Article contents
The Cotton Harvester in Retrospect: Labor Displacement or Replacement?
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 03 March 2009
Abstract
The prevailing view of new mechanical technology is that it has, in large part, pushed labor out of agriculture. An alternative hypothesis is that labor has been pulled out of agriculture by higher wages in nonfarm occupations. The mechanical cotton harvester is used to test the two hypotheses. Estimation of a simultaneous-equation model of the labor market for cotton pickers reveals 79 percent of reduction in hand picking of cotton was due to increased nonfarm wages—the pull effect; the remaining 21 percent is attributed to the decreased cost of machine harvesting—the push effect.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © The Economic History Association 1986
References
1 Holt, James S., “Labor Market Policies and Institutions in an Industrializing Agriculture” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 64 (12. 1982), pp. 999–1006. Quote from p. 999 (emphasis added).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
2 Day, Richard H., “The Economics of Technological Change and the Demise of the Sharecropper,” American Economic Review, 57 (06 1967), pp. 427–49.Google Scholar
3 Other studies in which agricultural labor is implicitly or explicitly assumed to be in large part displaced by machines include: Barnett, Paul et al. , “Labor's Dwindling Harvest,” California Institute for Rural Studies, University of California, (Davis, 1978);Google ScholarMarshall, Ray, Rural Workers in Rural Labor Markets, (Salt Lake City, 1974);Google ScholarPadfield, Harland and Martin, William E., Farmers, Workers and Machines, (Tucson, 1965);Google ScholarSchmitz, Andrew and Seckler, David, “Mechanized Agriculture and Social Welfare: The Case of the Tomato Harvester,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 52 (11 1970), pp. 569–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
4 Binswanger, Hans P., “Measured Biases of Technical Change: The United States,” in Induced Innnovation, Technology, Institutions and Development, Binswanger, Hans P., Ruttan, Vernon W. et al. , eds. (Baltimore, 1978).Google Scholar
5 Kislev, Yoav and Peterson, Willis, “Induced Innovations and Farm Mechanization,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 63 (08 1981), pp. 562–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
6 Day, “The Economics of Technological Change…”, p. 441.Google Scholar
7 USDA, Economic Research Service, Statistical Bulletin No. 535, “Statistics on Cotton and Related Data, 1920–1973” (Washington, D.C., 1974), p. 218.Google Scholar
8 Prices paid by farmers to owners of mechanical cotton harvesters for harvesting services.Google Scholar
9 Watkins, J. L., King Cotton: A Historical and Statistical Review, 1790–1908 (New York, 1908).Google Scholar
10 For a more detailed description of the early development of the mechanical cotton harvester and of the various types of mechines see Smith, H. P. et al. ,, The Mechanical Harvesting of Cotton, Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Bulletin 452 (College Station, 1932);Google ScholarStreet, James H., The New Revolution in the Cotton Economy (Chapel Hill, 1957);Google ScholarFite, Gilbert C., “Recent Progress in the Mechanization of Cotton Production in the United States,” Agricultural History, 24 (01 1950), pp. 190–207. The following discussion on the development of the mechanical cotton harvester draws heavily on Smith and Street.Google Scholar
11 The use of custom rates as a measure of the cost of machine harvesting is discussed in Section IV.Google Scholar
12 According to the published data, the United States achieved a 100 percent mechanical harvest before the state of Mississippi. No doubt this is due to rounding. Mississippi was one of the last states to be 100 percent mechanized in the harvest of cotton.Google Scholar
13 Musoke, Moses S. and Olmstead, Alan L., “The Rise of the Cotton Industry in California: A Comparative Perspective,” this Journal, 42 (06 1982), pp. 385–412;Google ScholarMaier, Frank H., “An Economic Analysis of Adoption of the Mechanical Cotton Picker,” (Ph.D. diss., University of Chicago, 1969).Google Scholar
14 Pedersen, Harald A. and Rapier, Arthur F., “The Cotton Plantation in Transition,” Mississippi State College Agricultural Experiment Station Bulletin 508 (Jan 1954), pp. 3–4.Google Scholar
15 Street, James H., “The ‘Labor Vacuum’ and Cotton Mechanization,” Journal of Farm Economics, 35 (08 1953), pp. 381–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
16 Reynoldson, L. A., et al., “The Combined Harvest-Thresher in the Great Plains,” USDA Technical Bulletin No. 70 (Feb. 1928), p. 35; H. J. Friesen, et al., “1952–53 Custom Rates for Farm Operations in Central Kansas,” Kansas Agricultural Economic Report No. 59 (1953), p. 14.Google Scholar
17 The 12 states are Alabama, Arizona, Arkansas, California, Georgia, Louisiana, Mississippi, Missouri, New Mexico, North Carolina, South Carolina, and Tennessee. Texas and Oklahoma were omitted because of the prevalence of strippers in these states.Google Scholar
18 Street, James H., “Cotton Mechanization and Economic Development,” American Economic Review, 45 (09 1955), pp. 566–83.Google Scholar
19 Hagen, C. R., “Twenty-Five Years of Cotton Picker Development,” Agricultural Engineering 32 (11 1951), pp. 593–99.Google Scholar
20 Fair, Ray C., “The Estimation of Simultaneous Equation Models With Lagged Endogenous Variables and First Order Serially Correlated Errors,” Econometrica, 38 (05 1970), pp. 507–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
21 Kislev, Yoav and Peterson, Willis, “Prices, Technology, and Farm Size,” Journal of Political Economy, 90 (11 1982), pp. 578–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 14
- Cited by