Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T02:25:42.021Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Razorbacks, Ticky Cows, and the Closing of the Georgia Open Range: The Dynamics of Institutional Change Uncovered

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Shawn Everett Kantor
Affiliation:
Assistant Proffesor of Economics, Univeresity of Arizona, Tucson, AZ 85721.

Extract

This article attempts to explain why the adoption of potentially productive institutions is delayed and why inefficient ones persist by exploring the dynamics of institutional change in a particular historical case—the closing of the Georgia open range in the late nineteenth century. A closed range policy would have generated net benefits for specific regions of Georgia, but distributional conflicts, coupled with high transaction costs, made a voluntary agreement to do that unattainable. The article describes the Georgia legislature's important role in facilitating the adoption of a policy that led to more rapid agricultural development in the postbellum period.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1991

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Arrow, Kenneth J., “The Property Rights Doctrine and Demand Revelation Under Incomplete Information,” in Boskin, Michael J., ed., Economics and Welfare: Essays in Honor of Tibor Scitovsky (New York, 1979).Google Scholar
Atlanta and West-Point Railroad Company, “Reports of the President and Superintendent of the Atlanta and West-Point Railroad Company, to the Stockholders in Convention” (1880 and 1884).Google Scholar
Binger, Brian R., and Hoffman, Elizabeth, “Institutional Persistence and Change: The Question of Efficiency,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 145 (03 1989), pp. 6784.Google Scholar
Bonner, James C., Georgia's Last Frontier: The Development of Carroll County (Athens, GA, 1971).Google Scholar
Carroll County Times (Georgia, various issues).Google Scholar
Carroll Free Press (Georgia, various issues).Google Scholar
The Central Railroad v. Hamilton, 71 Georgia461 (1883).Google Scholar
The Central Railroad v. Summerford, 87 Georgia626 (1891).Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald, “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics, 3 (10 1990), pp. 144.Google Scholar
Crawford, Vincent C., “A Theory of Disagreement in Bargaining,” Econometrica, 50 (05 1982), pp. 607–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cronon, William, Changes in the Land: Indians, Colonists, and the Ecology of New England (New York, 1983).Google Scholar
Davis, Lance E., and North, Douglass C., Institutional Change and American Economic Growth (Cambridge, 1971).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeCanio, Stephen J., Agriculture in the Postbellum South: The Economics of Production and Supply (Cambridge, MA, 1974).Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold, “Some Aspects of Property Rights,” Journal of Law and Economics, 9 (10 1966), pp. 6170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, Harold, “Toward a Theory of Property Rights,” American Economic Review, 57 (05 1967), pp. 347–59.Google Scholar
Dover v. The State of Georgia, 80 Georgia781 (1888).Google Scholar
Ellickson, Robert C., “Of Coase and Cattle: Dispute Resolution Among Neighbors in Shasta County,” Stanford Law Review, 38 (02 1986), pp. 623–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, Joseph, “Information and the Coase Theorem,” Economic Perspectives, 1 (Fall 1987), pp. 113–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flynn, Charles L. Jr., White Land, Black Labor: Caste and Class in Late Nineteenth-Century Georgia (Baton Rouge, 1983).Google Scholar
Georgia, , Session Laws (Atlanta, various years).Google Scholar
Georgia Department of Agriculture, Annual Report of Thomas P. Janes, Commissioner of Agriculture of the State of Georgia for the Year 1875 (Atlanta, 1876).Google Scholar
Georgia Department of Agriculture, Publications of the Georgia State Department of Agriculture from September, 1874 to January, 1878 (Atlanta, 1878).Google Scholar
Georgia Department of Agriculture, Report of the Commissioner of Agriculture of the State of Georgia, Embracing the Years 1881 and 1882 (Atlanta, 1882).Google Scholar
Georgia General Assembly, “Report of the Georgia State Agricultural Society to Establish More Experimental Farms in the State: 1884–1885,” Record Group 37, Subgroup 8, Series 4, Box I. Georgia Dept. of Archives and History, Atlanta.Google Scholar
Georgia Railroad and Banking Company, “Reports of the Directors, &c. of the Georgia Railroad and Banking Company to the Stockholders in Convention” (1877).Google Scholar
The Georgia Railroad Company and Banking Company v. Neely, 56 Georgia 540 (1876).Google Scholar
The Georgia Railroad Company and Banking Company v. Walker, 87 Georgia 204 (1891).Google Scholar
Georgia Supreme Court, “Case File of George H. Tumlin v. Charles C. Parrott,” A–15581, Box 246, Location No. 247–01, Georgia Dept. of Archives and History, Atlanta.Google Scholar
Greeley, Horace, What I Know of Farming: A Series of Brief and Plain Expositions of Practical Agriculture as an Art Based Upon Science (New York, 1871).Google Scholar
Hahn, Steven, The Roots of Southern Populism: Yeoman Farmers and the Transformation of the Georgia Upcountry, 1850–1890 (New York, 1983).Google Scholar
Higgs, Robert, Competition and Coercion: Blacks in the American Economy, 1865–1914 (New York, 1977).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Philip T., “Institutions and Agriculture in Old-Regime France,” Journal of institutional and Theoretical Economics, 145 (03 1989), pp 166–81.Google Scholar
Holleman v. Kingery, 81 Georgia624 (1888).Google Scholar
Jackson Herald (Georgia, various issues).Google Scholar
Jefferson Forest News (Georgia, various issues).Google Scholar
Jones v. Sligh, 75 Georgia7 (1885).Google Scholar
Kantor, Shawn E., and Kousser, J. Morgan, “Common Sense or Commonwealth? The Fence Law and Institutional Change in the Postbellum South” (Social Science Working Paper 703, California Institute of Technology, July 1989, revised October 1991).Google Scholar
Kantor, Shawn Everett, “Property Rights and the Dynamics of Institutional Change: The Closing of the Georgia Open Range, 1870–1900” (Ph.D. diss., California Institute of Technology, 06 1990).Google Scholar
King, J. Crawford Jr., “The Closing of the Southern Range: An Exploratory Study,” Journal of Southern History, 48 (02 1982), pp. 5370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Libecap, Gary D., “Distributional Issues in Contracting for Property Rights,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 145 (03 1989), pp. 631.Google Scholar
Libecap, Gary D., and Wiggins, Steven N., “The Influence of Private Contractual Failure on Regulation: The Case of Oil Field Unitization,” Journal of Political Economy, 93 (08 1985), pp. 690714.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, Donald N., “The Economics of Enclosure: A Market Analysis,” in Parker, William N. and Jones, Eric L., eds., European Peasants and Their Markets (Princeton, 1975).Google Scholar
Maddala, G. S., Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics (New York, 1983).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mailath, George J., and Postlewaite, Andrew, “Asymmetric Information Bargaining Problems with Many Agents,” Review of Economic Studies, 57 (07 1990), pp. 351–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Newnan Herald (Georgia, various issues).Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., Structure and Change in Economic History (New York, 1981).Google Scholar
A. D. O'Rear Collection, Drawer 171, Roll 46, Georgia Dept. of Archives and History, Atlanta.Google Scholar
Ransom, Roger L., and Sutch, Richard, One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation (New York, 1977).Google Scholar
Reid, Joseph D., “Sharecropping as an Understandable Market Response: The Postbellum South,” this Journal, 33 (03 1973), pp. 106–30.Google Scholar
Robb, Raphael, “Pollution Claim Settlements Under Private Information,” Journal of Economic Theory, 47 (04 1989), pp. 307–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent, “The Development of Irrigation in Provence, 1700–1860: The French Revolution and Economic Growth,” this Journal, 50 (09 1990), pp. 615–38.Google Scholar
Samuelson, William J., “A Comment on the Coase Theorem,” in Roth, Alvin E., ed., Game-Theoretic Models of Bargaining (Cambridge, 1985), pp. 321–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
South-Western Railroad Company, “Report of the Chief Engineers, President and Superintendents of the South-Western Railroad Company, of Georgia” (1861, 1866, and 1869).Google Scholar
Tharpe v. Hardison, 69 Georgia 280 (1882).Google Scholar
Southern Cultivator (various issues).Google Scholar
Tumlin v. Parrott, 82 Georgia 732 (1889).Google Scholar
U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1957 (Washington, DC, 1960).Google Scholar
U.S. Census Office, Tenth Census, 1880, Compendium of the Tenth Census (Washington, DC, 1883).Google Scholar
U.S. Census Office, Tenth Census, 1880, Report of the Productions of Agriculture (Washington, DC, 1883).Google Scholar
Virts, Nancy, “Estimating the Importance of the Plantation System to Southern Agriculture in 1880,” this Journal, 47 (12 1987), pp. 984–88.Google Scholar
Washburn and Moen Manufacturing Co., The Fence Question in the Southern States as Related to General Husbandry and Sheep Raising, with the History of Fence Customs, and Laws Pertaining Thereto: And a View of the New Farm System of the South, as Shown in the Census of 1880 (Worcester, MA, 1881).Google Scholar
Weiman, David F., “The Economic Emancipation of the Non-Slaveholding Class: Upcountry Farmers in the Georgia Cotton Economy,” this Journal, 45 (03 1985), pp. 7193.Google Scholar
Winters v. Jacobs, 29 Georgia 115 (1859).Google Scholar