co-ops, pp. 132–34.Google Scholar

48 New York Times, Apr. 4, 1984.Google Scholar

49 See Williamson, Oliver E., Markets and Hierarchies (New York, 1975), for the most complete presentation of this approach.Google Scholar

50 Williamson, Oliver E., “The Modern Corporation as an Efficiency Instrument,” in Government Controls and the Free Market, ed. Pejovich, S. (College Station, Texas, 1975), p. 172.Google Scholar

51 Report of the Commissioner of Labor, p. 18.Google Scholar

52 See for example Davison, J. P., Florence, P. S., Gray, B., and Ross, N., Productivity and Economic Incentives (London, 1958).Google Scholar

53 Orcutt, H. F. L. et al. , “Machine Shop Management in Europe and America, Part III,Engineering Magazine (03 1898), p. 927.Google Scholar

55 Maxim, Hiram, “The Effects of Trade Unionism upon Skilled Mechanics,” Engineering Magazine (Nov. 1897).Google Scholar

56 Maxim, Hiram, “National Differences in Labor-Handling Methods,” Engineering Magazine (Dec. 1897), p. 370.Google Scholar

57 Robertson, A. J., “The Decline of the Scottish Cotton Industry, 1860–1914,” Business History, 12 (07 1970), p. 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

58 The lack of social distinctions between managers and employers may explain why cooperatives of professionals can be very successful. The London Symphony Orchestra has been a successful workers' cooperative since 1904. The members elect the conductor and the directors, and participate in a production process which is complex and requires a high degree of cooperation between participants. The possibilities for opportunistic behavior and for collective restrictions by workers are as great as in any enterprise.Google Scholar