Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-g7gxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-20T01:31:07.923Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

On the Distributional Implications of Safe Drinking Water Standards

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 March 2017

Dennis C. Cory*
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, The University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ, 85721, USA, e-mail: [email protected]
Lester D. Taylor
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, The University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ, 85721, USA, e-mail: [email protected]
*
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The provision of safe drinking water provides a dramatic example of the inherent complexity involved in incorporating environmental justice (EJ) considerations into the implementation and enforcement of new environmental standards. To promote substantive EJ, implementation policy must be concerned with the net risk reduction of new and revised regulations. The regulatory concern is that higher water bills for low-income customers of small public water systems may result in less disposable income for other health-related goods and services. In the net, this trade-off may be welfare decreasing, not increasing. Advocates of Health–Health Analysis have argued that the reduction in health-related spending creates a problem for traditional benefit-cost analysis since the long-run health implications of this reduction are not considered. The results of this investigation tend to support this contention. An evaluation of the internal structure of consumption expenditures reveals that low-expenditure households can be expected to react to an increase in the relative price of housing-related goods and services due to a water-rate hike by reducing both housing and health-related expenditures. That is, the representative low-expenditure household re-establishes equilibrium by not only decreasing housing-related spending, but also by decreasing spending on health-related expenditures in a modest but significant way. These results reflect the fact that expenditures on housing are a major proportion of overall household spending, and that accommodating drinking water surcharges exacerbates both health and food security concerns for low-expenditures households.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis 2017 

1 Introduction

The provision of safe drinking water provides a dramatic example of the inherent complexity involved in incorporating environmental justice (EJ) considerations into the implementation and enforcement of new environmental standards. The Safe Drinking Water Act (SDWA) requires the US Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) to set national standards that protect human health, and then requires public water systems (PWSs)Footnote 1 to meet these standards. More than 160,000 PWSs must implement these standards whether they supply drinking water to a few dozen taps or a few million.

Over the past decade, concerns over EJ have made the enforcement of environmental law, in general, and the selective enforcement of the SDWA, in particular, even more complex. EJ concerns may arise in one of two ways: (1) failure to enforce compliance with water quality standards may deny consumers the health benefits associated with less contaminated water,Footnote 2 or (2) forcing compliance may secure health benefits but at prohibitive cost.Footnote 3 The extent to which EJ considerations further complicate SDWA enforcement depends directly on the extent to which minority and/or low-income populations are disproportionately served by PWSs struggling to comply with new water quality standards.

Paradoxically, the decision to enforce compliance with a new drinking water standard may actually increase water rates significantly while lowering net health benefits for some low-income households. That is, from a public health perspective, the decision to enforce a new or revised drinking water standard may be counterproductive for some EJ communities. A substantial body of research has concluded that lower incomes are associated with higher mortality risks:

[ $\ldots$ ] the mortality rate for individuals with higher incomes is less than that for individuals with lower incomes. Reasons for this relationship relate to, among other things, better nutrition, better sanitation, better health care, better education, and better socioeconomic status – all items that are easier to come by with money. This raises a key issue about whether the cost of a proposed regulation, which de facto reduces the disposable income of individuals available for other purposes, would increase mortality risks and therefore produce more premature deaths than those purported to be saved by the proposed legislation (Keeney, Reference Keeney1994, p. 95).

The regulatory concern is that higher water bills for low-income customers of small PWSs result in less disposable income for other goods and services like health care, food, energy, and other essential services. In the net, this trade-off may be welfare decreasing, not increasing. The regulatory challenge is summarized by Sunstein (Reference Sunstein2001):

If, for example, those who would bear $300 or more in increased annual costs are also disproportionately poor, there is good reason for government to hesitate before imposing the regulation. It is easy to imagine a situation in which water quality regulation is “regressive,” in the sense that its costs come down especially hard on poor people. Now that is not a decisive objection to the regulation, but it is certainly an important point to consider (Sunstein, Reference Sunstein2001, p. 49).

To promote substantive EJ implementation, policy must be concerned with the net risk reduction of the revised arsenic regulation. As Raucher et al. (Reference Raucher, Rubin, Crawford-Brown and Lawson2011, p. 9) point out: “If a regulation significantly decreases the disposable income of those affected by the regulation, it could wholly or partially offset the health benefits of the regulation itself.”Footnote 4 Increasing the cost of water service to a distressed household may increase the likelihood that the household will forego some other necessity, starting with health insurance, then dentist appointments, then doctor visits, then adequate nutrition, and finally to eviction or foreclosure on the home. Thus, the core EJ issue at the individual or household level is whether compliance costs of a drinking water rule outweigh the corresponding net health risk reduction benefit. To the extent that compliance costs can be made affordable, substantive EJ is promoted.

1.1 Organization of the paper

In the context of safe drinking water standards, the EJ question is straightforward: do more stringent drinking water standards result in negative net health benefits for low-income households? To assess this contention, it is first necessary to establish how drinking water surcharges impact the health-related expenditure decisions of low-income households. In the following sections, an empirical investigation of the consumption choices of low-income households is presented.

In Section 2, a review of the literature on the health trade-offs associated with reduced income is presented, as well as a discussion of the controversy over the need to incorporate trade-off considerations into conventional benefit-cost analysis. Section 3 describes the estimation techniques used in the case studies, techniques designed to evaluate the internal structure of U.S. consumption expenditures by income class. Section 4 presents the results for two case studies: (1) the health-expenditure trade-offs resulting from implementation of the recently revised drinking water standard for arsenic for the small community of Tubac, Arizona, which experienced compliance costs far exceeding EPA’s estimates, and (2) the expected health trade-offs resulting from the cumulative impact of drinking water regulations, including arsenic, over the 2006–2012 period. The empirical evidence provided by these case studies tends to support the contention that both health and food security concerns are exacerbated by drinking water surcharges.

2 Health–health analysis and standard setting

For many years there has been sustained interest in using direct measures of economic well-being to assess the welfare status of low-income households. Indicators have been developed over time to account for both monetary and nonmonetary elements of support, addressing such diverse items as the ability to pay bills, get needed health care, and food sufficiency.

An early study by Bauman (Reference Bauman1998) utilized data by the Census Bureau in the Survey on Income and Program Participation (SIPP) from a nationally representative sample to evaluate low-income household well-being. The intent of the study was to augment traditional poverty measures with “hardship” measures since official poverty measures fail to adequately account for a number of factors that are critical to household material well-being. The cost of work, health status, the cost of health care, and noncash government benefits are just a few examples of frequently neglected items. This analytical approach to poverty analysis argues that questionnaires designed to directly assess the degree to which families experience financial problems and budget shortfalls (i.e. experience hardship) are needed to address the central concern of poverty policy; namely, the degree to which families are able to meet their basic needs.

Three types of questions on material hardship are typically asked. These questions address a household’s ability to meet essential expenses such as rent, utility, and medical bills; the ability to see a doctor or dentist as needed; and the adequacy of food availability. Based on the Bauman (Reference Bauman1998) SIPP analysis, and similar hardship or financial distress studies, a hierarchy of household necessities can be constructed as shown in Figure 1 (Crawford-Brown et al., Reference Crawford-Brown, Raucher, Rubin and Lawson2009).

Figure 1 Hierarchy of household necessities. Sources: compiled by Raucher et al. (Reference Raucher, Rubin, Crawford-Brown and Lawson2011), based on Bauman (Reference Bauman1998, Reference Bauman1999), Energy CENTS Coalition (1999), and Boushey et al. (Reference Boushey, Gundersen, Brocht and Bernstein2001).

This empirically documented hierarchy lends some credibility to the concern that the cumulative impact of drinking water regulatory compliance costs may result in negative net health benefits for low-income households. Households that have trouble paying for all of their necessities will tend to do without health insurance first, followed by not seeing a dentist regularly, not being able to see a doctor as needed, and not getting enough to eat.Footnote 5

2.1 Health–health analysis

The research program of Health–Health Analysis (HHA) was initiated partly in response to financial distress studies and their documentation of the possible negative net health benefits of regulatory programs.Footnote 6 Keeney (Reference Keeney1994), one of the early developers of HHA, states the motivating research agenda in stark terms: the cost of regulations is passed on to individuals; regulators, legislators, lawyers, and judges that neglect the implications of regulatory costs on fatalities will likely support policies leading to unnecessary and preventable deaths (Keeney, pp. 108–109). More formally, HHA postulates a systematic relationship between people’s wealth and their health, measured, for example, by risks of mortality and morbidity and by general life expectancy. Compliance with costly regulations affects the consumption of risk-reducing goods and services in the same way as a wealth decline. Spending on compliance necessarily reduces the resources that may be spent on all other goods and services. The effective size of the pie being smaller, less of it is put to the purchase of health and safety. HHA seeks to quantify the expected declines in health and safety that may be ascribed to the costs of complying with a regulation.Footnote 7 It then compares these outcomes to the direct improvements in health and safety attributable to the regulation to test whether a government policy may be expected to generate positive net health benefits (Lutter & Morrall, Reference Lutter and Morrall III1994).Footnote 8

HHA is an explicit distributive equity or EJ test of a proposed regulation. Currently the EPA determines drinking water standards primarily based on allocative efficiency, not distributive equity. Allocative efficiency requires that the degree of contaminant abatement maximize the net benefits of control. A drinking water regulation constitutes a Potential Pareto Improvement (PPI) if the marginal benefits of its implementation exceed the marginal costs. In other words, a proposed standard would pass the PPI allocative efficiency test if the change in net benefits resulting from a movement from the status quo to the new standard is positive. The underlying normative proposition for adopting the PPI allocative efficiency criteria is that society should reject policies that generate more in costs than in benefits.

HHA, on the other hand, addresses an entirely different concern. Low-income households in small community water systems (CWSs) may be forced to forego other health services to finance rising water bills. Net health benefits for this group could be negative.Footnote 9 If so, should the proposed drinking water standard be abandoned, adjusted, or left unchanged? Viewed in this light, it is clear that the HHA criterion of positive health net benefits for low-income households is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition for a policy proposal to constitute a PPI. A proposed drinking water standard could pass the PPI criterion and fail the HHA criterion, or pass the HHA criterion and fail the PPI criterion. The PPI allocative criterion attempts to channel scarce resources only into policies that generate more in benefits than costs while the equity HHA criterion attempts to highlight the EJ or distributive equity implications of adopting a proposed standard for low-income households.

2.2 The standard setting debate

The standard setting process conducted by the EPA for the treatment of drinking water contaminants is quite controversial. The idea of having enforceable, health-based drinking water standards is well accepted, but the underlying benefit-cost considerations that accompany the development of new standards are frequently the subject of intense debate. The revised arsenic standard is no exception in this regard. Following a detailed and protracted assessment process, a final rule was issued by EPA that established an enforceable arsenic maximum contaminant level (MCL) of 10 ppb for all CWSs and nontransient, noncommunity (NTNC) water systems. The effective date for the new standard of 10 ppb was February 22, 2002, and all water systems subject to the final rule were compelled to comply by January 23, 2006.

Both EPA benefit and cost estimates for the arsenic rule were sharply criticized.Footnote 10 Attacks ranged from faulty science and misinterpretation of key economic data to political agendas.Footnote 11 In part, the contentious reaction to the proposed rule was due to EPA’s own admission that the final rule does not pass a quantified benefit-cost test (i.e., benefits greater than costs). Even for the alternative MCL scenario of 20 ppb, where compliance costs are lowest, and using the upper bound estimate for benefits, expected net benefits were still negative. For the MCL scenario of 10 ppb, at which the standard was promulgated, estimated net benefits range from $-$ $66 million to $-$ $7.9 million dollars per year (in 1999 dollars).Footnote 12 However, the EPA argued that there were substantial “nonquantifiable” benefits of arsenic reduction that would make actual benefits exceed costs at the 10 ppb MCL,Footnote 13 hence EPA’s decision to finalize the proposal of a new arsenic standard of 10 ppb. Because of estimation uncertainties, it is ambiguous at best as to whether the adoption and implementation of the revised arsenic standard would constitute a Potential Pareto Improvement.

Given the controversial nature of the revised arsenic standard, HHA plays a pivotal role in both standard setting and implementation. If the aggregate net benefits of the revised standard are marginal at best, and the net health benefits for small PWSs are negative, then the new standard could be rejected on strict efficiency grounds alone. If not, then negative net health benefits for small PWSs would still argue for possible relaxation of the arsenic standard for these small companies on efficiency grounds, or the implementation of ancillary programs designed to mitigate the cost impact on these systems.Footnote 14

3 Estimation of the health–health implications of the revised arsenic rule for drinking water

For HHA analysis to be relevant to setting and implementing drinking water standards, low-income households in small PWCs would have to forego important health services in response to rising drinking water bills. This proposition can be assessed by using data collected by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) to evaluate the internal structure of U.S. consumption expenditures (Taylor, Reference Taylor2013).Footnote 15 The estimation challenge is to determine how health expenditures respond to increasing water expenditures that result from rising compliance costs. If health expenditures fall significantly in response to rising drinking water expenditures, then HHA is vindicated as a policy-relevant check on drinking water regulation, otherwise not.

In Taylor (Reference Taylor2013),Footnote 16 a framework was developed that can be used to estimate the impact on a household’s expenditure decisions in different categories of consumption arising from increases in the cost of water. A short discussion of this framework is as follows:

Ordinarily when information in a household budget survey is considered, it is in terms of expenditures for different goods and services and how these relate to income, prices, and socio-demographic factors such as age, family size, and education. Allocation of expenditures amongst different categories of consumption is seen as being determined by tastes and preferences acting in conjunction with a constraint imposed by prices and income. The parameters thus obtained are obviously useful in analyzing the impact on consumption resulting from changes in income and prices (should the latter be available), but income and price elasticities, in themselves, say little about the internal structure of consumption spending. How expenditures for housing, transportation, and personal care – to pick three standard categories of consumption spending – are related to expenditures for water, for example, are, in general, not the direct focus of empirical study.

Table 1 BLS consumption expenditure categories.

Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, available at http://www.bls.gov/cex/csxgloss.htm.

For the framework developed in Internal Structure, an approach to the analysis of household consumption behavior is postulated in which direct relationships amongst different categories of consumption become both the focus and engine of analysis. For an exhaustive set of expenditure categories (see Table 1), expenditures in a category are related, in turn, in a sequence of regression equations, to expenditures in each of the other categories. In Internal Structure, this was done for 14 categories of expenditure for each of 40 quarters of data (1996 through 2005) from the ongoing BLS Survey of Consumer Expenditures. Mean values from the 40 sets of estimates are then taken as input for a matrix of “intrabudget” coefficients, seen as representing the conjunctive effects on household expenditures of household tastes and preferences together with the constraints imposed by prices and income. The matrix of intrabudget coefficients thus obtained can be used in a variety of ways to estimate what, in effect, are general-equilibrium consequences on all categories of consumption that arise from increases or decreases in expenditures in a particular category or from reallocation of expenditures from one category of consumption to another.Footnote 17 $^{,}$ Footnote 18

In the BLS quarterly consumer expenditure surveys, water is included in expenditures for housing. To evaluate the expenditure implications of drinking water surcharges, expenditures for water have been removed from overall housing expenditures and treated as a separate expenditure category.Footnote 19 $^{\text{ }}$ Moreover, since the focus in the estimation is on low-income households, food expenditures have been separated into food consumed at home and food consumed outside the home. Expenditures for gasoline and oil are separated from transportation as well. The result, accordingly, is a set of 17 categories of expenditure in the analysis to follow.

Let $y_{\text{1}},\ldots ,y_{17}$ denote the exhaustive 17-category breakdown of expenditures just mentioned, and let

(1) $$\begin{eqnarray}y_{i}=\unicode[STIX]{x1D6FC}_{i}+\mathop{\sum }_{j\neq i}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6FD}_{ji}y_{j}+u_{i}\quad i,j=1,\ldots ,17,\end{eqnarray}$$

represent the least-squares regression equation of expenditures in the $i$ th category on expenditures in the other 16 categories. Equation (1) has been estimated for each of the 17 categories for each of 28 BLS Quarterly Consumer Expenditure Surveys from 2006Q1 through 2012Q4. For illustration, the estimated coefficients from the 17 regression equations for 2012Q4 for households for which water is not included in rent are tabulated in Table 2.Footnote 20 Mean values of the resulting 28 vectors of coefficients are given in Table 3.Footnote 21

Next, let $y=(y_{1},\ldots ,y_{17})$ denote a (column) vector of expenditures and let B be the $17\times 18$ matrix:

(2) $$\begin{eqnarray}B=[z,A],\end{eqnarray}$$

where $z$ denotes the (column) vector of intercepts from the last row in Table 3 and A denotes the transpose of the $17\times 17$ submatrix of “intrabudget” coefficients from the table. Hence:

(3) $$\begin{eqnarray}y=z+Ay,\end{eqnarray}$$

or

(4) $$\begin{eqnarray}[I-A]y=z,\end{eqnarray}$$

so that

(5) $$\begin{eqnarray}y=[I-A]^{-1}z.\end{eqnarray}$$

Expressions (3) and (5) are referred to as the structural and reduced-form representations of the model, respectively. Both representations are used extensively in the exercises in Chapters 4 and 5 of Internal Structure, depending upon whether expenditures are assumed to be exogenous or endogenous. “Exogenous” in this context refers to a change in $z$ , while “endogenous” refers to a change in y. However, since only exogenous changes are the focus in the present analysis, details regarding endogenous changes need not be gone into. Footnote 22 Results for the estimations reported in the text (for households for which water is not included in rent) are measured against a “base” vector of expenditures that is obtained from Equation (5) using intercepts from the last row in Table 3 for $z$ . Additional details on computing own- and cross-price elasticities in this estimation framework are presented in Appendix A.

Table 2 Intra-budget regressions. 17 categories of U.S. consumption expenditure, 2012 Q4, bottom quintile (855 observations).

Table 3 Means of intra-budget expenditures regression coefficients. 17 categories of U.S. consumption expenditure, bottom quintile, 2006 Q1–2012 Q4.

4 Net health impacts of the revised arsenic standard

In March of 2002, the EPA presented its report to Congress on small system arsenic implementation issues (U.S. EPA, 2002). Congress directed the EPA to review the agency’s affordability criteria for small PWS compliance. In responding, the EPA made it clear that the agency shared congressional concerns regarding small system compliance with drinking water regulations, in general, and with the recently promulgated arsenic rule, in particular.

In their economic analysis of the arsenic drinking water rule, EPA explicitly addressed the affordability issue by estimating compliance costs per household by system size (U.S. EPA 2000). The results of this analysis are presented in Table 4. The potential magnitude of the affordability concerns is well illustrated by these estimates. While all PWS customers would receive health benefits from reducing arsenic concentrations in drinking water to 10 ppb, household compliance costs for small systems with fewer than 3,300 customers can be anywhere from 1.8 to over 10 times more expensive compared to the weighted average across all system size categories.

Table 4 Mean annual costs per household of the arsenic MCL (10 ppb).

Notes: ppb $=$ parts per billion; Sources: U.S. EPA (2000, pp. 6–35).

The EPA made a variety of assistance programs available to small PWSs struggling to comply with the revised arsenic standard. These efforts constituted an extensive and consequential set of programs specifically designed to ease the burden on small PWSs trying to comply with the new water quality standard. Despite these efforts, compliance remained a complex and problematic undertaking for many small PWSs, as the experience of the small community of Tubac, Arizona illustrates.Footnote 23

4.1 The Tubac experience

Tubac is a census-designated place (CDP) located on the Santa Cruz River, approximately 45 miles south of Tucson, Arizona.Footnote 24 As of the 2010 Census, there were 1,183 individuals and 527 households residing in the CDP.Footnote 25 In total, the population of Tubac increased 25.5% between 2000 and 2010. The median age was 50 years with 22.3% of the residents over the age of 65. Residents who self-identified as having Hispanic ethnicity increased 42.2% from 2000 to 2010 and constituted 48.4% of the CDP population. Median household income in Tubac was $51,964 compared to $54,637 in Arizona and $55,970 in the U.S. However, due to 28.8% of the CDP households making more than $100,000 per year, per capita household income was $40,372 in Tubac compared to $26,996 in Arizona and $28,779 in the U.S. Importantly, nearly 1 in 4 households (23.5%) in Tubac have an annual income below $25,000, and 15.2% have incomes below $15,000 per year. Unemployment in the CDP was nearly 18% in 2010 with negative recent job growth.Footnote 26

The principal provider of drinking water in the Tubac CDP at the time of implementing the revised arsenic standard was the Arizona American Water Company (AAW). AAW was a large, technically sophisticated company providing water to over 300,000 customers in Arizona, and operating as a regulated utility in 20 states, serving over 15 million people across 30 states and parts of Canada.Footnote 27 In 2005, AAW had 532 customers in Tubac. After ruling out point-of-use and point-of-entry (POU/POE) treatment technologies as cost ineffective compared to centralized treatment, AAW then designed an arsenic treatment plant (ATP). Significant levels of treatment were required. The three groundwater wells servicing Tubac contained an average arsenic concentration of 25 ug/L, ranging from a low of 16 to a high of 36, making simple blending of water sources infeasible. To help defray ATP costs, AAW partnered with Tubac Marketplace, a small commercial development in the city, saving approximately $1 million in siting, storage, and pumping capacity expenditures. In the final design, one of the three wells was put out of service. The remaining two wells were then connected by a 4,900 ft. pipe of 12-inch diameter to the treatment plant itself. The plant was then able to treat arsenic to the safe levels prescribed by law (approximately 5 ug/L) and was capable of delivering 500 gallons per minute to customers. Additional storage of 500,000 gallons of water was also constructed.

Total cost of the plant was estimated to be $2.3 million, requiring a customer rate increase of approximately $78 per month. This rate increase was in addition to the 17% increase requested by AAW to cover other infrastructure investment and increased operating expenses incurred between 2001 and 2005. The net impact for Tubac water customers would be expending approximately 2.2% of the median Tubac level of income on drinking water, four times the U.S. average (Vandervoet, Reference Vandervoet2008, Reference Vandervoet2009).

Table 5 Effects of a $234 quarterly increase in expenditures for water in the bottom quintile of total expenditure. (Total expenditure held constant).

Did compliance costs of $234 per quarter (costs that were approximately six times the expense estimated by the EPA) cause low-income households using AAW drinking water to jeopardize their health by foregoing needed health services? The estimated change in expenditure patterns is shown in Table 5 for both low-expenditure households who paid water bills directly and for households who pay through higher rents, holding total expenditure constant. Following the procedures detailed in Equations (1) through (5), expenditures for a representative household in both groups over the 2006–2012 period were estimated. For this scenario involving a $234 quarterly increase in the price of water for households falling in the bottom quintile of the distribution of total expenditure, the relevant intrabudget coefficient matrix is the one from Table 3. A $234 increase in the price of water is recorded, initially, as an exogenous addition of that amount to what the typical household in the bottom quintile spends on water, assuming no change in its total expenditure, which is to say that the intercept for water in Table 3 is increased from $115.90 to $349.90 ($115.90  $+$  $234). The other intercepts are all unchanged, as is the total expenditure of $4,393 per quarter for the water-bill surcharge group and the $3,053 per quarter for the rent surcharge group. Expression (5) is then solved for this “new” value of $z$ , resulting in a new vector of expenditures, say, y*, and a new implied level of total expenditure of $4762. The original budget constraint of $4393 is then imposed by multiplying y* by 0.92 (4383/4762), with results as shown in Table 5.Footnote 28

For discussion purposes, BLS categories of expenditures have been aggregated into five classes: spending on housing with water expenditures broken out; spending on food; nine categories of discretionary spending; three categories of security spending related to physical and financial well-being; and miscellaneous spending. Expenditure estimates are presented in four columns. The “base” column of Table 5 reports expenditures for a representative household in the bottom quintile before the rate increase. The next column shows how expenditures for this household were adjusted in response to the $234 increase in Tubac water bills. The last two columns present the corresponding category and class changes in spending, respectively.

Table 6 Effects of a $348 quarterly increase in expenditures for water in the bottom quintile of total expenditure (total expenditure held constant).

* Constrained to be nonnegative.

4.1.1 Surcharge added to water-bill households

For the representative household in this group, total annual expenditures are $17,572, corresponding to about the 15th percentile of expenditures for U.S. households. Housing expenditures are decreased by $46.09, accommodating 19.7% of the $234 surcharge.Footnote 29 Spending on water amounts to $350.81. If the representative household failed to adjust their water consumption behavior in response to the surcharge, total spending on water would be $374.95 (base of $140.95 plus surcharge of $234.00). The savings due to water conservation amounts to $24.14 or approximately 10.3% of the $234 surcharge.Footnote 30 Food spending actually increases by $37.41 per quarter or $12.47 per month. While this adjustment is de minimis, it does illustrate that food security concerns are not exacerbated for this group. Approximately half of the water surcharge is accommodated by a net reduction in discretionary spending of $118.03. Nearly one third of the $234 surcharge is accommodated through a $77.32 reduction in security spending, with health spending reductions alone accounted for 12.4%. In percentage terms, this adjustment is striking since security spending only accounts for 15.9% of the original base budget. Finally, reductions in miscellaneous spending amounts to $6.05 or 2.6% of the water surcharge.

4.1.2 Surcharge added to rent group

For the representative household in this group, total annual expenditures are only $12,212.Footnote 31 Housing expenditures increased by $152.31 for this group of households in response to the $234 surcharge. If there were no change in housing-expenditure behavior, the new level of spending on housing would be $1,288.04. The difference of $81.69 (i.e., $1,288.04–$1,206.35) amounts to 34.9% of the water surcharge. Discretionary spending cuts again play an important role in adjusting to the increased rent. The reduction of $63.60 amounts to 27.2% of the water surcharge. Both food and health security concerns are exacerbated for this rental group of households. Food expenditures are reduced by $57.72, security expenditures are cut by $29.90, and spending on health goods and services are lowered by $10.88. These reductions account for 24.7%, 12.8%, and 4.6% of the $234 rent hike attributable to the water surcharge. Finally, cuts in miscellaneous spending are negligible.Footnote 32

4.1.3 Summing up

The $234 water surcharge is assumed to be passed on to customers either directly in their water bill or indirectly through higher rents. The expenditure implications for the two types of household differ in significant ways. Water conservation accommodates approximately 10% of the surcharge for water-bill households. Water conservation is ineffective for the rental group since reductions in water usage are unlikely to be reflected in future rents. Food security concerns are exacerbated for the rental group and unaffected for the water-bill group. Security spending reductions accommodate nearly 1/3 of the water surcharge for water-bill households, but only 12.8% for rental households. Health security concerns are impacted for both groups, but again the expenditure implications for the rental group are less in both absolute and percentage terms.

4.2 Secular impacts of safe drinking water standards

The implementation of a single MCL for drinking water may result in low-income households jeopardizing their overall health by reducing expenditures for other essential health-related goods and services. The central EJ policy concern in the context of providing safe drinking water, however, is that promulgation of new or revised MCLs over time may result in a regressive pattern of distributing benefits and costs. That is, SDWA programs may tend to promote the interests of higher income groups more than those of the poor. Yet given the substantial health and longevity benefits of safe drinking water, it is clear that the interests of society, including those of the poor, may justify substantial SDWA investment.

Implementing future MCLs for drinking water in a manner that promotes substantive EJ for low-income customers of small PWSs will continue to be a daunting proposition. The national primary drinking water regulations (NPSWR) promulgated by the EPA are legally enforceable standards that apply to all PWSs. These regulations limit drinking water contamination from organic chemicals, radionuclides, inorganic chemicals, microorganisms, disinfectants, and disinfection by-products. In 2011, the EPA was monitoring over 200 drinking water standards, compared to 19 MCLs in 1975 (U.S. EPA, 2011). Not surprising, the consumer price index (CPI) for water and sewer has surpassed the CPI for all items for the past 15 years, as illustrated in Figure 2.Footnote 33 Meanwhile poverty in the U.S. has remained an intractable problem. Census figures released in September 2013 confirmed that record-high numbers of households are living in poverty.Footnote 34 In 2012, 46.5 million people (one out of seven) were living in poverty in the U.S., the largest number in the 54 years the census has measured poverty. Almost one out of sixteen people in the U.S. (6.6% of the population) were living in deep poverty with incomes 50% below the poverty line. Racial and ethnic minorities were particularly vulnerable to poverty and deep poverty. Coupling ever-increasing drinking water regulationsFootnote 35 with a large and increasing resident population living in poverty dramatically illustrates the substantive EJ challenges facing the EPA in coming years.Footnote 36

To estimate the likely change in expenditure patterns for a representative low-income household in response to the cumulative impact of more stringent drinking water standards, the combined effects of the actual increase for arsenic abatement ($234) and an increase of $114 resulting from an increase in the CPI for water relative to the ALL items CPI for Urban Consumers of 44.7% over the 10 years 2004–2013 (December–December) has also been evaluated. The results for the combined $348 quarterly increase in expenditures for water by households in the bottom quintile of total expenditures are presented in Table 6.

Figure 2 U.S. Water Rate Increases. Source: US department of labor, bureau of statistics, consumer price index. Available at http://www.bls.gov/cpi/

4.2.1 Surcharge added to water-bill group

The financial stress of secular water-rate increases, coupled with stagnant growth in real income, forces households in the bottom quintile to intensify water conservation measures. Of the $348 total increase, $47.23 (i.e., a surcharge of $348 minus a category change of $300.77) is accommodated by water conservation measures, with an additional adjustment of $66.03 in other housing-related goods and services made as well. Taken as a whole, spending reductions in housing expenditures accommodates 32.5% of the surcharge (see Table 6). Food expenditures actually increased for this group by $53.62 so that food security issues remain unaffected. Discretionary spending plays a dominant role in accommodating the impact of the water surcharge. By reducing spending by $168.66 in this class, most of the increase in water and food expenditures can be incorporated into the household budget. Security spending reductions again play a disproportionate role in reacting to the imposition of this water surcharge. A spending reduction of $110.82 amounts to 31.8% of the surcharge while security spending accounts for only 15.9% of the original base expenditure budget. Finally, health-related expenditures fall by $41.69, or 12% of the surcharge.

4.2.2 Surcharge added to rent group

For these extremely low-expenditure households, rents cannot be lowered through water conservation since they do not receive a water bill directly. On the other hand, the $348 rent increase attributable to the per-household surcharge can be partially accommodated through reductions in housing spending generally. Under this scenario, housing expenditures are estimated to increase by $218.53 (see Table 6). If housing-expenditure behavior remained unchanged, total housing spending would have risen by $348. The difference of $239.47 accounts for 37.2% of the rent hike. Food security concerns for this low-income group are exacerbated by the rent increase. The reduction of $82.82 in food spending accommodates roughly 23.8% of the rent increase. Discretionary spending reductions accommodates 26.1% of the surcharge while security expenditure cuts account for an additional $42.91 or approximately 12.3% of the surcharge. Focusing on health-related expenditures directly, the reduction of $15.61 accommodates 4.9% of the surcharge by itself.

Table 7 Expenditure accommodations for quarterly water surcharges in the bottom quintile of total expenditure (total expenditure held constant).

4.3 Summing up

A comparison of the two simulations, one estimating the impact of the revised arsenic standard in isolation, and the other evaluating the expenditure implications of rising real drinking water costs over the decade ending in 2013, is presented in Table 7. On average, the results support three general conclusions. First, about one third of drinking water surcharges are financed through reductions in food expenditures for extremely low-expenditure households (i.e., total annual expenditures of $12,212 annually) while there are no reductions in food expenditures for low-expenditure households (i.e., total annual expenditures of $17,572 annually) in response to the imposition of water surcharges. Second, about 12% of drinking water surcharges are accommodated by reductions in health-related goods and services in low-expenditure household while only 5% of the surcharge is accounted for by reductions in health expenditures in the extremely low-expenditure group. Third, reductions in security spending generally play a disproportionate role in adjusting to surcharges in low-expenditure households, accounting for nearly one third of the surcharge accommodation but only amounting to 16% of the original budget. For extremely low-expenditure households, only 5% of the surcharge is accommodated by reductions in health-related goods and services.

5 Conclusions

Advocates of HHA maintain that surcharges for improved drinking water will result in reductions in other health and food-related expenditures. In the net, enforcing drinking water standards may result in negative net health benefits for low-income households in small PWSs. The results of this evaluation of the internal structure of U.S. consumption expenditures lend empirical support to the contention that as real drinking water costs rise, health and food expenditures fall, assuming stagnant real income.

While the HHA proposition that policies intended to protect human health ought to result in positive net health benefits seems unassailable, the use of HHA in environmental standard setting has been controversial. In fact, Portney and Stavins (Reference Portney and Stavins1994) argue that in most applications the ancillary health impacts of regulatory compliance costs are unlikely to be significant. As a result, conventional benefit-cost (PPI) analysis should remain the principal tool of economic assessment for environmental laws and regulations. In general, slight real income losses are not likely to translate into aggregate health impacts of significance. Moreover, higher incomes and jobs created by regulation tend to translate into offsetting life-saving benefits.

The Portney–Stavins critique of HHA seems particularly valid when compliance costs are highly dispersed and low on a per-household basis. For drinking water regulations, however, the same households that benefit from the regulation typically bear the full compliance cost. In this context, Raucher et al. (Reference Raucher, Rubin, Crawford-Brown and Lawson2011) argue that negative health impacts arising from regulatory costs may appreciably offset the risk reduction of the drinking water regulation itself. That is, increasing the cost of water service to a distressed household will increase the likelihood that the household will forego some other health-related necessity. In the case of arsenic, the authors estimated that cost-associated health risks may be within the same order of magnitude as the EPA-estimated arsenic risk reduction for customers of small PWSs.Footnote 37

Based on the results presented here, security spending may be reduced by as much as 33% of any surcharge that must be imposed to comply with stricter water standards for customers in small systems, health expenditures by as much as 12%, and food expenditures by as much as 34%. Looking ahead, the net health impact of these accommodations will be determined by a complex set of factors including the effectiveness of EPA programs designed to minimize the surcharge impact on low-income households in small PWSs ,Footnote 38 and the funding and effectiveness of safety-net programs designed to ameliorate health and food security concerns.Footnote 39

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank Scott Rubin, Timothy Tardiff, two anonymous referees, and participants in the Environmental Law and Economics conference in Groningen in May 2015 for helpful comments.

Appendix A. Calculation of own- and cross-price elasticities of demand

Absent direct information on prices, it is not possible (short of heroic assumptions about the structure of preferences) to estimate price elasticities from household surveys of consumer expenditures in a framework of conventional demand analysis. Surprisingly, however, this is possible in the present framework, for both own- and cross-price elasticities can be obtained through simulation. The key for doing so is to note that changes in prices can be incorporated into the analysis through the “intercept” vector $z$ in equation (5). Equation (5) is solved for two different values of $z$ , the first to establish a baseline set of expenditures and a second to reflect the assumed change (or changes) in price. The resulting price effects are then represented by the differences between the two solution vectors $y$ .

The procedure involved, using the entries in Table 1 of the text as parameters, will be illustrated for an assumed 10 percent increase in the price of food consumed at home.Footnote 40 The results are tabulated in Table A1. To begin with, baseline expenditures are obtained from equation (5) using the “intercepts” from the last row in Table 2 of the text for $z$ , that is, a value of $705 for food home $132 for food away for alcoholic beverages, etc. These are given in the first column of Table A1. The total expenditure implied by this value for $z$ is $4393.Footnote 41 Note that the base expenditure for food is $761. An increase in the price of food of 10 percent is represented as a 10 percent increase in this base expenditure, that is, an increase of $76. The intercept for food in $z$ ($706) is replaced by $782 ($706 $+$ $76). All other elements of $z$ remain the same. Call this new value of $z$ , $z^{\ast }$ . Equation (5) is then solved for $z^{\ast }$ , with total expenditure held constant, with results as in columns 4 and 5 of the Table A1. Expenditures are seen to increase $67.22 for food at home, decrease $31.91 for housing, and so on and so forth. Table A1 also includes results for a 5 percent increase in the price of food.

Table A1 Own- & cross-price elasticities. For a 5 & 10 percent increase in price of food (total expenditure held constant).

Formally, own- and cross-price elasticities in the present framework are obtained as follows. In an obvious notation, the total-expenditure budget constraint will be given by

(A1) $$\begin{eqnarray}\mathop{\sum }_{i=1}^{n}p_{i}q_{i}=y.\end{eqnarray}$$

Hence, for a change of $\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}p_{i}$ in the price of $q_{i}$ , with total expenditure $y$ held constant, we will have:

(A2) $$\begin{eqnarray}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}(p_{i}q_{i})+\mathop{\sum }_{j\neq i}p_{j}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}q_{j}=0.\end{eqnarray}$$

Then:

(A3) $$\begin{eqnarray}\frac{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}(p_{i}q_{i})}{p_{i}q_{i}}+\mathop{\sum }_{j\neq i}\frac{p_{j}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}q_{j}}{p_{i}q_{i}}=0.\end{eqnarray}$$

Consequently, in elasticities:

(A4) $$\begin{eqnarray}\frac{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}(p_{i}q_{i})}{p_{i}q_{i}}\bigg/\frac{q_{i}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}p_{i}}{p_{i}q_{i}}+\mathop{\sum }_{j\neq i}\left(\left(\frac{p_{j}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}q_{j}}{p_{j}q_{j}}\bigg/\frac{q_{i}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}p_{i}}{p_{i}q_{i}}\right)\left(\frac{p_{j}q_{j}}{p_{i}q_{i}}\right)\right)=0.\end{eqnarray}$$

Since all of the quantities in this expression (A5) are observable, cross-price elasticities will therefore be given by

(A5) $$\begin{eqnarray}\unicode[STIX]{x1D702}_{ji}=\frac{p_{j}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}q_{j}}{p_{j}q_{j}}\bigg/\frac{q_{i}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}p_{i}}{p_{i}q_{i}}\end{eqnarray}$$

and the own-price elasticity byFootnote 42

(A6) $$\begin{eqnarray}\unicode[STIX]{x1D702}_{ii}=\frac{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}(p_{i}q_{i})}{q_{i}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}p_{i}}-1.\end{eqnarray}$$

Thus, for a 10 percent increase for the price of food, the own-price elasticity for food [from expression (A6)] will be given by

(A7) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle \unicode[STIX]{x1D702}_{11} & = & \displaystyle \frac{67.22-76.07}{76.07}\nonumber\\ \displaystyle & = & \displaystyle -0.12,\end{eqnarray}$$

while the cross-elasticity for housing (say) [from expression (A5)] will be given by

(A8) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle \unicode[STIX]{x1D702}_{31} & = & \displaystyle \frac{-31.91}{1557.65}\bigg/\frac{76.07}{760.72}\nonumber\\ \displaystyle & = & \displaystyle -0.20\end{eqnarray}$$

both as in column 5 of Table A1.Footnote 43

Application of expressions (A5) and (A6) to the expenditure changes posted in Tables 5 and 6 of the text associated with the price-increase scenarios of $234 and $348 yields the own- and cross-elasticities listed in Table A2. Own-elasticities for the two scenarios are indicated to be $-$ 0.10 and $-$ 0.14 for water purchased separately (columns 1 and 2) and $-$ 0.35 and $-$ 0.37 for housing when water is included in rent (columns 3 and 4).Footnote 44

Table A2 Estimated own- and cross-price elasticities with respect to changes in price of water. Households in bottom quintile of total-expenditure distribution (from Tables 5 and 6).

Of obvious interest is how these estimates compare with those found in the literature. Dalhuisen et al. (Reference Dalhuisen, Raymond, de Groot and Nijkamp2003) obtain a mean own-price elasticity of 0.41 in a meta-analysis of almost 300 studies over the period 1963–1998, and in a similarly extensive survey of the water demand literature, Olmstead and Stavins (Reference Olmstead and Stavins2008) find that the price elasticity of residential demand varies substantially across place and time, but on average, in the U.S., a ten percent increase in the marginal price of water in the urban residential sector can be expected to diminish demand by about three to four percent. Finally, in another meta-analysis of the variation in estimates of price elasticities taken from 24 studies of residential water demand published in journals between 1967 and 1993, Espey et al. (Reference Espey, Espey and Shaw1997) noted that estimates of the elasticities ranged from $-$ 0.02 to $-$ 3.33, with a mean of $-$ 0.51, and that 90 percent of the estimates fell between $-$ 0.50 and $-$ 0.75.

Thus, while the own-price elasticities calculated in the present investigation would appear to be at the lower end of existing estimates, two mitigating factors are to be noted: (1) calculations in the present effort refer to extremely low-income households and (2) the full array of cross-elasticities is taken into account.Footnote 45

Appendix B. The Arizona arsenic experience

It is important to note that the issues addressed by EJ and HHA are interrelated, but not identical. The arsenic experience in the state of Arizona is illustrative in this regard.

Arsenic is a common pollutant in Arizona’s groundwater (Hendricks, Reference Hendricks1985). The impact of revising the arsenic drinking water standard was dramatic in the state with 334 PWSs needing to take corrective action to comply, 80 percent of which were small PWSs with fewer than 3,300 connections (see Table B1). In fact, the total number of systems in Arizona affected by the revised standard accounted for roughly 10 percent of the nation’s total number of PWSs needing to take corrective action. In terms of population, almost 4.5 million Arizona residents were affected by the new standard, accounting for approximately 35 percent of the national population estimated to be affected by the revised arsenic MCL of 10 ppb (U.S. EPA, 2006).

Table B1 Public water systems in Arizona.

PWS customers reflect the diversity of the state in terms of race and income (see Table B2).

Table B2 Summary statistics.

The percentage of black persons in contaminated areas is disproportionately lower (1.25%) than the percentage of black population in noncontaminated areas (2.06%). The difference between percentages of black persons in contaminated and noncontaminated areas is $-0.81\%$ , and it is statistically significant at 5% level of significance. The percentage of minority persons (black $+$ Hispanic) in contaminated areas is approximately the same (23.77%) as in areas without contamination (21.31%). The difference between percentages of minority persons in contaminated and noncontaminated areas is 2.34%, and it is statistically insignificant. However, the percentage of white persons in arsenic contaminated area is disproportionately higher (81.22%) and statistically significant from the percentage of white persons in noncontaminated areas. The percentage of Hispanic persons in contaminated areas is greater (22.52%) than the percentage of Hispanic population in noncontaminated areas (19.25%), but the difference between the two is statistically insignificant. Moreover, per capita income, average housing value, and the income per household are each statistically greater in arsenic contaminated areas, as opposed to the corresponding figures in noncontaminated areas. These results suggest that the continued selective implementation and enforcement of the revised SDWA arsenic standard is not likely to disadvantage minority (i.e., black $+$ Hispanic population taken together) or low-income groups disproportionately in Arizona. In fact, these basic statistics suggest quite the opposite – there is a disproportionate impact of arsenic contamination on nonpoor and majority communities in Arizona.Footnote 46

Implementation of the revised arsenic standard in Arizona was not complicated by EJ concerns since small PWSs requiring corrective action were not disproportionately low income or minority in their customer base.Footnote 47 The health concerns addressed by HHA, however, remained. The Tubac case study documented that higher water bills for low-income customers of small PWSs are likely to result in lower household expenditures for other goods and services like health care, food, energy, and other essential services. While this evidence supports the contention that the net health impact on low-income water consumers may be negative when rate hikes become onerous, the result that low-income households will be worse off is not inevitable. More generally, consumers will reallocate their budget across all goods and services to maximize their utility in the face of water-rate hikes. Some consumers may choose to forego health services while others may economize on other non-health-related items to accommodate higher drinking water bills. In either case, consumers may be worse off, particularly low-income consumers who spend a disproportionately large share of their total income on necessities, if their tastes and preferences do not change during the course of MCL implementation. A possible exception to this adverse impact can occur when low-income customers come to highly value the health benefits of a more stringent MCL, as benefit information is disseminated over the course of MCL implementation, and the accompanying rate hike is modest. In this special case, water customers are happy to secure the health benefits of safer drinking water at a modest price and are better off, so that no distributive justice problem exists.Footnote 48

Footnotes

Note:EPDS:Entry points to the distribution systems. PWSs: Public Water Systems. System Size: The number of customers served by a PWS. Ownership Type: There are three types of ownership (Private: Owned by a private entity; Public: Owned by a municipality; Mixed: jointly (private and public) owned). System Type: System type can either Community Water System (CWS) serving to residential areas, or Nontransient Noncommunity (NTNC) serving to nontransient nonresidential areas. Water Source: This represents the source of water for a PWS. Source of water can be either groundwater (GW), surface water (SW). Source: Kiger (Reference Kiger2007).

Definition of variables: Arsenic affected area: zip-code area that has been affected by arsenic. Arsenic nonaffected area: zip-code area not affected by arsenic. White: percentage of white population in a zip-code area. Black: percentage of black population in a zip-code area. Hispanic: percentage of Hispanic population in a zip-code area. Minority: percentage of black and Hispanic population in a zip-code area. IncomePC: per capita family income in a zip-code area (U.S. Dollars). AVH: Average value of house in a zip-code area (U.S. Dollars). IncomePH: Average income per household in a zip-code area. Note: bracket values in the third column are $t$ -test statistic of difference of two means: $^{\text{a}}$ significance at 5%, and $^{\text{b}}$ significance at 10%. Source: Cory and Rahman (Reference Cory and Rahman2009)

1 A PWS is defined as having at least 15 service connections or serving at least 25 people per day for 60 days annually.

2 For example, according to the EPA, the value to consumers of a reduction in the risk of adverse health effects of arsenic exposure includes the following components: (1) the avoidance of medical costs and productivity loss associated with illness, (2) the avoidance of pain and suffering associated with illness, (3) the losses associated with risk and uncertainty of morbidity, (4) the reduction in risk of premature mortality (U.S. EPA, 2000).

3 The cost per household of safe drinking water is almost four times higher for small systems than for large systems. Small systems lack the economies of scale that allow large systems to spread the costs associated with infrastructure improvements or SDWA regulations among their many customers. Each household serviced by a small system could pay more than $3,000 in addition to its regular water bill, and EPA reports that as a conservative estimate because it does not include proposed or recently promulgated regulations (Scheberle, Reference Scheberle2004).

4 In fact, based on EPA’s own estimates of compliance costs for arsenic abatement, Raucher et al. (Reference Raucher, Rubin, Crawford-Brown and Lawson2011, pp. 16–18) estimate that cost-associated risks may be within the same order of magnitude as the EPA-estimated arsenic risk reductions.

5 Distress or hardship indicators may provide a useful complementary measure to traditional income measures of health and well-being. For example, these studies suggest an explicit chain of causation for negative net health outcomes resulting from regulatory compliance costs. Unfortunately, the reliability of financial distress studies is suspect. Critics argue that answers from the SIPP do not track well over time. In addition, study results are sensitive to sample selection, response, and attrition bias. The lack of temporal stability in Census panel data can be partly explained by changing economic circumstances and partly by responders’ corresponding outlooks. As Bauman (Reference Bauman1998) concludes, measures of material hardship provide insight into the material circumstances of low-income households, but must be used with some caution as a complement to, not a substitute for traditional poverty measures.

6 The origins of HHA in the federal regulatory policy context date back to 1992, when the Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OSHA) considered the effect of compliance costs on workers’ disposable incomes and then looked at the health effects associated with lowering those disposable incomes (OSHA, 1992). OSHA concluded that compliance costs could reach a point at which it was likely that the adverse health consequences of the income loss to workers would exceed the health benefits from the regulation.

7 For example, Gerdtham and Johannesson (Reference Gerdtham and Johannesson2002) estimated the effect of income on mortality using a random sample of the adult Swedish population of over 40,000 individuals followed up for 10–17 years. The income loss that would induce an expected fatality was estimated to be $6.8 million when the costs were borne equally among all adults.

8 The extensive literature on HHA has been reviewed elsewhere (Rubin, Raucher & Lawson, Reference Rubin, Raucher and Lawson2008).

9 Sunstein (Reference Sunstein1996) argues that there are a variety of mechanisms by which risk regulation may increase aggregate risks: (a) A regulatory ban may result in independent health risks coming from ancillary “replacement” risks. If we ban substance $A$ , the replacement substance $B$ may be dangerous too. If a carcinogenic substance is regulated, perhaps people will use a product that is not carcinogenic but that causes serious risks of heart disease. (b) Regulation may produce a new, offsetting risk that is qualitatively similar to or indistinguishable from the target risk. Perhaps regulation or some substances that threaten to destroy the ozone layer will produce greater use of other substances that also threaten the ozone layer. (c) Regulation may force society to lose or forego “opportunity benefits.” For example, careful screening procedures that keep out drugs and services may deprive people of certain health benefits at the same time that they protect people from certain health risks. This problem has received recent attention with respect to the Food and Drug Administration, especially with its efforts to control the spread of AIDS. (d) Regulated substances may have health benefits as well as health risks, and by eliminating those health benefits, regulations may therefore create health dangers on balance. (e) Regulation of one risk may protect a certain group of people while imposing a new risk on another group. This may happen if, for example, a ban on a certain pesticide protects consumers, plants, and animals while increasing risks to farmers. (f) More generally, the economic costs imposed by regulation may create health risks as well. In any of these contexts, HHA could serve as a useful complement to efficiency analysis in determining the desirability of a proposed policy.

10 In fact, EPA originally proposed a revised standard of 5 ppb on June 22, 2000 but increased this MCL to 10 ppb on January 22, 2001, ostensibly due to opposition from water authorities encountered during a requested comment period on alternative MCLs (U.S. EPA 2001).

11 Some organizations criticized EPA’s health-benefit estimates as being overestimates and others criticized them as underestimates. For overestimation critiques, see Burnett and Hahn (Reference Burnett and Hahn2001) and National Research Council (1999); for underestimation critiques, see the Natural Resources Defense Council publication (2000) and Wilson (Reference Wilson2001).

12 U.S. EPA (2000).

13 Quantifiable benefits used in the economic analysis were limited to avoided cases of bladder and lung cancer. Some of the nonquantifiable benefits included avoided cases of skin, kidney, liver, and prostate cancer, and other cardiovascular, pulmonary, neurological, and endocrine effects (U.S. EPA, 2000).

14 EPA is well aware of the burdensome nature of revised and new drinking water standards on small systems. A variety of programs have been developed to mitigate costs including the Small Local Governments Compliance Assistance policy, the Drinking Water State Revolving Fund, and the Consumer Confidence Help program (see http://www2.epa.gov/compliance/resources-and-guidance documents).

15 Expenditures and income are highly correlated for households in the lowest quintile. The U.S. Census Bureau collects data on the total money income earned by U.S. individuals, families, and households. Households consist of all people who occupy a housing unit, regardless of whether they are related to each other by birth, marriage, or adoption, or not. In 2012, the average total money income for U.S. households was $71,274, with a median value of $51,017. For the bottom quintile of household income in that year, the mean level was $11,490.

16 Hereafter, Internal Structure. See also Taylor (Reference Taylor2016).

17 The validity of this whole approach obviously depends upon the matrix of intrabudget coefficients representing stable distributional characteristics of households’ expenditure decisions. Chapter 3 of Internal Structure presents a battery of analyses establishing that this assumption can be taken at face value.

18 In Internal Structure, questions of the following sort are investigated. Suppose that, from a point of equilibrium, there is an increase (for whatever reason) of $50 in expenditures for food. In terms of the matrix of intrabudget coefficients, this will perturb the equilibrium expenditures for the other categories, which will then feed back on expenditures for food, which will once again disturb other expenditures, and so on and so forth. In the new equilibrium (assuming that one is reached), how is the increase of $50 in food expenditures ultimately diffused amongst the other categories? Alternatively, one might ask what will be the effect on equilibrium expenditures when an increase in expenditures in one category is offset by a like decrease in another category, an increase, say, of $50 for housing coupled with a decrease of $50 for apparel?

19 The analysis involves two different samples of households in the bottom quintile of total expenditure: households for which expenditures for water are nonzero and households for which water is included in rent. Typically, there are about 900 households in the surveys underlying the former and 500 the latter. Unfortunately, information regarding households whose expenditures are recorded as zero because of access to private wells is not available.

20 Coefficient estimates are in columns, equations in rows.

21 Both tables refer to households in the bottom quintile of total expenditure.

22 It might seem that new equilibria are independent of how changes in expenditure come about, but this is not the case, for equilibrium depends upon where and how changes in expenditure occur and at what point (and how) a total-expenditure budget constraint is imposed. In particular, exogenous changes [as should be clear from consideration of expression (5)] lead to new equilibria that are different from the original. With endogenous changes, however, since z is not changed, the system will eventually return to the same equilibrium as before. Chapters 4 and 5 of Internal Structure provide discussion and examples.

23 For a brief discussion of the impact on small PWSs for the state of Arizona as a whole, see Appendix B.

24 Tubac is nationally known for both its art and history. The Tubac Presidio State Historic Park was established in 1959 and the Museum in 1964. The first Tubac Festival of the Arts took place in 1960, with the Tubac Center of the Arts opening in 1972.

25 For a comprehensive listing of Tubac demographic data, see http://www.clrsearch.com/Tubac_Demographics/AZ/.

26 The overall quality of life in Tubac is judged to be high by CLRsearch.com, a real estate service that provides information on home, school, and community demographic characteristics for cities across the U.S. A quality-of-life index is calculated based on what variables affect individuals as they search for a new home, how much they would enjoy living in a place, and the impact of selected variables. Positive variables weighted for the quality-of-life index include amusement, culture, education, medical facilities, religion, restaurants, and weather. Negative variables include crime, earthquake frequency, pollution, and mortality. An area’s index score is compared to the national average of 100. A score of 200 indicates twice the national average, while 50 indicates half the national average. The quality-of-life index for Tubac is 148, compared to 129 for Arizona and 100 for the U.S.

27 Customers of Arizona American Water are now served by EPCOR Water. See http://epcor.com for additional information.

28 Results for exogenous increases in the cost of water of $348 in Table 6 of the text are obtained in the same manner. Changes in these tables may not sum to zero because of rounding.

29 Taking money from housing to pay for the drinking water increase is reminiscent of William “Willie” Sutton (June 30, 1901–November 2, 1980), a prolific American bank robber who stole an estimated $2 million and eventually spent more than half of his adult life in prison. When asked by a reporter why he robbed banks he simply replied “because that’s where the money is” (see http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Willie_Sutton).

30 Water demand in the residential sector is sensitive to price, but the magnitude of the sensitivity is small (i.e., demand is inelastic) at current prices. In their meta-analysis of 124 estimates generated between 1963 and 1993, (Espey & Shaw, Reference Espey and Shaw1997) obtain an average price elasticity of $-$ 0.51. Dalhuisen et al. (Reference Dalhuisen, Raymond, de Groot and Nijkamp2003) obtain a mean price elasticity of 0.41 in a meta-analysis of almost 300 price elasticity studies, 1963–1998. In their survey of the water demand literature, Olmstead and Stavins (Reference Olmstead and Stavins2008) concluded that the price elasticity of residential demand varies substantially across place and time, but on average, in the United States, a ten percent increase in the marginal price of water in the urban residential sector can be expected to diminish demand by about three to four percent.

31 This amounts to an average daily expenditure of $28 per day per household. The U.S. official poverty line for a family of three is roughly $20,090 of income per year (see http://aspe.hhs.gov/2015-poverty-guidelines).

32 For some low-income renters, the impact of rising water rates may be ameliorated by government programs. For example, under the Section 8 Certificate program, low-income renters have their rental payment capped at 30% of household income. In this case, landlords would be compensated for increased water costs by the federal government, not by the low-income renter. To the extent that social programs can protect low-income households from rent increases due to SDWA compliance costs, the concerns of HHA are partially addressed.

33 Wastewater treatment costs can be substantial for low-income households. Households in cities building new sewage treatment infrastructure pay up to 15 times more on their sewer bills than households in cities with old wastewater treatment systems, according to a Circle of Blue survey of residential wastewater rates in 30 major cities. As the U.S. EPA implements stricter water quality regulations, wastewater treatment plants are forced to overhaul their systems, and customers ultimately see significant increases in their sewer bills. For example, a family of four using 100 gallons per person per day pays $13.92 per month in Salt Lake City compared to $208.60 per month in Atlanta which is undergoing a $4 billion modernization and expansion (see Brett Walton (2010) at http://www.circleofblue.org/2010/world/the-price-of-water-a-comparision-of-water-rates-usage-in-30-u-s-cities/).

35 The EPA is charged with regulating five new pollutants per year under the SDWA. The EPA under the Obama administration has committed to adding 16 contaminants to the list of regulated substances.

36 For a detailed discussion of these challenges, see Cory et al., Reference Cory, Tauhidur, Satheesh, Melissa and Miles2012.

37 “In small rural communities with a presumed $5\unicode[STIX]{x03BC}\text{g}/\text{L}$ exposure reduction to meet the arsenic MCL and a $407 per-household annual cost to do so, the results show that the net health benefits of the arsenic MCL might be roughly half of the arsenic-associated risk reduction (i.e., 4.45 cases of arsenic-related health effects avoided over 70 years per 1,000 individuals, but 2.04 cases of other adverse effects added per 1,000 persons due to the cost impacts). If a small rural community has a relatively large proportion of low-income households compared to the national average, then the cost-associated health impacts are expected to be even larger, and would result in an even lower net benefit from the MCL (because the projected cost-associated risk is estimated at the mean national income and would be higher for lower income levels).” Raucher et al. (Reference Raucher, Rubin, Crawford-Brown and Lawson2011, p. 17)).

38 EPA is well positioned to assume a leadership role in evaluating fundamental SDWA reforms (Rubin & Raucher, Reference Rubin and Raucher2010). It is widely recognized that increased flexibility should be incorporated whenever possible into the SDWA if this act is to be truly protective of public health for all classes of water consumers (Regnier, Reference Regnier2002). A variety of reforms have been proposed. Prominent among these proposals are the reforms advocated by the National Rural Water Association including: (1) basing MCLs on the magnitude, duration and frequency of exposure, (2) triggering enforcement actions only when a PWS is in significant noncompliance with SDWA regulations, (3) giving states exclusive enforcement authority, with the EPA exercising deferential oversight, (4) making variances and exemptions more compatible with the needs of PWSs, and (5) allowing affordability to be an affirmative defense in enforcement actions (Koorse, Reference Koorse2002). In addition, regulatory flexibility could be enhanced by the use of dual standards, allowing small PWSs to achieve slightly less stringent water quality standards, and by facilitating the use of system consolidation to increase the customer base of small PWSs. For critical reviews of EPA’s performance with respect to incorporating EJ considerations into drinking water regulations, see Rubin and Raucher (Reference Rubin and Raucher2010) and Logomasini (Reference Logomasini2008).

39 Program examples would include the Affordable Care Act which is designed to end pre-existing condition exclusions for children and covers preventive care at no cost to low-income households, and the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP) which is designed to improve levels of nutrition among low-income households.

40 All calculations are undertaken in SAS. For a much more detailed discussion elasticities calculated in this framework, see Taylor (Reference Taylor2016).

41 This represents a quarterly total; the implied total annual expenditure is about $17,000.

42 Note that the elasticity in this expression refers to revenue rather than quantity, hence the subtraction of 1. See next footnote.

43 Note that, per the preceding footnote, the own-price elasticity is measured from expenditure after the price change (rather than from the base expenditure), since, with no change in quantity demanded, this is what expenditure (as given by $q_{i}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}p_{i}$ ) would be in the absence of a nonzero elasticity. However, a nonzero (negative) elasticity causes some of the revenue [specifically, $q_{i}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}p_{i}-\unicode[STIX]{x1D6E5}(p_{i}q_{i})$ ] in effect to “melt” away because of the higher price. For cross-elasticities, on the other hand, since prices of other goods are not changed, calculations are made from base expenditures.

44 Note that the higher (absolute) values for the latter are virtually the same as the former when the cross-elasticities with respect to housing are added to the own-values ( $-$ 0.31 and $-$ 0.33 vs. $-$ 0.35 and $-$ 0.37, respectively).

45 Existing studies of water demand in general suffer from an inability to estimate cross-elasticities because of multicollinearity. If other prices are in fact important in influencing water demand and also highly correlated with the price of water, then their influence (via the impact of omitted variables) will be reflected in the estimated water elasticity. [Cf., Griliches (Reference Griliches1957).] Such, accordingly, may account for own-price elasticities estimated in conventional demand models tending to be larger than the ones reported here.

46 In Cory and Rahman (Reference Cory and Rahman2009), zero-order correlations were used to measure the strength of linear associations between census and exposure variables while logistic regression models were utilized to estimate the relationship between the likelihood of arsenic contamination in a particular geographical area and its associated demographic and economic characteristics. Both zero-order correlation analysis and logistic regression estimation support the conclusion that continued selective implementation and enforcement of the revised SDWA arsenic standard is unlikely to disadvantage minority or low-income groups disproportionately in Arizona.

47 For policy purposes, EJ is concerned with the fair treatment of all people regardless of race or income with respect to the implementation of environmental laws and regulation (U.S. EPA, 2003). In the context of arsenic in drinking water, fair treatment means that no group of people should bear a disproportionate share of the negative implementation consequences.

48 Additionally, the Arizona Department of Environmental Quality in conjunction with U.S. EPA have instituted a variety of programs to facilitate environmental compliance in small communities generally, as well as specific drinking water programs to provide technical guidance and financial aid. The Small Community Environmental Compliance Assistance Program, the Arsenic Master Plan, and the Drinking Water State Revolving Fund are three prominent examples of programs designed to keep compliance cost lower for small PWSs in Arizona. See Cory et al. (Reference Cory, Tauhidur, Satheesh, Melissa and Miles2012) for a discussion.

References

Bauman, Kurt(1998). Direct measures of poverty as indicators of economic need: evidence from the survey of income and program participation. U.S. Census Bureau Population Division Technical Paper No. 30.Google Scholar
Bauman, Kurt(1999). Extended measures of well-being: meeting basic needs. U.S. Census Bureau Current Population Reports No. P70-67.Google Scholar
Boushey, Heather, Gundersen, Bethney, Brocht, Chauna & Bernstein, Jared (2001). Hardships in America: The Real Story of Working Families. Economic Policy Institute.Google Scholar
Burnett, Jason K. & Hahn, Robert W.(2001). EPA’s Arsenic Rule: The Benefits of Standard Do Not Justify the Costs, AEI-Brookings Joint Center on Regulatory Studies, Regulatory Analysis Paper 01-02.Google Scholar
Cory, Dennis C. & Rahman, Tauhidur (2009). Environmental Justice and Enforcement of the Safe Drinking Water Act: The Arizona Arsenic Experience. Ecological Economics, 68, 18251837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cory, Dennis C., Tauhidur, Rahman, Satheesh, Aradhyula, Melissa, Anne Burns & Miles, H. Kiger (2012). Environmental Justice and Federalism. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford-Brown, Douglas, Raucher, Robert, Rubin, Scott & Lawson, Megan(2009). Risk Tradeoffs in Public Health When Water Prices Rise: The Implications for Small Community Supplies; Available at http://nrwadev.org/benefits/whitepapers/TOC.htm.Google Scholar
Dalhuisen, Jasper M., Raymond, J. G. M. Florax, de Groot, Henri L. F. & Nijkamp, Peter (2003). Price and Income Elasticities of Residential Water Demand: A Meta-Analysis. Land Economics, 79 (2), 292308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Energy CENTS Coalition(1999). Minnesota’s Energy Gap: Unaffordable Energy and Low Income Minnesotans. http://www.energycents.org/index.html.Google Scholar
Espey, Molly, Espey, James & Shaw, W. Douglass (1997). Price Elasticity of Residential Demand for Water: A Meta-Analysis. Water Resources Research, 33 (6 June), 13691374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Espey, M. J. & Shaw, W. D. (1997). Price Elasticity of Residential Demand for Water: A Meta-analysis. Water Resources Research, 33(6), 13691374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerdtham, Ulf G. & Johannesson, Magnus (2002). Do Life-Saving Regulations Save Lives? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 24, 231249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griliches, Zvi (1957). Specification Bias in Estimates of Production Functions. Journal of Farm Economics, 39(1), 820.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendricks, David M. (1985). Arizona Soils. Tucson, AZ: College of Agriculture, University of Arizona.Google Scholar
Keeney, Ralph L. (1994). Mortality Risks Induced by the Costs of Regulation. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8, 95110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiger, Miles H. (2007). Environmental federalism and the safe drinking water act: The Arizona Arsenic experience, M.S. thesis. Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ.Google Scholar
Koorse, Steven J.(2002) Enforcement Flexibility Under the Safe Drinking Water Act, White Paper prepared for the National Rural Water Association (May), pp. 1–124. Available at http://www.nrwa.org/benefits/whitepapers/conserve/conserve01/conserve01.doc.Google Scholar
Logomasini, Angela (2008). Arsenic. Washington, DC: Competitive Enterprise Institute; Available at http://cei.org/studies-other-studies/arsenic.Google Scholar
Lutter, Randall & Morrall III, John F. (1994). Health–Health Analysis: A New Way to Evaluate Health and Safety Regulation. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8, 4366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mishel, Lawrence & Shierholz, Heidi(2013) A Decade of Flat Wages: The Key Barrier to Shared Prosperity and a Rising Middle Class. Briefing Paper #365 (August). Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institute; Available at http://www.epi.org/publication/a-decade-of-flat-wages-the-key-barrier-to-shared-prosperity-and-a-rising-middle-class/.Google Scholar
National Research Council (1999). Arsenic in Drinking Water. Washington, DC: National Academies Press; Available at http://www.nap.edu/openbook.php?record_id=6444.Google Scholar
Natural Resources Defense Council (2000). Arsenic and Old Laws. New York: Clean Water and Oceans Division; Available at http://www.nrdc.org/water/drinking/arsenic/aolinx.asp.Google Scholar
Occupational Safety Health Administration (OSHA) (1992). Air Contaminants Proposed Rule. Federal Register, 57, 26002.Google Scholar
Olmstead, Sheila & Stavins, Robert(2008). Comparing price and non-price approaches to urban water conservation. Harvard Kennedy School, Faculty Research Working Paper RWP08-034.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Portney, Paul R. & Stavins, Robert N. (1994). Regulatory Review of Environmental Policy: The Potential Role of Health–Health Analysis. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8 (1 January), 111122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raucher, Robert S., Rubin, Scott J., Crawford-Brown, Douglas & Lawson, Megan M. (2011). Benefit-Cost Analysis for Drinking Water Standards: Efficiency, Equity and Affordability Considerations in Small Communities. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 2 (1), 122 Available at http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jbca.2011.2.1/jbca.2011.2.1.1004/jbca.2011.2.1.1004.xml.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Regnier, John E. (2002). Flexibility in the SAFE Drinking Water Act. Rural Water, Fourth Quarter, 1314.Google Scholar
Rubin, Scott J. & Raucher, Robert(2010). Applying Environmental Justice to Drinking Water Regulations; Available at http://mail.nrwadev.org/benefits/whitepapers/TOC.htm.Google Scholar
Rubin, Scott J., Raucher, Robert & Lawson, Megan2008 The Relationship Between Household Financial Distress and Health: Implications for Drinking Water Regulation. White Paper for the National Rural Water Association. pp. 1–19; Available at http://www.denix.osd.mil/cmrmd/upload/NRWAPAPER.pdf.Google Scholar
Scheberle, Denise (2004). Implementing Drinking Water Regulations in a One-Size-Fits-All World. In Federalism and Environmental Policy: Trust and the Policies of Implementation. Washington, DC: Georgetown University Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. (1996). Health–Health Tradeoffs. University of Chicago Law Review, 63, 15331573.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.(2001). The Arithmetic of Arsenic, University of Chicago Institute for Law and Economics, Working Paper No. 135; Available at http://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/law_and_economics_wp/.Google Scholar
Taylor, Lester D. (2013). The Internal Structure of U.S. Consumption Expenditures. New York, NY: Springer International Publishing Co.Google Scholar
Taylor, Lester D.(2016). Notes on Measurement of Consumer Expenditures (With Special Reference to the On-Going BLS Consumer Expenditure Survey). Department of Economics, University of Arizona. Available from .Google Scholar
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2000). Arsenic in Drinking Water Rule Economic Analysis. Washington, DC: Office of Groundwater and Drinking Water, EPA 815-R-00-026; Available at http://nepis.epa.gov/exe/ZyPURL.cgi?Dockey=20001YQT.txt.Google Scholar
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2002). Sources of Technical and Financial Assistance for Small Drinking Water Systems. Washington, DC: Office of Groundwater and Drinking Water, EPA 816-K-02-005; Available at http://yosemite.epa.gov/water/owrccatalog.nsf/EPATitle?OpenView&CartID=13452-051242.Google Scholar
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2003). Environmental Justice; Available at http://www.epa.gov/compliance/environmentaljustice/index.html.Google Scholar
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2006). Arsenic in Drinking Water, Basic Information. Office of Groundwater and Drinking Water Web Resources; Available at http://water.epa.gov/lawsregs/rulesregs/sdwa/arsenic/basic-information.cfm.Google Scholar
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2011). Drinking Water and Ground Water Statistics. Office of Water (4606 m), EPA 816-R-13-003 (March); Available at http://water.epa.gov/scitech/datait/databases/drink/sdwisfed/upload.epa816r13003.pdf.Google Scholar
Vandervoet, Kathleen (2008). Water Rates May Rise 72.7 Percent. Tubac Villager, IV (2 December), 12.Google Scholar
Vandervoet, Kathleen (2009). 120 Attend Water Rate Hearing. Tubac Villager, IV (6 April), 10.Google Scholar
Wilson, Richard (2001). Underestimating Arsenic’s Risk. Regulation, 24 (3), 5052.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 Hierarchy of household necessities. Sources: compiled by Raucher et al. (2011), based on Bauman (1998, 1999), Energy CENTS Coalition (1999), and Boushey et al. (2001).

Figure 1

Table 1 BLS consumption expenditure categories.

Figure 2

Table 2 Intra-budget regressions. 17 categories of U.S. consumption expenditure, 2012 Q4, bottom quintile (855 observations).

Figure 3

Table 3 Means of intra-budget expenditures regression coefficients. 17 categories of U.S. consumption expenditure, bottom quintile, 2006 Q1–2012 Q4.

Figure 4

Table 4 Mean annual costs per household of the arsenic MCL (10 ppb).

Figure 5

Table 5 Effects of a $234 quarterly increase in expenditures for water in the bottom quintile of total expenditure. (Total expenditure held constant).

Figure 6

Table 6 Effects of a $348 quarterly increase in expenditures for water in the bottom quintile of total expenditure (total expenditure held constant).

Figure 7

Figure 2 U.S. Water Rate Increases. Source: US department of labor, bureau of statistics, consumer price index. Available at http://www.bls.gov/cpi/

Figure 8

Table 7 Expenditure accommodations for quarterly water surcharges in the bottom quintile of total expenditure (total expenditure held constant).

Figure 9

Table A1 Own- & cross-price elasticities. For a 5 & 10 percent increase in price of food (total expenditure held constant).

Figure 10

Table A2 Estimated own- and cross-price elasticities with respect to changes in price of water. Households in bottom quintile of total-expenditure distribution (from Tables 5 and 6).

Figure 11

Table B1 Public water systems in Arizona.

Figure 12

Table B2 Summary statistics.