Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T17:01:24.431Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

When Self-interest is Self-Defeating: The Public Goods Experiment as a Teaching Tool

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 April 2015

Robert G. Nelson
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology
Richard O. Beil Jr.
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Auburn University, Alabama

Abstract

This simple classroom experiment demonstrates many of the behavioral phenomena associated with the voluntary provision of a public good. The mechanics of the game are explained in detail and complete instructions are provided, as well as suggestions for follow-up lectures. Influences such as anonymous voting, persuasion, returns to free-riding, and duration of association can be explored in connection with concepts of incentives, individual rationality and group welfare. A number of variations and extensions can be used to incorporate prisoners' dilemmas, incentive compatible mechanisms, negative externalities, and Coasian bargaining.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Southern Agricultural Economics Association 1994

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Andreoni, James. “Why free ride? Strategies and learning in public goods experiments.J. Public Econ. 37(1988):291304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anonymous. “How do you mean, ‘fair’?The Economist 327(May 29, 1993):71.Google Scholar
Asch, Peter and Gigliotti, Gary A.. “The Free-Rider Paradox: Theory, Evidence, and Teaching.J. Econ. Education 22(1991):3338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bagnoli, Mark and McKee, Michael. “Voluntary Contribution Games: Efficient Private Provision of Public Goods.Econ. Inquiry 29(1991):351–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brock, John R.A Public Goods Experiment for the Classroom.Econ. Inquiry 29(1991):395401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, Allan M.Welfare Economics and Social Choice Theory. Hingham, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1983.Google Scholar
Forker, Olan D. and Ward, Ronald W.. Commodity Advertising: the Economics and Measurement of Generic Programs. New York: Lexington Books, 1993.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H., Gilovich, Thomas, and Regan, Dennis T.. “Does Studying Economics Inhibit Cooperation?J. Econ. Perspectives 7(1993): 159171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, R.Mark, David Schmidtz, and Walker, James M.. “The Assurance Problem in a Laboratory Market.Public Choice 62(1989):217236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ledyard, John O.Incentive Compatibility.” In The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, vol. 2, Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P., eds., London: Macmillan Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Leuthold, Jane E.A Public Goods Experiment for the Classroom.J. Econ. Education 18(1987):5865.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marwell, Gerald and Ames, Ruth E.. “Economists Free Ride, Does Anyone Else?J. Public Econ. 15(1981):295310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCaleb, Thomas S. and Wagner, Richard E.. “The Experimental Search for Free Riders: Some Reflections and Observations.Public Choice 47(1985):479490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Satterthwaite, Mark A.Strategy-proof Allocation Mechanisms.” In The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, vol. 4, Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P., eds., London: Macmillan Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E.Economics of the Public Sector, 2nd ed. New York: Norton, 1988.Google Scholar
Sulock, Joseph M.The Free Rider and Voting Paradox ‘Games’.J. Econ. Education 21(1990):6569.Google Scholar
Walker, James M., Gardner, Roy, and Ostrom, Elinor. “Rent Dissipation in a Limited-Access Common-Pool Resource: Experimental Evidence.J. Environmental Econ. and Management 19(1990):203–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar