Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T22:49:44.505Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Moral Conditions of Economic Growth*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 February 2011

Karl F. Helleiner
Affiliation:
The University of Toronto

Extract

Historians in general are rather suspicious of theories—and who is to blame them? The temptation to do violence to historical reality is strong, and must be resisted with might and main. However, bad company will sooner or later corrupt even the best of manners; and the economic historian, owing to his long and intimate association with that bold and reckless crowd, the theorists, has finally learned to overcome his scruples and inhibitions. Like the children of Israel, he goes a whoring after Baalim: he tries to develop a general theory of economic growth.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1951

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Stigler, George J., The Theory of Price (New York: The Macmillan Co., 1946), p. 12Google Scholar.

2 Boulding, Kenneth E., “Equilibrium and Wealth: A Word of Encouragement to Economists,” Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, V (1939), 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 Myint, Hla, Theories of Welfare Economics (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1948)Google Scholar, esp. chaps, i and iv.

4 See, for instance, Simon Kuznets, “Measurement of Economic Growth,” The Tasks of Economic History (Supplemental Issue of The Journal of Economic History), VII (1947), 10 ff., and Spengler, Joseph J., “Theories of Socio-Economic Growth,” Problems in the Study of Economic Growth (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1949), pp. 47 ff.Google Scholar

5 Smith, Adam, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, ed. Cannan, Edwin (Modern Library; New York: Random House), p. lviiGoogle Scholar.

6 Dingle, Herbert, Science and Human Experience (London: Williams & Norgate Ltd., 1931), p. 66Google Scholar.

7 See Schweitzer, Albert, Indian Thought and Its Development, trans. Mrs. Russell, Charles E. B. (2d ed.; London: Hodder & Stoughton Ltd., 1936Google Scholar).

8 In the case of the Stoics, however, this fundamental attitude of serene indifference and detachment did not lead to complete withdrawal from worldly activities. The Stoic, while setting no store by personal achievements in the field of politics or in economic pursuits, nevertheless accepted active participation in social life as a duty. Since the Stoic was expected to fulfill his social obligations—though without enthusiasm—his asceticism did not, perhaps, seriously impair his energy in matters economic or political. Indeed, some of the most active and successful administrators of imperial Rome were disciples of the Stoa.

It was different, however, with the Epicureans. Unlike the followers of Zeno, those of Epicurus did advocate withdrawal. “The life they envisaged as ideal was that of a club, a group of congenial friends like the one in the midst of which their Master lived in the Garden in Athens, unmolested because of its obscurity and inactivity.”—W. S. Ferguson, “The Leading Ideas of the New Period,” The Cambridge Ancient History, VII, 37.

9 The statement of a Christian writer of the second half of the fourth century, Tyrannius Rufinus, that in Egypt the number of monks was nearly equal to the remainder of the people (Gibbon, Edward, The Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire [Modern Library; New York: Random House], II, 4, n. 15Google Scholar) was-undoubtedly a gross exaggeration. But we may give some credence to other contemporary authors (quoted by Gibbon), all of whom testify to the multitude of anchorites and monasteries in various regions of the Hellenistic world.

10 St. Augustine, De opere monachorum, chap. 22, quoted by Gibbon, II, 7, n. 30.

11 To many of these people the attractions of monastic life may not have been purely spiritual. The economic and social security of the cloister must often have appeared preferable to the hardships and dangers of worldly life. To oppressed tenant farmers and poor mechanics the ascetic discipline to which they had to submit may have seemed sweet and lenient, compared with the toil and misery of their previous existence.

12 See, for instance, Weber, Max, The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (London: G. Allen & Unwin Ltd., 1930Google Scholar), and Tawney, R. H., Religion and the Rise of Capitalism (Harmondsworth, England: Pelican Books, 1938Google Scholar).

13 Introduction to Contemporary Civilization: A Source Book. (New York: Columbia University Press, 1946), I, 139 f.Google Scholar

14 Thomas Robert Malthus, Principles of Political Economy (2d. ed.; London School of Economics Reprints), p. 321.

15 Adam Smith, p. 329.

16 See Duesenberry, James S., “Some Aspects of the Theory of Economic Development,” Explorations in Entrepreneurial History, III (1950), 72Google Scholar.

17 Langer, Susanne K., Philosophy in a New Key (New York: Penguin Books, 1948), p. 36Google Scholar.

18 See Heichelheim, Fritz, Wirtschaftsgeschichte des Altertums (Leiden: A. W. Sijthoff, 1938), I, 38 ff. and 45 ff.Google Scholar

19 Langer, Philosophy in a New Key, p. 129.

20 On this point see Weber, Max, Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie (Tübingen: Mohr, 1921), III, 233 ff.Google Scholar

21 See Brunner, Otto, Adeliges Landleben und europäischer Geist. Leben und Werk Wolf Helmhards von Hohberg, 1612–1688 (Salzburg: O. Müller, 1949, pp. 72 f.Google Scholar

22 Enlightened opinion on the subject was summarized by Daniel Defoe in the preface to his A System of Magick or a History of the Black Art (London, 1727) in these words: “I see no great Harm in our present Pretenders to Magick, if the poor People could but keep their Money in their Pockets; and that they should have their Pockets pickʼd by such an unperforming, unmeaning, ignorant Crew as these are, is the only Magick that I can find in the whole Science.”

23 This badly neglected “plutological” aspect of war has been made the subject of a highly stimulating study by Lane, Frederic C., “The Economic Meaning of War and Protection,” Journal of Social Philosophy and Jurisprudence, VII (1942), 254 ff.Google Scholar

24 The Odyssey of Homer, trans. Butcher, S. H. and Lang, A. (New York: The Macmillan Co., 1906Google Scholar), Book IX, lines 252 ff., p. 142: “Strangers, who are ye? Whence sail ye over the wet ways? On some trading enterprise or at adventure do ye rove, even as sea-robbers over the brine, for at hazard of their own lives they wander, bringing bale to alien men.” The same question in identical words has been asked previously (Book III, lines 70 ff., p. 33) of Athena and Telemachos by Nestor. See also the comments by Thucydides in his History of the Peloponnesian War, trans. Richard Crawley (Everyman's Library; New York: E. P. Dutton & Co.), Book I, chap. 1.5: “… the question we find the old poets everywhere representing the people as asking of voyagers—‘Are they pirates?’—as if those who are asked the question would have no idea of disclaiming the imputation, or their interrogators of reproaching them for it.”

25 See Brunner, Otto, Land und Herrschaft (3d ed.; Brno, Munich, Vienna: R. M. Rohrer, 1943)Google Scholar.

26 In recent times, however, an increasingly broad interpretation of labor's right to “peaceful” picketing threatens to introduce an element of neofeudalism—nor can it be said to be the only one—into modern society.

27 von Wieser, Friedrich, Das Gesetz der Macht (Vienna: J. Springer, 1926), pp. 254 ffGoogle Scholar.

28 See Easterbrook, W. T., “The Climate of Enterprise,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, XXXIX (1949), 322 ff.Google Scholar

29 See Nelson, Benjamin N., “The Usurer and the Merchant Prince: Italian Businessmen and the Ecclesiastical Law of Restitution,” The Tasks of Economic History (Supplemental Issue of The Journal of Economic History), VII (1947), 104 ff.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

30 See de Roover, Raymond, Money, Banking and Credit in Mediaeval Bruges (Cambridge: The Mediaeval Academy of America, 1948), pp. 54 and 305 ff.Google Scholar

31 The “Summa Theologica” of St. Thomas Aquinas, literally translated by fathers of the English Dominican province, Part II2 (London: Burns Oates & Washbourne Ltd., 1918), p. 321Google Scholar (quaestio LXXVII, art. 2).

32 Erasmus, Desiderius, The Praise of Folly, trans. Hudson, Hoyt Hopewell (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1941), p. 69.Google Scholar

33 Defoe, Daniel, An Essay upon Projects (London, 1702), reprinted in The Works of Daniel Defoe, ed. Hazlitt, William (London, 1843), III. 11.Google Scholar