Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-16T12:15:54.190Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

EMBEDDED AND AUTONOMOUS MARKETS IN NORTH KOREA'S FISHING INDUSTRY: RESOURCE SCARCITY, MONITORING COSTS, AND EVOLVING INSTITUTIONS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 May 2021

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

North Korea today is a most unusual post-socialist state. Market actors and market prices are integral to economic life, but private property remains illegal, and private enterprise outside the household is de jure non-existent. In such an institutional context, some market processes are more autonomous in relation to the state, while others are more embedded within state structures. In this article, we offer a theoretical account of the shape that North Korea's market economy has taken, developed from a set of fishing industry case studies. We note four broad categories of enterprises: closely embedded, loosely embedded, semi-autonomous, and autonomous. By relative autonomy/embeddedness we mean control over fixed assets, cash flow, and operational decisions such as wage and price setting. We postulate three major determinants of embeddedness/autonomy: (1) relative strategic resource scarcity between state and market actors, (2) monitoring costs, and (3) institutional evolution that reflects these realities, though to varying extents.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the East Asia Institute

INTRODUCTION

EMBEDDED AND AUTONOMOUS MARKETS

Today, much of North Korea's private sector continues to exist in a legal gray zone, but there are some shades of “gray.” Some firms involving private entrepreneurs (embedded entrepreneurs) exist within state organizations. They form what we have termed elsewhere “Pseudo-state Enterprises” (Lankov et al. Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017). Conversely, other private entrepreneurs do not formally operate as part of state firms and are more autonomous in relation to state organizations. In this article, we examine the fishing industry to generate an empirically rooted theory as to why it is that some forms of market activities are more embedded within the state, while others are more autonomous in relation to state structures.

A Marxist-Leninist Party-State, which to some extent North Korea remains, is a mono-organizational society where no legitimate form of social organization beyond the household itself exists outside the boundaries of the state (Rigby Reference Rigby and Tucker1977; Ellman Reference Ellman2014, 29). Hence, to understand how North Korean market actors are socially embedded, one must analyze how market actors relate to the state.

Thus, to borrow terminology that Peter Evans (Reference Evans1995) used originally to describe the role of states in industrial transformation, but turn it on its head, market actors can be said to have become embedded within or autonomous in relation to the North Korean state. There is actually a continuum of possibilities between these two extremes: different market actors differ in the degree to which their firms are embedded in or autonomous in relation to the state-dominated political economy.

Using a set of case studies from the North Korean fishing industry, we offer an account of how and why some market actors become embedded within state structures while others have become and remained autonomous in relation to the state. We posit that there are two indicators of relative embeddedness. The first is the degree of resource/asset sharing: how much do state actors and organizations provide market actors and vice versa? The provision of strategic assets and resources (land, labor, licenses, and registrations inter alia) by state actors often comes with additional control from state actors and requirements for the provision of revenue. This leads to the second indicator: how much control does the state organization attempt to exercise over cash flow and the way business is conducted (the market actor firm's “business model”)?

We argue that, first, a (more) embedded market actor has greater access to valuable and scarce state resources, but such access also implies greater control by the state, especially over cash flow and wage setting. In situations where resource scarcity and dependence are more mutual—that is, where the state organization provides more resources—one should expect a higher degree of embedding. This is primarily because the state organization has the necessary financial incentives (as well as ability to provide important or even vital administrative and legal support) to maintain closer and more intrusive ties.

Second, we also argue that the incentive or capacity to monitor is an important factor. Some market firms are less embedded in spite of reliance on state-owned resources because their operations are too small or dispersed to be monitored more effectively. This has led to the creation of new market institutions and their partial formalization by the North Korean state. Thus, excessive monitoring costs given resource scarcity faced by the North Korean state mean that many North Korean traders (wholesale and retail) in the domestic market, as well as household producers are partially or largely autonomous in relation to the state.

This relative autonomy has been partially recognized in North Korean law and in actual practice. And this recognition points to attempts, to a limited extent, by the government to institutionalize and regulate some market practices. This institutionalization can be termed a form of “institutional compromise,” with market forces and actors, and it is also an important factor in the growth of autonomous market actors outside the confines of the state sector.

We believe the approach we set out is novel insofar as it analyzes market–state relations in North Korea with a particular emphasis on the limits of state power, and also the presence of strategic resources within state organizations that structure relationships between the state organizations and market actors. Moreover, this article contributes to a growing literature on marketization by offering a theoretical account of why different types of firm have arisen.

CASE STUDIES FROM THE FISHING INDUSTRY

Herein, we focus on the fishing industry which can be seen as a good material of a case study. The industry contains a rich supply chain with niches that have elements comparable or broadly similar to those found in many other industries in the country. These include retail and wholesale marketing, a range of largely autonomous household activities, as well as involvement of the state Foreign Trade Companies (FTCs), and side-work units. Each part of the supply chain is comparable to a set of organizational forms/activities that today are integral elements of the North Korean economy as a whole, and thus the fishing industry can be considered as having features that may be generalizable to many other areas of the North Korean economy.

With respect to the level of embeddedness within the state, the four ideal types that we deduce from interview data and from the existing literature on North Korean marketization are as follows:

  • the deeply embedded entrepreneur often operating within a Foreign Trade Company (frequently as its “head of a branch”), under relatively high degree of supervision and support from a state entity;

  • the loosely embedded entrepreneur (like a boat owner) under relatively little supervision from the state entity they are embedded within;

  • the semi-autonomous or fully autonomous trader (traders of fisheries products, but also potentially of many other exportable, producer, and consumer goods), sometimes under some state control in marketplaces, other times autonomous in relation to state structures

  • the fully autonomous household producer, working from the autonomy of their own home with little if any government control

The kind of resources provided by the state appears to directly affect how much value the state organization is able to appropriate. This means that Foreign Trade Companies (FTCs), which usually are able to provide more resources, are also able to appropriate more value and have more control over their market partners than many domestically orientated state organizations were (at least until recently). FTC headquarters may also provide capital, as well as export rights and significant political protection (Yang Reference Yang2008; Joung Reference Joung2012; Lee et al. Reference Lee, Yang, Kim, Lee, Lim and Cho2013; Kim Reference Kim2013).

However, other state partners in the fishing industry and elsewhere have less to offer to their private partners, and less capacity to monitor them. In the fishing industry, for example, the “side-work boat” is less embedded within the state than FTC-based operations. Indeed, generally speaking, “side-work units” inside and outside the fishing industry appear to less deeply embedded within the relevant SOEs and other state structures and less subject to control, but also offered fewer resources by their state counterparts. This is partially a product of their institutional origins as part of state campaigns to stimulate semi-autonomous production within state-owned enterprises using waste and idle resources (Yun Reference Yun2018).

The owners of side-work boats (who normally, but not always, also operate the boats as captains) pay state organization a fee for its willingness to register their boats as its property. This registration gives the owners the right to fish, since access to the sea is controlled through licensing, thoroughly enforced by the coastguard. Getting sea access licenses requires a fixed regular payment to be made to the state agency, but little more control by that agency. Such ‘side-work units’ also operate in other sectors, such as on agricultural plots organized on the land of state enterprises, in bus transport, haulage, and also consumer services like catering; their continued proliferation indicates that they are a real source of income for state agencies (Yang and Yun Reference Yang and Yun2016). For the state agencies, they generate predictable cash flow in the form of license fees with no additional resources offered or control exerted.

Other activities exist outside the state. The household economy of cottage industrial production is perhaps the clearest example of activities that are autonomous in relation to state structures. Many forms of household production exist: the 2008 Census indicates that over 80 percent of North Korean households were involved in such production on a daily basis (Jeong et al. Reference Jeong, Kim and Suk2012). Of respondents to UNICEF's Multiple-Indicator Cluster Survey (MICS) in 2017, 53.7 percent of households reported having their own agricultural land, including 29.7 percent of urban households (UNICEF 2018). This is a major source of legal household production that can be sold on markets domestically, independent from the state. Interview testimony discussed below indicates that in the fishing industry, households have been an important source of equipment, boats, and nets inter alia. Catch processing and storage can also be done inside the household.

Some forms of market trading are also largely or completely autonomous in relation to state organizations beyond the payment of rental fees for usage of the market space. In some cases, traders do not require even market space, and this makes them even less dependent on the state. With the spread of mobile telephone ownership, this may have become a more viable option for more market actors (Lee et al. Reference Lee, Kwak, Kim, Kim, Yang and Lee2017).

In the next sub-section, we briefly lay out our methodology. First we offer a brief summary of the existing literature on markets in North Korea and interaction between markets and state organizations, pointing to issues that our study seeks to address. Next we consider the concept of embeddedness and outline the determinants we have deduced from the data we have been able to compile. Section 3 considers four types of relations with the state in the North Korean fishing industry. We offer conclusions in Section 4.

METHODOLOGY

SOURCES

In this article, we use interview data (gathered in 2016–17) from 15 interviewees (who worked in separate de facto/de jure firms connected to the fish/seafood supply chain). Interviewees were all former participants at different levels of the industry, from different parts of the country, who worked in the industry at different times. Furthermore, they are, to quote Eisenhardt and Graebner (Reference Eisenhardt and Graebner2007, 28) “highly knowledgeable informants who view the focal phenomena from diverse perspectives.” We also cite refugee surveys regarding the North Korean economy to give some indication of how prevalent the types of business we are describing actually are.

Two issues often raised regarding the use of North Korean refugee interview data are reliability and generalizability. We use what Patton (Reference Patton2000, 1195) termed “triangulation of qualitative data sources,” and the theoretical categories we postulate are based upon multiple data sources including North Korean official sources, our own interview data, and existing research published by South Korean researchers since 1990. By using a diverse range of sources we hope to maximize reliability and generalizability of our findings. The structures that we analyze are well known to researchers and have existed for decades (for instance, Seo Reference Seo1994; Naewaetongsinsa 1995). Market actors began to strategically embed in FTCs in the early 1990s (Seo Reference Seo1994; Yang Reference Yang2008). Market actors began to emerge within side-work units even earlier, in the late 1980s (Yun Reference Yun2013). Market trading and autonomous household production have always been a part of the North Korean economy to some extent.Footnote 1 We thus believe we are on relatively firm ground in creating a causal theory as to why they exist and take the form they do.

In addition to interview testimony, for context we cite North Korean official sources like The Korean Compendium of Geography: Industrial Geography (in Korean “Chosŏn Chiri Chŏnsŏ: Kyŏngje Chiri”), and Reference Volume for Cadres in the Legal Field (in Korean “Pŏpt'ujaeng Pumun Ilgundŭr-ŭl Wihan Ch'amgosŏ”), as well as North Korean laws. Where relevant, we also cite the works of North Korea's leaders.

MEASUREMENT

The level of embeddedness cannot be measured quantitatively through interview data or the utilization of other currently available sources, but the same is true of many economic phenomena (Piore Reference Piore2006). Through semi-structured interviews with former market actors about the role and power of the state and the autonomy of private actors, we have elucidated how and to what extent state organizations are able to control over market actors.

We extrapolate the four above-mentioned relative levels of embeddedness and autonomy. We seek to generate a set of empirically rooted causal explanations for the relative embeddedness/autonomy of different market actors deduced from comparable cases (Eisenhardt Reference Eisenhardt1989; Ragin Reference Ragin2014, 34–52), North Korean official sources, and existing studies of North Korean marketization. The conceptual underpinnings of this are further described below.

EXISTING LITERATURE ON NORTH KOREAN MARKETIZATION

The literature on marketization generally has largely focused on the role of the central state vis-a-vis the market. The work of Han (Reference Han2009), Yang (Reference Yang2010), Park (Reference Park2011), Kim and Yang (Reference Kim and Yang2012), Yun (Reference Yun2013), Yang and Yun (Reference Yang and Yun2016) among others has highlighted the role of private actors and private finance within state-owned enterprises and other state institutions. Han (Reference Han2009) analyzes changing central government policy toward the market in the 2000s and shifting attitudes to reform. Lee Seok-gi (Reference Lee2003) identifies a core institutional mechanism through which markets began to penetrate state-owned enterprises and other state institutions in North Korea: the cash plan (“aeksang kyehyaek” in Korean). Yang (Reference Yang2010) stresses the role of spontaneous market forces, while Park (Reference Park2011) points to the key role played by many state organizations in promoting marketization. Kim and Yang (Reference Kim and Yang2012), Yun (Reference Yun2013), Haggard and Noland (Reference Haggard and Noland2011) offer interesting, illustrative refugee survey data indicating widespread de facto privatization. However, we believe that the term “de facto privatization,” while useful, does not fully capture the complexity of relations that can exist between market actors in certain niches and the lack of such relations in other niches.

A central debate in the study of North Korea's contemporary political economy is currently about the extent to which marketization can be described as primarily being “from below” or “from above.” In other words, it is debated to what extent North Korea's post-socialist market institutions, actors, and relations emerged spontaneously from coping strategies adopted by households and low-level agents of the state, or from above through the conscious action of FTC headquarters and central government agencies in Pyongyang (Lee et al. Reference Lee, Yang, Kim, Lee, Lim and Cho2013).

We offer a new answer: many market actors have ties to or formally act within state agencies and SOEs, but such ties are not necessarily an indication solely of direct control or hierarchical relations. Rather, as evidence presented here demonstrates, they are indicative of a two-way process. On the one hand, market actors cede a level of operational autonomy to become embedded within state institutions and therefore subject to their oversight, while on the other hand state institutions also cede some discretionary control over certain assets/rights to market actors in order to obtain access to potential revenue streams. Thus marketization is often neither top-down, or bottom-up, but co-dependent.

THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK: EMBEDDEDNESS AND ITS PUTATIVE CAUSES

MARKET ACTORS EMBEDDED IN THE STATE ORDER

In North Korea, some state organizations are able to enter into relationships that involve the pooling of valuable assets like trade rights with private partners. Private market actors have, to borrow an expression from Peter Evans (Reference Evans1995), a form of “embedded autonomy,” existing as quasi-independent actors within the confines of state organizations. However, the level of their embeddedness or autonomy varies greatly. Some market actors are more resource-dependent on state organizations, and hence are forced to accept more oversight, while others are more autonomous and have greater effective control over their fixed assets and cash flow.

We posit that two major causes determine the likelihood and level of embeddedness: resource scarcity and monitoring costs. The spread of market transactions and the emergence of new market actors, as well as marketized production units embedded within the state hierarchy can be understood as an institutional compromise necessary for regime survival (Lee Reference Lee2003; Lankov et al. Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017). The institutional compromises made since the late 1980s are important in understanding how it was that state agencies and enterprises developed interdependent relations with market actors.

The structure of the relationship between state organizations and private actors appears to reflect the value of the assets provided by the two sides—i.e. the extent they have related resources (Dyer Reference Dyer, Singh and Kale2008). The state institution is potentially in a predatory position vis-à-vis market actors, having in theory the ability to dismiss their market partners, and dissolve their operations.Footnote 2 Yet, such actions, while possible, are counterproductive, in the most literal sense, since they destroy productive capacity and potential sources of revenue. Thus, state institutions often lack critical resources, including capital, industry-specific knowledge and skills, as well as the access to and knowledge of foreign markets and local networks. Such resources are in scarce supply in the North Korean economy, and often are under control of the private market operators. Therefore, if state agencies wish to acquire some of the residual income that can be generated from the utilization of such resources they have to enter into arrangement with market operators.

Conversely, state agencies also possess a multitude of resources which are potentially useful for market actors. If market actors wish to acquire access to such assets and resources, they may also have to accept some form of control from state agencies. For example, state control over access to foreign markets can mean that private entrepreneurs enter arrangements with state agencies in order to gain less dangerous and more regularized access to export markets (Joung Reference Joung2016).

Monitoring costs is another major factor. As Lankov et al. (Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017) have demonstrated, relations between market actors and the state organizations are partially the product of the monitoring costs of evaluating performance. Indeed, the costs of monitoring are seemingly a major reason why some forms of market activity are largely autonomous in relation to the state. Limited monitoring capacity has increasingly been recognized through the legalization of a range of market activities in North Korean law. Many market activities on the part of state entities becoming legal since 2002–03 (Yang Reference Yang, Seok, Chang-uk, Moon-su, Seok-gi and Eun-yeong2009).

The issue of monitoring costs was first recognized by Kim Il Sung himself in the late 1960s, with some forms of household production for market trading being legalized back then. The state's relative tolerance of autonomous market actors is thus also arguably the product of institutional compromise, compromise that emerged in the mid-1960s after attempts to completely eliminate all markets (Joung Reference Joung2011). As North Korea has become more marketized, more production has occurred outside the confines of the state—including crops, livestock, garments, and various other commodities and inputs (Seo Reference Seo1994; Choi and Koo Reference Choi and Koo2003; Lankov et al. Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017; Kim Reference Kim2017; Choi Reference Choi2018).

In section 3 we will illustrate how these causal claims can be justified with reference to the case of the fishing industry.

THE CASE OF THE FISHING INDUSTRY

OVERVIEW

Background

In the late 1950s, private fishing, hitherto dominant, fell victim to collectivization and nationalization programs. From then on, the North Korean fishing industry was composed of three different kinds of organization: state-run fishing enterprises, fishing cooperatives, and side-work fishing units (“puǒp chagǒppan”). In theory, the “side-work units” existed solely to produce foodstuffs and consumer goods to be eventually distributed to the workers of the SOE or state agency under whose auspice they were established. State-run fishing companies were directly managed either by the central government or by regional authorities. Cooperatives (actually state-owned in everything but the name) were usually under the provincial or local government, while side-work units were part of larger state organizations or SOEs (Various 1990, 245). Side-work units, relatively unimportant at early stage, came to serve as a key organizational vehicle for the marketization of North Korean fishing in the 1980s (Yun Reference Yun2013). Notably, side-work units also became important in agriculture from the 1980s onward, and in mining in the 1990s (Choi Reference Choi1998, 17–20; Joung Reference Joung2016).

The state's investment and development strategy for much of North Korean history can be characterized by heavy emphasis on mass mobilization and large-scale production. Geographically dispersed production would be more costly and difficult to monitor, and Kim Il Sung (Reference Kim1993, 259) believed that limiting the number of firms was to be important in effective state planning. If official data is any guide, the four large state-run fishing companies under the DPRK Cabinet's Fishing Ministry produced at least 48 percent of the total catch in the 1980s (Various 1990, 237–238). This is probably explained by the steady build-up in capital stock at state-run companies. Ship tonnage at state companies between 1960 and 1982 rose by over 600 percent, the number of large fishing trawlers increased by over 400 percent between 1970 and 1980 in the industry overall, while the number of medium-sized trawlers rose by a factor of 41.5 between 1960 and 1982 (Various 1990, 242). The motorized fishing fleet as of 1988 is given in Table 1.

TABLE 1 North Korea's motorized fishing fleet in 1988

Data from: Yu-jin Lee, “Ch'oegŭn Pukhanŭi Susanŏptongyanggwa Chŏngch'aek Pangyang Yŏn'gu” (Recent Trends in North Korea's Fishing Industry and Research into Policy Directions). Sanŭnjosawŏlbo 11 (2015), 85.

The steady build-up of capital stock created a cost structure that was only sustainable so long as Soviet oil was available at discounted “friendship prices” (Van Ree Reference Van Ree1989; Mikheev Reference Mikheev1993; Szalontai Reference Szalontai2006). The economic collapse of the 1990s led to sudden and fundamental changes in the structure of the industry, with smaller “sub-work units” and nimbler semi-private FTC-run fishing operations becoming more important while large state-operated trawlers and fishing fleets were no longer usable. At the same time, the country's retail and wholesale sectors became increasingly marketized, while Foreign Trade Companies adopted to marketized realities with some forms of embedded marketized structures (Yang Reference Yang2008).

Until the 2017 round of the UN-imposed sanctions, fisheries exports were one of North Korea's most important sources of foreign currency. Indeed, they were North Korea's number one export as recently as 2003, peaking that year at 37 percent of all exports measured in US dollars (KOTRA 2004, 21). They declined thereafter, but, having bottomed out in absolute dollar terms in 2007, the seafood export began to rise until 2016, as shown in Figure 1 below. The UNCTAD data presented below is also unlikely to be complete, but it is nonetheless illustrative of the fact that the fishing industry is an important part of the country's export earnings.

FIGURE 1 (a) North Korean Exports (2001–2019) and (b) North Korean fisheries exports as a percentage of the total (2001–2019)

The Current Supply Chain

Since the late 1950s, only state organizations and agencies have been legally allowed to engage in fishing (aside from fishing on land). The Fisheries Act, first adopted in 1995, codifies this, stipulating that fishing vessels can be registered to state institutions, enterprises, and other organizations (like collective farms), but not as individually owned fishing boats. The Boat Registration Act adopted in 2007 further codifies the system. Enforcement seems to be rigorous, and virtually all informants agree that the proper registration with some official entity is necessary for any fishing boat to go out to sea (R2, R3, R4, R5, R6, R7, R10).

Not only must all boats be registered under a state organization, but all working-age males are also expected to register with a workplace within the state economy. Employment registration rights and sea access rights (the latter being intertwined with boat registrations rights) are two major assets only the state organizations can possibly possess in the North Korean system, but any aspiring entrepreneur needs these rights to run a fishing business (Lankov et al. Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017). A stylized portrait of the supply chain of the fishing industry is presented in Figure 2.Footnote 3

FIGURE 2 The North Korean fishing industry supply chain

Data from: Authors' reconstruction from interviews and official sources

There is a marked difference between FTCs and side-work units. Many FTCs are multi-unit firms with significant capacity, potentially including in-house haulage capabilities and fish processing (Yang Reference Yang2008). They also can procure fish on the domestic market for sale to foreign markets. By contrast, side-work unit members interviewed indicated that they often sell their catch directly to traders, or else process it in their households before selling it on the domestic market.Footnote 4 Traders and households usually exist largely autonomously in relation to the state, though some do embed within state retail enterprises. Below we examine different parts of the supply chain in more depth.

DEEPLY EMBEDDED FTC BRANCHES

In the early 1990s, quasi-independent trading entities within Foreign Trade Companies (FTCs) began to emerge, here again partially due to a relaxation of institutional constraints (Yang Reference Yang2008).

FTCs answer to a central government agency. Internally, they have different branches or “bases” (“kiji” in Korean), which produce goods or provide services primarily for export or for sale in foreign currency. These units can include everything from mines to factories, fishing stations to restaurants. Some are akin to franchises of their respective FTC, run by “entrepreneur branch managers” that use the “brand” of the FTC and some aspects of its “business model,” in exchange for protection, trade rights, and sometimes other resources.

Figure 3 illustrates the complex inter-dependencies that pervade the North Korean foreign trade company system. Nominally it is hierarchical and under the complete control of the state, but in reality, it plays host to numerous market actors. The lines between the FTC and its branches indicate the maximal known amount of resource sharing that may occur, which includes the FTC offering nominal salaries and some inputs to branches.

FIGURE 3 The North Korean Foreign Trade Company System and the fishing industry

Data from: Kim Jic-soo (Reference Kim2013) with additions and revisions

Some FTC branches are run partially with individual investment and partly with loans from state banks and/or funds provided by central state organizations (R14), while some others fully rely on investment made by individuals (R2, R3). The decentralization of the system in the early 1990s was an institutional compromise made by Kim Jong Il in order to raise exports, but it led to the embedding of market actors in the state (Yang Reference Yang2008).

Surveys of North Korean refugees indicate that the number of foreign-currency earning operations run or financed by individuals rose between 2005 and 2015, with as much as 45 percent of such operations believed to be private as of 2015 (Yang and Yun Reference Yang and Yun2016, 63). Access to capital also appears to be a primary motivator for state organizations to enter into such arrangements. The government sought to address this particular manifestation of resource scarcity in 2014, by legalizing private loans to state companies (National Intelligence Service 2019, 579), but actual private management and ownership rights have not been recognized.

An FTC head office may not just lack financial resources, but also technical expertise, local market knowledge, managerial expertise and many other resources that cannot simply be acquired through visits to the local marketplace or lending from local informal credit providers. Thus, the comparison to franchising is a helpful one. As scholars of franchising have noted, resource scarcity can occur along multiple dimensions, and the franchisor (aka the FTC head office in our case) is thus induced to franchise, i.e. embed private actors, when vertical integration is not possible due to monitoring costs or lack of resources (Minkler Reference Minkler1992; Norton Reference Norton1988; Combs and Ketchen Reference Combs and Ketchen1999; Gonzalez-Diaz and Solis-Rodriguez Reference Gonzalez-Diaz and Solis-Rodriguez2012).

FTCs provide entrepreneurs, acting as branch managers, with a range of important resources. They can provide access to foreign markets, which other entities previously did not possess, provide physical resources (factory and warehouse space for processing and dispatch inter alia), as well as the above-mentioned asset (boats) registrations, sea access rights and employment registration. Thus FTC branches do not just catch their own fish for sale but can also engage in fish wholesaling on international markets (R2, R14). FTC export rights come in the form of “trade plans” (colloquially known as “wak’ŭ” in North Korea).Footnote 5 In the case of fish, North Korean legal documents indicate that in the 2000s, the price of at least some exported maritime produce was regulated under the trade plan system (Various 2010, 249–250).

Greater embedding within the state involves a greater level of control from state agencies—as we have noted, the recourse access and control are two side of the same phenomenon, the more resources the state agency is capable of providing, the more control it can expect to exercise. Being within the FTC framework also allows entrepreneurs to run larger, vertically integrated operations of greater technical sophistication, involving storage, haulage, and logistics that state organizations may not be able to afford to fund and manage on their own. Such operations can provide large quantities of catch to foreign counterparties (R2, R3, R13, R14). These foreign trading rights make FTC branch management a lucrative proposition for would-be investor-managers—generating annual revenues sometimes measured in the hundreds of thousands of dollars (R2, R3). Indeed, within the North Korean system foreign trade rights are also a scarce resource in their own right. Foreign trade rights have not been a well distributed, open-access, resource, and this has further compelled entrepreneurs to create firms embedded within the state.

At the same time, maximizing profit and minimizing embezzlement entails significant monitoring costs for state agencies (Lankov et al. Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017). FTC head office monitors its branches to make sure that they do not embezzle excessively and also abide by certain state rules regarding various aspects of operations. The amount of embezzlement and other rule breaking allowed differs by the time period and the FTC's own characteristics to an unknown extent.Footnote 6

The FTC monitoring regime means that the operational autonomy of entrepreneur branch managers is more restricted than that of other boat operators. State mandated practices such as the payment of monthly wages in North Korean won, and delivery of food rations to employees is seemingly mandatory as well (R2, R13, R14). This is partially because the North Korean leadership and its police are interested in ensuring that such norms are upheld (Han Reference Han2009; Various 2010).

What's more, as noted above, at least some prices are set not by the branches or the FTCs, but by the Ministry of Trade, which issues “trade plans” (“Muyŏk Kyehwaek”). Hence, in a real sense, even though many branches of FTCs are financed by private individuals, they are run at least partially according to rules set by head office and by the state regulator of foreign trade. To use the terminology of franchising, private investors use not just their host FTC's “brand” but also important aspects of its “business model.” This represents both an institutional compromise on the part of the state, and a significant constraint on market actors operating under such arrangements.

This level of control, with the monitoring costs it appears to entail and the level of resource sharing that both sides engage in, appears to be absent from much of the rest of the fishing industry. It does, however, appear to be common within the foreign trade sector (Yang Reference Yang2008; Yang and Yun Reference Yang and Yun2016). Attempts to reform the sector under Kim Jong Un have recently been reversed, and there is little sign that the arrangements described above will be replaced by greater formal property rights in the near future.Footnote 7

LOOSELY EMBEDDED SIDE-WORK BOATS

Surveys of North Korean refugees indicate that there are a large number of fishing boats which are bought by market actors, or made to their order, but registered to state organizations, officially being productive equipment used by “side-work units” (puǒp). This practice seems to be becoming more common (Yang and Yun Reference Yang and Yun2016). The boat owners pay a regular cash fee for the right to use registration (Lim Reference Lim2009, 127). Like boat registration with the FTCs, such schemes remain technically illegal, but have been largely tolerated from the center, though certain forms of private enterprises embedded within the side-work institutional form have been subject to crackdowns in the recent past (Han Reference Han2009, 205). This de facto private ownership of fishing boats as an institutional compromise traces back to the late 1980s when such arrangements appear to have begun and were tolerated by the government (R10; Yun Reference Yun2013, 133)

Interviewees agree that the boat and, where provided by captains or crew, other equipment, is de facto private property, and can be bought and sold on the open market outside the supervision of organization to which such property is nominally registered. This scheme is illustrated in Figure 4.

FIGURE 4 Boat Registration Schemes within North Korean state entities

Data from: Authors' reconstruction from interviews and official sources

As Lankov et al. (Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017) have catalogued elsewhere, fixed payment schemes are widely used by North Korean state organizations who lack the requisite monitoring capacity. In the fishing industry the problem is particularly acute, with so many state organizations being permitted to organize their own fishing “side-work units.” In 2011, Kim Jong Il (Reference Kim2015, 526) even mentioned this, saying “not a few state organizations break the law and use their ‘specialness’ as an excuse to overfish.”Footnote 8 This is a further indication of how unregulated the industry is in practice.

However, issues are not merely a product of monitoring costs: they also seem to reflect resource scarcity faced by the state organizations—pretty much like the situation we have seen in the FTCs case. Respondents agree that state organizations primarily hand over their name to would-be captains or boat owners in order to acquire a source of reliable and valuable income, so it is the resource scarcity which leads state organizations into loosely embedded relations with market actors. However, the price they charge appears to differ on the basis of the quality of the name—likes the brands of franchises. The political police (powibu), the military as well as central party-related organizations tend to be particularly expensive to register with (R4, R5, R10).

Yet, even the lower reaches of these politically powerful organizations compete for market actors as a source of supplemental income (R5). It is also important to note that the actual boat owner chooses the state organization to register with, and can switch registration to another organization with relative ease and few if any penalties (R4, R6). This “right to free exit” is a clear indicator of actual ownership rights increases the competition between the state agencies and adversely influences the leverage they have over their private partners.

The above described registration schemes are by no means unique to the fishing industry. Similar registration schemes are also prevalent in transport and haulage, and they have basically existed in agriculture since the 1980s (Yang and Yun Reference Yang and Yun2016). This is a further indication that conclusions drawn from case studies from the fishing industry are potentially generalizable to other sectors. Such schemes were made explicitly illegal in 2008 under Article 36 of the Equipment Management Act (National Intelligence Service 2019, 642). In practice, however, this regulation seems to have little if any impact on the actual situation. The owners have the right to dispose of boats and profit from their use, and they are in daily operational control, with compensation agreed upon by the captain or owner and his crew.

Owners make use of a variety of different compensation schemes for their workers, dependent on their structural position vis-à-vis their state partners. Fishermen often have to provide their own equipment (nets, boats) and bring their own provisions. They are frequently compensated with a percentage of the catch. The practice seems to be widespread in side-work units (R4, R5, R6, R7). R1, a woman who worked on a coast guard vessel as a fisherwoman to supply the unit with food, was also given a percentage of what she caught.

Outside the foreign trade sector, there seems to be little integration between individual boat owners and other parts of the industry beyond the household (R4, R5, R6, R7). Fishermen and women may sell their catch at market, their families may process, store and/or sell their catch, but interviewees indicated that larger, vertically integrated firms based on side-work boats do not yet exist. This could be why respondents agree that the sale of catch is not regulated or controlled by the state organization to which the boat is registered. Instead the captain and/or the owner (if separate from captain) and the crew dispose of the catch and acquire the income from its sale directly at port or at market.

Some of the state's larger fishing companies, dormant for nearly three decades, appear to have been rehabilitated in recent years, though their actual ownership structure is not known (Bermudez and DuMond Reference Bermudez and DuMond2018). At present, however, so far as interviewees and survey data indicate, it appears that much of the fishing industry remains loosely embedded within the state, and is de facto privatized with respect to operations, profit-sharing, and the disposability of tangible fixed assets.

AUTONOMOUS HOUSEHOLD PRODUCERS, SEMI-AUTONOMOUS TRADERS, AND PSEUDO-STATE RETAILERS

Domestic sales and input production part of the fishing industry has significantly autonomous elements. The August 3 Consumer Goods Movement (“the 8.3 Movement”), major institutional compromise, launched in 1984, presaged a rapid expansion in the scope of market transactions and market actors in the economy (Lee Reference Lee1992; Choi and Koo Reference Choi and Koo2003; Yun Reference Yun2018). The spread of household commerce, largely autonomous in relation to state retail organizations, presaged the spread of embedded market actors inside the North Korean state mono-organizational society—creating a market for embedded entrepreneurs to purchase inputs and sell their product domestically.

In the fishing industry, the retail and household sectors have integrated to some extent, with traders also sometimes involved in food processing (R10). The same is also true of other household industries, with household producers also sometimes selling the product they make at market (Choi Reference Choi2018, 50–52). There are also specialized producers of nets and even boats who sell to traders or customers inside the market sector (R11, R12), though imports of equipment appear to be highly important—South Korean sources estimate that over 80 percent of North Korean fishing equipment and over 90 percent of nets are now imported from abroad, overwhelmingly from China (KDB 2015, 882), and our informants also unanimously say that Chinese imports dominate the North Korean fishing industry.

For these market actors, strategic embedding may serve no purpose because nearby enterprises and other state organizations may not possess useful resources or have no significant enough incentive to share these resources with households. Here, resource scarcity does not lead to embedding due to a lack of related resources that would incentivize state organizations and households to enter into partnerships for the production of nets/boats/baits. The monitoring costs also play a role, since state agencies have limited capacity, and can only utilize so many opportunities. The low value of the product and its dispersion across a large number of households means that monitoring costs given the potential revenues (or lack thereof) appear to be too high for state agencies to seek embedded relations with these private actors.

These concerns are reflected to some extent in the central government's legalization of some household activities. The sphere of individual property for control and profit purposes (though not legally sellable or leasable under Civil Code) is a well-established institution under North Korean law. The North Korean government has issued manuals for the police whose legal analysis defends the right of households to profit from the legal use of their property (Various 2010, 95–96). This includes one's garden, kitchen utensils, and home appliances, as well as potentially the labor power of the household itself when not at regular state assigned workplaces or schools.

In the fishing industry, another such household-based and relatively autonomous group are seafood traders. Interviewees report that sales of fish at the wharf and market are done relatively freely, with wharf guards being bribed where needed (R1, R5, R6, R7, R8, R9, R10, R15). This practice appears to have occurred as early as the 1980s and to have become commonplace in the 1990s. Since 2002, marketplace transactions may occur within officially designated market spaces, with stall rental fees collected by state market management organizations (Lim Reference Lim2008). State regulation in this area can be intrusive and systemized: prices charged in marketplaces are regulated (Han Reference Han2009; Kim Reference Kim2011), and traders paying stall fees or rents (Hong et al. Reference Hong, Cha, Joung and Kim2016; Cha and Collins Reference Cha and Collins2018).

There have been crackdowns on market activity in the past, especially in the 2005–09 period (Han Reference Han2009; Yang Reference Yang2010), but transactions are not limited to this space, and, thanks to the spread of mobile phones, they can increasingly occur outside officially prescribed places (Lee et al. Reference Lee, Kwak, Kim, Kim, Yang and Lee2017). However, transacting outside the market, out of view of the state, either through makeshift “grasshopper markets”/alleyway markets (peripatetic markets), or at home having met prospective clients at designated meeting points is by no means a new phenomenon (Choi Reference Choi1998).

There are cases when traders also make use of the state-owned assets, sometimes engaging in spot transactions with state enterprises. For instance, wholesale traders have to use large refrigerating facilities which tend to be owned and administered by the SOEs, often the old large fishing companies whose fleets have been moored since the early 1990s (for such companies, the still-operational refrigeration facilities sometimes constitute a major source of income) (R8, R10, R11). However, such a relationship does not directly affect the autonomy that traders have with respect to the operations of their business—i.e. the sale of maritime produce.

The sale of maritime produce is bifurcated into two rather distinct groups: FTCs, which play host to entrepreneurs embedded in state structures, and private traders, who are often not a formal part of any particular state structure. Granted, the market system is becoming increasingly institutionalized, with permanent physical markets growing in number and scale (Joung Reference Joung2010). Such institutionalization means that traders have to pay regular stall fees, but it does not appear to substantially impact their business otherwise.

There are also cases where traders make use of state retail space, or even embed their operations within state retail institutions. The sale on consignment of consumer goods by state shops on commission for private traders (this practice was legalized fully in the early 2000s; Lim Reference Lim2008), while traders actually taking over the running of state shops has become increasingly common but remains illegal (Lee et al. Reference Lee, Kwak, Kim, Kim, Yang and Lee2017, 85). This is a form of embedding of retail operations within state structures that is akin that of a side-work boat insofar as traders pay fees for the use of state assets (physical space and the right to trade), but appear to be much freer of state control than FTC branch managers. Here again the state organization has far less scarce resources to offer—sales rights—than an FTC, so thus is able to exercise far less control on the enterprise.

Refugee surveys indicate that the embedding of market actors into state retail organizations became more prevalent between 2005 and 2015, with over 50 percent of state retail establishments being such embedded firms (Yang and Yun Reference Yang and Yun2016, 65). For larger traders, involvement in such schemes in the past, prior to 2002, would likely have afforded them protection, and state retail institutions would have benefited from the resources of these traders. Since 2002, the seeming further rise of such a practice may be due to the fact that state shop space is an alternative to market retail space.

CONCLUSION

Among the post-socialist states, North Korea occupies an unusual position: unlike China or Vietnam, it has not experienced officially approved market-oriented reforms (until recently, at least); unlike the ex-Soviet states, it has not made a formal switch to the market economy. Nonetheless, the market relations in the country have existed since the late 1980s and have come to play a major role in its economy since the late 1990s. However, the market actors in North Korea operate in a very peculiar legal and institutional environment which makes necessary an unusually close interaction between them and state agencies/enterprises of different kinds.

In spite of all changes, the state has maintained near monopolistic legal control in some areas which are of key significance for a number of private businesses: for example, only government agencies or SOEs can officially own vehicles, real estate, or seagoing vessels. It means that the rights to register such assets (unusable without proper registration), which are vital for any aspiring business in many fields, constitute an important resource which the official entities might be willing to share if and when conditions are right. Apart from the fixed assets, the SOE and state agency to a large extent control cash flow as well as wage and price settings. These privileged rights of the state entities make close cooperation with them a necessary condition for many types of private businesses.

On the other hand, the newly emerging private operators have their own unique resources which are beyond the reach of the SOE and/or government agencies—like capital, always in short supply in the state economy with a dysfunctional banking system. Frequently, they also possess vital technical expertise or access to important networks.

In this situation it makes perfect sense for both sides to enter a mutually profitable arrangement which would allow them access to the vital resources controlled by other side. Given the institutional environment of North Korea which leaves little if any operational space for the non-government economic actors, the best solution is to embed what is essentially a private entity within the SOE or state agency.

Such embedded companies are very common in the present-day North Korean economy. The level of embeddedness or autonomy, however, varies significantly. Research indicates that it depends largely on the amount of resources both parties can contribute. Generally, the more valuable resources can be presented by the state entity, the greater the level of embeddedness is likely to be.

This trend is well illustrated by the difference between two types of arrangements which are common in North Korean coastal fishing nowadays. While nearly all fishing boats nowadays are effectively run privately, their owners/operators can choose whether they will register with the foreign trade companies (FTC) or with side-work units of SOE. The FTC, being privileged entities, can bring significantly more resources into the deal. Their registration usually provides better legal protection, many more opportunities for vertical integration, and direct or semi-direct access to the overseas markets. The side-work units have fewer resources, even though it is possible to arrange vertical integration across the state/household barrier, or find access to the export networks.

Given such differences, it is predictable that FTC-associated private entities have a greater level of embeddedness, with more control exercised by the FTC supervisor. Nonetheless, these bodies also tend to attract market operators with greater amount of capital and better access to resources in general. So the logic behind the embeddedness is sound, and these schemes are mutually beneficial for both sides. They constitute an interesting case of post-socialist arrangement, being neither fully marketized nor fully administrative.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

The authors would like to thank the two anonymous reviewers, and the journal's editor Professor Stephan Haggard for their helpful, insightful, and kind comments, suggestions, and advice. They would also like to thank Hyunjun Yeo for his help and assistance with research.

This work was supported by the Laboratory Program for Korean Studies through the Ministry of Education of the Republic of Korea and Korean Studies Promotion Service of the Academy of Korean Studies (AKS-2019-LAB-1250001).

CONFLICTS OF INTEREST

The authors have no conflicts of interest to declare.

Appendix: Interviewees

Footnotes

1. For a discussion of South Korean literature on North Korean government policy toward markets, see Ward and Green (Reference Ward, Green, Cathcart, Green and DenneyForthcoming).

2. We are grateful to one of the reviewers for pointing this fact out.

3. For simplicity's sake, vertical integration between household producers and market traders has been omitted, as has informal, small-scale smuggling.

4. Smuggling has been omitted from the schema, but certain types of smuggling could be considered autonomous market trading by individuals or households obtaining (illegal) access to foreign markets. Other forms of smuggling are reported to involve FTCs, especially since the implementation of UN sectoral sanctions in 2017.

5. The exercise and leasing of trade rights is codified under the Trade Act, last amended in 2015. The scope of legal ownership of fixed capital assets and the registration process is covered under the Equipment Registration Management Act, last amended in 2015, and does not allow private individuals to own commercial machinery or facilities, nor register them as state assets but continue to utilize them for personal gain (National Intelligence Service 2019, 642).

6. Under Kim Jong Il the auditing system also involves the sporadic dispatch of auditing teams from the Ministry of State Security to detect and curtail embezzlement at the lower levels of the trade bureaucracy (Han Reference Han2009; Kwak Reference Kwak2016).

7. From 2015 the North Korean trade system underwent a number of important legal changes that may lessen the scarcity of trade licenses. Enterprises and collective farms are no longer required to use FTCs as an interface through which to access foreign markets, meaning that private actors potentially have far more potential entities in which to embed their foreign-market-orientated activities (Lee et al. Reference Lee, Kwon, Min, Yang, Lee, Lim and Jeong2018). However, these changes were reversed in 2018, and the old system appears to have largely been restored (Ward Reference Ward2019).

8. The terms “specialness” and “special unit” are euphemisms for the military, Office 39 (the Kim family's fundraising office in the Central Party), the military industrial complex, and the Ministry of State Security.

References

Bermudez, Joseph, and DuMond, Marie. 2018. “Examining the Modernization and Expansion Project at the Korean People's Army Fishery Station No. 15.” Beyond Parallel. https://beyondparallel.csis.org/modernization-expansion-project-korean-peoples-army-fishery-station-no-15/. Accessed October 24, 2018.Google Scholar
Cha, Victor, and Collins, Lisa. 2018. “The Markets: Private Economy and Capitalism in North Korea?.” Beyond Parallel. https://beyondparallel.csis.org/markets-private-economy-capitalism-north-korea/#market-regulation. Accessed October 24, 2018.Google Scholar
Choi, Bong Dae, and Koo, Kab Woo. 2003. “Pukhan Tosi ‘Nongminsijang’ Hyŏngsŏng Kwajŏngŭi Ihaengnonjŏk Hamŭi- 1950–1980yŏndae Sinŭiju, Ch’ŏngjin, Hyesanŭi Sayerŭl Chungsimŭro” (Farmers’ Markets in Sinuiju, Chungjin and Hyesan in North Korea, 1950s–1980s). Hyŏndaebukhanyŏn'gu 6: 133187.Google Scholar
Choi, In-je. 2018. “Pukhanŭi Kaeinsugongŏbe Kwanhan Yŏn'gu” (A Study of Private Handicraft Manufacturing in North Korea). Masters diss., University of North Korean Studies.Google Scholar
Choi, Su-yŏng. 1998. “Pukhanŭi Chae2 Kyŏngjae” (North Korea's Second Economy). Korea Institute of National Unification Research Report 97–20.Google Scholar
Combs, James G., and Ketchen, D.J.. 1999. “Explaining Interfirm Cooperation and Performance: Toward a Reconciliation of Predictions From the Resource-Based View and Organizational Economics.” Strategic Management Journal 20 (9): 867888.10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(199909)20:9<867::AID-SMJ55>3.0.CO;2-63.0.CO;2-6>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dyer, Jeffrey H., Singh, Harbir, and Kale, Prashant. 2008. “Splitting the Pie: Rent Distribution in Alliances and Networks.Managerial and Decision Economics 29 (2–3): 137148.10.1002/mde.1391CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eisenhardt, Kathleen M. 1989. “Building Theories from Case Study Research.” The Academy of Management Review 14 (4): 532550.10.5465/amr.1989.4308385CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eisenhardt, Kathleen M. and Graebner, Melissa E.. 2007. “Theory Building From Cases: Opportunities And Challenges.” Academy of Management Journal 50 (1): 2532.10.5465/amj.2007.24160888CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellman, Michael. 2014. Socialist Planning, 3rd edn. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9781139871341CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, Peter. 1995. Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400821723CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gonzalez-Diaz, Manuel, and Solis-Rodriguez, Vanesa. 2012. “Why do Entrepreneurs Use Franchising as a Financial Tool? An Agency Explanation.” Journal of Business Venturing 27 (3): 325341.10.1016/j.jbusvent.2011.03.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Noland, Marcus. 2011. Witness to Transformation: Refugee Insights into North Korea. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Han, Gi-beom. 2009. “Pukhan Chŏngch'aekkyŏlchŏnggwajŏngŭi Chojikhaengt'aewa Kwallyojŏngch'i: Kyŏngjegaehyŏk Hwaktae Mit Hut'oerŭl Chungsimŭro (2000–09)” (The Organizational Behavior and Bureaucratic Politics in North Korea's Decision-making Process: Expansion and Retreat of Economic Reform, 2000–09). PhD diss., Kyungnam University.Google Scholar
Hong, Min, Cha, Mun-seok, Joung, Eun-lee, and Kim, Hyeok. 2016. “Pukhan Chŏn'guk Sijang Chŏngbo: Kongsiksijang Hyŏnhwangŭl Chungsimŭro” (Information regarding the North Korean National Market: Focusing on Status of Formal Markets). Korea Institute for National Unification (KINU) Research Report 16–24. http://repo.kinu.or.kr/bitstream/2015.oak/8431/1/0001478607.pdf. Accessed October 24, 2018.Google Scholar
Jeong, Hyung-gon, Kim, Byung-yeon, and Suk, Lee. 2012. “Pukhan-ŭi Sichanghwa Hyŏnhwang-gwa Kyŏngche Ch'eche-ŭi Pyŏnhwa Chŏnmang” (The Current Situation of Marketization in North Korea and Prospects for Change in its Economic System). Korea Institute for International Economic Policy, Research Report 12–26. http://kiss.kstudy.com/public/public3-article.asp?key=60001921. Accessed October 24, 2018.Google Scholar
Joung, Eun-lee. 2010. “Pukhan Sichang-ŭi Chetohwa Suchun-e Kwanhan Punsŏk—Kongsŏl Sichang-ŭi Oehyŏngchŏk Palchŏn-ŭl Kipan-ŭro” (A Study of the Systematization Level of North Korean Markets—the Case Study of External Development of the Public Markets). KDI Pukhan kyŏngche ripyu 5: 1447.Google Scholar
Joung, Eun-lee. 2011. “Pukhanaesŏ Sichang-ŭi Yŏksajŏk Hyŏngsŏnggwajŏnggwa Kyŏngjaegujoŭi byŏnhwa” (History of Market and Changes of Economic Structure in North Korea). Asaeayŏngu 54 (1): 283.Google Scholar
Joung, Eun-lee. 2012. “Pukhan Muyŏk Hoesa-e Kwanhan Yŏn'gu: Puk-chung Chŏpkyŏng Tosi Sinŭichu-rŭl Chungsim-ŭro” (A Study of North Korean Foreign Trade Companies: Centered around the Border City of Sinuiju). In 2012 T'ongilpu Sinchin Yŏnkucha Chŏngch'aek Kwacha (The Political Tasks of the 2012 Newly Appointed Researchers at the Ministry Of Unification). Seoul: Ministry of Unification.Google Scholar
Joung, Eun-lee. 2016. “Pukhanŭi Sŏktansanŏpgwa Puk-Chung Muyŏkae Kwanhan Yŏngu: Pukhan Sunchŏntangwangjigurŭl Chungsimŭro” (Research on the North Korean Coal Industry and Sino-North Korean Trade: Focusing on the Sunchŏn Area). Hangukdongbukanonchong 78: 2752.Google Scholar
KDB (Korea Development Bank). 2015. Pukhanŭi Sanŏp (North Korea's Industry). Anyang: Namogihwaek.Google Scholar
Kim, Byung-yeon and Yang, Moon-soo. 2012. Pukhan Kyŏngche-Esŏŭi Sichang-Kwa Chŏngpu (Market and Government in the North Korean Economy). Seoul: Sŏul taehakkyo ch'ulp’anpu.Google Scholar
Kim, Il-han. 2011. “Pukhanŭi Kagyŏkkaehyŏkkwa Sijanggagyŏk Kyŏlchŏngyoin Punsŏk” (The Analysis of the Market Price-Decision Mechanism and Price Reform in North Korea). PhD diss., Dongguk University.Google Scholar
Kim, Il Sung. 1993. “Yŏnhapkiŏpsorŭl Chojikhamyŏ Chŏngmuwŏnŭi Saŏp Ch'egyewa Pangbŏbŭl Kaesŏnhaltedaehayŏ” (On Organizing Industrial Combines and Improving the Work System and Methods Of the Cabinet). In Kimilsŏngjŏjakchip: Che39kwŏn (Kim Il Sung Collected Works: Volume 39). Pyongyang: Chosŏnlodongdangch'ulp’ansa.Google Scholar
Kim, Jic-soo. 2013. “Tonju’ŭi Hyŏngsŏnggwajŏnge Taehan Yŏn'gu” (The Formation Process of ‘Donju’ in North Korea). Masters diss., University of North Korean Studies.Google Scholar
Kim, Jong Il. 2015. “Kwangbokchigusangŏpchungsimŭn Inminsaengwarhyangsange Ibajihanŭn Hyŏndaejŏgin Sangŏppongsagijiida” (The Kwangbok Supermarket is a Modern Commercial Service Branch that Contributes to the Improvement Of the People's Lives). In Kimjŏngilsŏnjip(chŭngbop'an)25kwŏn (Kim Jong Il Collected Works (Expanded Edition): Volume 25). Pyongyang: Chosŏnlodongdangch'ulp’ansa.Google Scholar
Kim, So-yŏng. 2017. “Kyŏngjewigi Ihu Pukhan Nongŏppumunŭi Kyehoekkwa Sijang” (Plan and Market in North Korea's Agriculture after the Economic Crisis). PhD diss., University of North Korean Studies.Google Scholar
KOTRA (Korean Trade-Investment Promotion Agency). 2004. “2003yŏn Pukhanŭi Taeoemuyŏktongyang.” http://news.kotra.or.kr/common/extra/kotranews/globalBbs/249/fileDownLoad/27905.doGoogle Scholar
Kwak, Myeong-Il. 2016. “Pukhan Inminboanwŏn'gwa Chuminŭi Kwan'gye Pyŏnhwa Yŏn'gu” (A Study on the Change of Relations between People's Safety Agents and Residents in North Korea). PhD diss., University of North Korean Studies.Google Scholar
Lankov, Andrei, Ward, Peter, Yoo, Ho-yeol, and Kim, Ji-young. 2017. “Making Money in the State: North Korea's Pseudo-State Enterprises in the Early 2000s.” Journal of East Asian Studies 17 (1): 5167.10.1017/jea.2016.30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Hy-Sang. 1992. “The Economic Reform of North Korea: The Strategy of Hidden and Assimilable Reforms.” Korean Observer 23: 437474.Google Scholar
Lee, Seok-gi. 2003. “Pukhanŭi 1990yŏndae Kyŏngjewigiwa Kiŏp Haengt'aeŭi Pyŏnhwa: Saengjonch'uguhyŏng Naebuja T'ongjewa T'oehaengjŏk Sijangwa” (North Korea's Economy Crisis in the 1990s and Change in Enterprise Behavior: Survival Seeking-type Insider Control and Regressive Marketization). PhD thesis, Seoul National University.Google Scholar
Lee, Seok-gi, Kwak, In-ok, Kim, Seok-jin, Kim, Yeon-ho, Yang, Moon-soo, and Lee, Yeong-hun. 2017. “Pukhanŭi Sŏbisŭsanŏp” (North Korea's Service Sector). Korea Institute for Industrial Economics and Trade Research Report 2017-859. www.kiet.re.kr/part/sDownload.jsp?s_idx=45862.Google Scholar
Lee, Seok-gi, Kwon, Tae-jin, Min, Byeong-gi, Yang, Moon-soo, Lee, Dong-hyeon, Lim, Gang-taeg, and Jeong, Seung-ho. 2018. “Kim Jong Un Sidae Pukhan Kyŏngje Kaehyŏk Yŏnggu” (Kim Jong Un era North Korean economic reform research). Korea Institute for Industrial Economics and Trade Research Report 2018-869.Google Scholar
Lee, Seok-gi, Yang, Moon-soo, Kim, Seok-jin, Lee, Yeong-hun, Lim, Gang-taeg, and Cho, Bong-hyŏn. 2013. Pukhan Kyŏngje Chaengjŏm Punsŏk (An Analysis of Controversies Surrounding the North Korean Economy). Korea Institute for Industrial Economics and Trade Research Report 2013-673. www.kiet.re.kr/part/sDownload.jsp?s_idx=40602.Google Scholar
Lim, Gang-taeg. 2009. “Pukhan'gyŏngjeŭi Sijangwa Silt'ae Kwanhan Yŏn'gu” (Research on the Realities of Marketization in the North Korean Economy). Korea Institute for National Unification (KINU) Research Report 09–04. http://repo.kinu.or.kr/handle/2015.oak/1395. Accessed October 24, 2018.Google Scholar
Lim, Su-ho. 2008. Kyehwaekgwa Sijangŭi Kongjon: Pukhanŭi Kyŏngjaegaehyŏkgwa Chaejaebyŏnhwa Chŏnmang (The Coexistence of Plan and Markets: North Korean Economic Reform and Prospects for Systemic Change). Seoul: Samsung Economic Research Institute.Google Scholar
Mikheev, Vasily. 1993. “Reforms of the North Korean Economy: Requirements, Plans and Hopes.” Korean Journal of Defense Analysis 5 (1): 8195.10.1080/10163279309464486CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minkler, Alanson P. 1992. “Why Firms Franchise: A Search Cost Theory.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 148 (2): 240259.Google Scholar
Naewaetongsinsa. 1995. Pukhansilsangjonghapjaryojip: T'albukjaŭi Chŭngŏnŭl Tonghae Pon Pukhansahae (General Collection of Materials about the Real North Korea: North Korean Society through the Testimonies of North Korean Refugees). Seoul: Naewaetongsinsa Buseol Bukhanmunjaeyeonguso.Google Scholar
National Intelligence Service (NIS). 2019. Pukhanbŏbryŏngjip (North Korean Laws). https://www.nis.go.kr:4016/AF/1_2_1.do. Accessed July 3, 2020.Google Scholar
Norton, Seth W. 1988. “Franchising, Brand Name Capital, and the Entrepreneurial Capacity Problem.” Strategic Management Journal 9: 105114.10.1002/smj.4250090711CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, Hyeong-Jung. 2011. “Pukhan-esŏ 1990 Nyŏntae Chŏngkwŏn Kikwan-Ŭi Sangŏpchŏk Hwaltong-Kwa Sichang Hwaktae” (The Commercial Activity of the State Agencies in North Korea of the 1990s, and the Growth of the Market). T'ongil Chŏngch'aek Yŏngu 20: 213237.Google Scholar
Patton, Michael Q. 2000. “Enhancing the Quality of and Credibility of Qualitative Analysis.” Health Services Research 34: 11891208.Google Scholar
Piore, Michael J. 2006. “Qualitative Research: Does it Fit in Economics?European Management Review 3 (1): 1723.10.1057/palgrave.emr.1500053CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ragin, Charles C. 2014. The Comparative Method: Moving Beyond Qualitative and Quantitative Strategies. Oakland: University of California Press.10.1525/9780520957350CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rigby, T.H. 1977. “Stalinism and the Mono-Organizational Society.” In Stalinism Essays in Historical Interpretation, edited by Tucker, Robert C.. Norton: Piscataway, NJ.Google Scholar
Seo, Jae-jin. 1994. “Pukhan Chumin Kachiŭisik Pyŏnhwa: Tonggu Mit Soryŏnwadŭi Pigyoyŏngu” (The Changing Values of North Koreans: Comparisons with Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union). Korean Institute of National Unification (KINU) Research Report 94–23.Google Scholar
Szalontai, Balazs. 2006. Kim Il Sung in the Khrushchev Era: Soviet-DPRK Relations and the Roots of North Korean Despotism, 1953–1964. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
UNICEF. 2018. “Multiple Indicator Cluster Survey 2017: Survey Findings Report, Democratic People's Republic of Korea.” https://mics-surveys-prod.s3.amazonaws.com/MICS6/East%20Asia%20and%20the%20Pacific/Korea%2C%20Democratic%20People%27s%20Republic%20of/2017/Survey%20findings/Korea%20DPR%202017%20MICS_English.pdf. Accessed June 13, 2019.Google Scholar
Van Ree, Erik. 1989. “The Limits of Juche: North Korea's Dependence on Soviet Industrial Aid, 1953–76.” Journal of Communist Studies (5): 5073.10.1080/13523278908414954CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Various. 1990. Chosŏn Jiri Jŏnsŏ: Kyŏngje Jiri (The Korean Compendium of Economic Geography: Industry Volume) (abbreviated to “KCG”). P'yŏngyang: Kyoyuktosŏch'ulp’ansa.Google Scholar
Various. 2010. Pŏpt'ujaeng Pumun Ilgundŭr-ŭl Wihan Ch'Amgosŏ (Reference Volume for Cadres on the Legal Front) (abbreviated to “RVCLF”). P'yŏngyang: Inminboansŏngch'ulp’ansa.Google Scholar
Ward, Peter. 2019. “Strengthening State Control, North Korea Partially Scraps Foreign Trade Reforms.” NK Pro. www.nknews.org/pro/strengthening-state-control-north-korea-partially-scraps-foreign-trade-reforms/?t=1593752213811. Accessed on July 3, 2020.Google Scholar
Ward, Peter, and Green, Christopher. Forthcoming. 2021. “From Periphery to Center: A History of North Korean Marketization.” Decoding the Sino-North Korean Borderlands, edited by Cathcart, Adam, Green, Christopher, and Denney, Steven. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.Google Scholar
Yang, Moon-soo. 2008. “Pukhan Muyŏg-ŭi Chedo-wa Silt'ae” (The Institutions and Current State of North Korean Foreign Trade). KDI Research Report.Google Scholar
Yang, Moon-soo. 2009. “Formation and Development of North Korean Markets, and an Analysis of Market Actors” (Pukhan Sijang-ŭi Hyŏngsŏng‧Baljŏng-wa Haengwija Punsŏk). In Pukhan Kyehoek kyŏngje-ŭi Pyŏnhwa-wa Sijanghwa (Changes in North Korea's Planned Economy and Marketization), edited by by Seok, Lee, Chang-uk, Kim, Moon-su, Yang, Seok-gi, Lee, and Eun-yeong, Kim, pp. 117145. Seoul: Korean Institute of National Unification: Seoul, 2009).Google Scholar
Yang, Moon-soo. 2010. Pukhan Kyŏngche-ŭi Sichanghwa: Yangt'ae, Sŏngkyŏk, Mek’Ŏnichŭm, Hamŭi (North Korea's Marketization: Shape, Nature, Mechanism, Implications). Seoul: Hanŭl.Google Scholar
Yang, Moon-soo, and Yun, In-ju. 2016. “Pukhan Kiŏbŭi Sasilsangŭi Sayuhwa—Sujun'Gwa Ch'Usee Kwanhan Chŏngyangjŏk Punsŏk” (De Facto Privatization of North Korean Enterprises: A Quantitative Approach on Level and Trend). Tongilyŏngu (20): 4588.Google Scholar
Yun, Gyeong-eun. 2018. Pukhan “8wŏl3irinminsobip'um”saengsanundong Yŏn'gu” (A Study on “August 3 People's Consumer goods” Production Movement of North Korea). Masters diss., University of North Korean Studies.Google Scholar
Yun, In-joo. 2013. “Pukhanŭi Sayuhwa Hyŏnsang Mit Tongage Kwanhan Yŏn'gu : Sijangŭl Maegaero Han Sajŏk Pumunŭi Hwakchangŭl Chungsimŭro” (A Study on the Privatization in North Korea and its Development: Focusing On The Expansion of the Private Sector through Marketization). PhD diss., Korea University.Google Scholar
Figure 0

TABLE 1 North Korea's motorized fishing fleet in 1988

Figure 1

FIGURE 1 (a) North Korean Exports (2001–2019) and (b) North Korean fisheries exports as a percentage of the total (2001–2019)

Figure 2

FIGURE 2 The North Korean fishing industry supply chainData from: Authors' reconstruction from interviews and official sources

Figure 3

FIGURE 3 The North Korean Foreign Trade Company System and the fishing industryData from: Kim Jic-soo (2013) with additions and revisions

Figure 4

FIGURE 4 Boat Registration Schemes within North Korean state entitiesData from: Authors' reconstruction from interviews and official sources