Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7fkt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T01:50:08.774Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Private Valuation of a Public Good in Three Auction Mechanisms

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 January 2015

Arnaud Z. Dragicevic
Affiliation:
Center for Interuniversity Research and Analysis on Organizations (CIRANO)
David Ettinger
Affiliation:
Paris-Dauphine University (LEDa, CEREMADE)
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

We evaluate the impact of three auction mechanisms—the Becker-DeGroot-Marschak (BDM) mechanism, the second-price auction (SPA), and the random nth-price auction (NPA)—in the measurement of private willingness-to-pay and willingness-to-accept for a pure public good. Our results show that the endowment effect is lower with the BDM mechanism. In this market mechanism, the effect disappears after a few repetitions. Yet, on a logarithmic scale, the random nth-price auction yields the highest speed of convergence towards equality of welfare indices. We also observe that subjects value public goods in reference to their private subjective benefit derived from their public funding.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis 2011

References

Andreoni, J., 1988. Why free-ride? Strategies and Learning in Public Goods Experiments. Journal of Public Economics 37, 291304.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J., 1990. Impure Altruism and Donations to Public Goods: A Theory of Warm-Glow Giving? Economic Journal 100, 464477.Google Scholar
Bateman, I., Carson, R., Day, B., Hanemann, M., Hanley, N., Hett, T., Jones-Lee, M., Loomes, G., Mourato, S., Ozdemiroglu, E., Pearce, D., Sugden, R., and Swanson, J. (eds.), 2002. Economic Valuation with Stated Preference Techniques: A Manual. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G., DeGroot, M. and Marschak, J., 1964. Measuring Utility by a Single Response Sequential Method. Behavioral Science 9, 226232.Google Scholar
Bohm, P., 1972. Estimating Demand for Public Goods: An Experiment. European Economic Review 3, 111–30.Google Scholar
Bohm, P., Linden, J. and Sonnegard, J., 1997. Eliciting Reservation Prices, Becker–DeGroot–Marschak Mechanisms vs. Markets. Economic Journal 107, 10791089.Google Scholar
Brookshire, D. and Coursey, D., 1987. Measuring the Value of a Public Good: An Empirical Comparison of Elicitation Procedures. American Economic Review 77, 554566.Google Scholar
Cherry, T., Crocker, T. and Shogren, J., 2003. Rationality Spillovers. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 45, 6384.Google Scholar
Clark, J., 2002. House Money Effects in Public Good Experiments. Experimental Economics 5, 223231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R., 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3, 144.Google Scholar
Coppinger, V., Smith, V. and Titus, J., 1980. Incentives and Behavior in English, Dutch and Sealed-Bid Auctions. Economic Inquiry 18, 122.Google Scholar
Dragicevic, A., 2009. Market Mechanisms and Valuation of Environmental Public Goods. Ph.D Thesis, École Polytechnique ParisTech, Paris, 160 pages.Google Scholar
Gode, D. and Sunder, S., 1993. Allocative Efficiency of Markets with Zero-Intelligence Traders: Market as a Partial Substitute for Individual Rationality. Journal of Political Economy 101, 119137.Google Scholar
Hanemann, W., 1991. Willingness to Pay and Willingness to Accept: How Much Can They Differ? American Economic Review 81, 635647.Google Scholar
Hoffman, E., Menkhaus, D., Chakravarti, D., Field, R. and Whipple, G., 1993. Using Laboratory Experimental Auctions in Marketing Research: A Case Study of New Packaging for Fresh Beef. Marketing Science 12, 318338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horowitz, J., 2006 a. What Do We Know About the Performance of the Becker-DeGroot-Marschak Mechanism. Available at http://faculty.arec.umd.edu/jhorowitz/BDM-Empirics-1.doc.Google Scholar
Horowitz, J., 2006 b. The Becker–DeGroot–Marschak Mechanism Is Not Necessarily Incentive Compatible, Even for Non-Random Goods. Economics Letters 93, 611.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. and Thaler, R., 1990. Experimental Test of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem. Journal of Political Economy 98, 13251348.Google Scholar
Kagel, J., Harstad, R. and Levin, D., 1987. Information Impact and Allocation Rules in Auctions with Affiliated Private Values: A Laboratory Study. Econometrica 55, 12751304.Google Scholar
List, J., 2003 a. Does Market Experience Eliminate Market Anomalies? Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 4171.Google Scholar
List, J., 2003 b. Using random nth-Price Auctions to value Non-Market Goods and Services. Journal of Regulatory Economics 23, 193205.Google Scholar
Lusk, J. and Rousu, M., 2006. Market Price Endogeneity and Accuracy of Value Elicitation Mechanisms, in List, J. (ed.), Using Experimental Methods in Environmental and Resource Economics, Northhampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Lusk, J., Alexander, C. and Rousu, M., 2007. Designing Experimental Auctions For Marketing Research: Effect Of Values, Distributions, And Mechanisms On Incentives For Truthful Bidding. Review of Marketing Science 5, 130.Google Scholar
McCabe, K., Rassenti, S. and Smith, V. 1990. Auction Institutional Design: Theory and Behavior of Simultaneous Multiple-Unit Generalizations of the Dutch and English Auctions. American Economic Review 80, 12761283.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. and Weber, R., 1982. A Theory of Auctions and Competitive Bidding. Econometrica 50, 10891122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2003), “Les Approches Volontaires dans les Politiques de l’Environnement”, OCDE, Paris.Google Scholar
Plott, C., 1996. Rational Individual Behavior in Markets and Social Choice Processes: The Discovered Preference Hypothesis, in Arrow, K., Colombatto, E., Perleman, M. and Schmidt, C., (eds.), Rational Foundations of Economic Behavior, Macmillan and St. Martins London.Google Scholar
Plott, C. and Zeiler, K., 2005. The Willingness to Pay/Willingness to Accept Gap, the Endowment Effect, Subject Misconceptions and Experimental Procedures for Eliciting Valuations. American Economic Review 95, 530545.Google Scholar
Randall, A. and Stoll, J., 1980. Consumer’s Surplus in Commodity Space. American Economic Review 71, 449457.Google Scholar
Rozan, A., Stenger, A. and Willinger, M., 2004. Willingness-to-Pay for Food Safety: An Experimental Investigation of Quality Certification on Bidding Behaviour. European Review of Agricultural Economics 31, 409425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shogren, J., Shin, S., Hayes, D. and Kliebenstein, J., 1994. Resolving Differences in Willingness to Pay and Willingness to Accept. American Economic Review 84, 255270.Google Scholar
Shogren, J., List, J. and Hayes, D., 2000. Preference Learning in Consecutive Experimental Auctions. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 83, 10161021.Google Scholar
Shogren, J., Cho, S., Koo, C., List, J., Park, C., Polo, P. and Wilhelmi, R., 2001. Auction Mechanisms and the Measurement of WTP and WTA. Resource and Energy Economics 23, 97109.Google Scholar
Sinclair-Desgagné, B., 2005. Calcul Économique et Développement Durable. Esprit critique, 07–N.01. Available at http://www.espritcritique.fr.Google Scholar
Smith, V., 1979. An Experimental Comparison of Three Public Good Decision Mechanisms. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 81, 198215.Google Scholar
Smith, V., 1991. Rational Choice: The Contrast between Economics and Psychology. Journal of Political Economy 99, 877897.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vickrey, W., 1961. Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders. Journal of Finance 16, 837.Google Scholar