Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T17:47:37.332Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

PRICE DETERMINANTS OF BRED COWS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 September 2017

JAMES L. MITCHELL*
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, Kansas State University, Manhattan, Kansas
DERRELL S. PEEL
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, Oklahoma
B. WADE BRORSEN
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, Oklahoma
*
*Corresponding author's e-mail: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Hedonic modeling of Oklahoma cow auction data is used to determine the market value of bred cow characteristics. We use Agricultural Marketing Service data that let us consider more years and more lots of cattle than is typical for a cattle hedonic study. The greatest price premiums were for black, late-gestating cows, categorized as high quality by market reporters and weighing between 1,600 and 1,700 lb. Previous research on optimal cow size finds much smaller-size cows are optimal, and our research finds that larger cows receive a lower price per pound but still receive a substantially higher price per head.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2017

1. Introduction

Bred cows are inputs into beef production. They are a joint product because of the future flow of calves (including the unborn calf) being bundled with the slaughter value of the cow at the time of sale. Often producers market replacement cows and heifers as bred. Additionally, many producers sell older cull cows as bred cows. Research has determined that cull cow retention and marketing as bred can be economically viable (Amadou, Reference Amadou2012). Although past studies have identified several cow-marketing strategies (Amadou et al., Reference Amadou, Raper, Biermacher, Cook and Ward2014; Lawrence, Reference Lawrence2002; Trapp, Reference Trapp1986), none have considered the contribution of bred cow traits to total value. A standard methodology to quantify product differentiation and price variability is the hedonic approach.

Numerous studies have used hedonic models to explain price variation among agricultural products. In particular, considerable research effort has sought to identify factors affecting feeder cattle price differentials (e.g., Avent, Ward, and Lalman, Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004; Bailey, Peterson, and Brorsen, Reference Bailey, Peterson and Brorsen1991; Buccola, Reference Buccola1980; Coatney, Menkhaus, and Schmitz, Reference Coatney, Menkhaus and Schmitz1996; Faminow and Gum, Reference Faminow and Gum1986; Marsh, Reference Marsh1985; Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Mintert, Brazle and Grunewald1988; Schulz, Dhuyvetter, and Doran, Reference Schulz, Dhuyvetter and Doran2015; Williams et al., Reference Williams, Raper, DeVuyst, Peel and McKinney2012; Zimmerman et al., Reference Zimmerman, Schroeder, Dhuyvetter, Olson, Stokka, Seeger and Grotelueschen2012). Early studies focused on the value of feeder cattle physical characteristics. Later studies incorporated regional and temporal factors and have assessed the value of various value-added programs and sales (Blank, Saitone, and Sexton, Reference Blank, Saitone and Sexton2016; Mallory et al., Reference Mallory, DeVuyst, Raper, Peel and Mourer2016). Results from these academic studies have provided producers with valuable information on the linkage between feeder cattle characteristics and their accompanying premiums and discounts.

In addition to feeder cattle hedonic analyses, research has also determined factors affecting purebred bulls (Dhuyvetter et al., Reference Dhuyvetter, Schroeder, Simms, Bolze and Geske1996; Vestal et al., Reference Vestal, Lusk, DeVuyst and Kropp2013), cow-calf pairs (Parcell, Schroeder, and Hiner, Reference Parcell, Schroeder and Hiner1995), and cull cow prices (Mintert et al., Reference Mintert, Blair, Schroeder and Brazle1990). Both studies of cows, as well as Peel and Doye (Reference Peel and Doye2008), note significant premiums for cows that are bred, but the studies did not focus on the hedonic prices for bred cows alone. Bred cows are the only class of cattle that have not been explicitly studied in a hedonic framework.

This study addresses the question of how physical characteristics and temporal and market factors influence the price of bred cows sold in seven auctions across the state of Oklahoma. Research on bred cow price determinants provides sellers with information on which traits buyers find desirable along with the value of those attributes. Furthermore, buyers will be able to make a more efficient decision about whether to purchase or raise replacements (Schulz and Gunn, Reference Schulz and Gunn2014). Thus, information about the value placed on individual bred cow traits is potentially useful to many in the cattle industry.

2. Agricultural Marketing Service (AMS) Data

The most common unit of observation in hedonic livestock research is auction lots. Typically, researchers enlist the services of staff, research associates, and trained personnel to record results from livestock auctions, which allows collection of a wide range of animal characteristics (e.g., Avent, Ward, and Lalman, Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004; Bailey, Peterson, and Brorsen, Reference Bailey, Peterson and Brorsen1991; Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Mintert, Brazle and Grunewald1988). Data for this research are from aggregated U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA)–AMS bred cow reports, where aggregation occurs across varied categories of lots. Given that the data of this research are aggregate, a brief discussion of data aggregation is warranted.

The literature on aggregated data has two main thrusts. The objective of the first deals with the aggregation problem, whereas the second is concerned with prediction. Considerable effort has been devoted toward the aggregation problem—namely, the problem of aggregation bias defined as the deviation of macroparameters from the average of the corresponding microparameters (Gupta, Reference Gupta1971; Lee, Pesaran, and Pierse, Reference Lee, Pesaran and Pierse1990; Sasaki, Reference Sasaki1978; Thiel, Reference Theil1954). The central focus of the prediction problem is in determining whether to use micro- or macromodels to predict an aggregate dependent variable (Grunfeld and Griliches, Reference Grunfeld and Griliches1960; Pesaran, Pierse, and Kumar, Reference Pesaran, Pierse and Kumar1989). Both problems, prediction and aggregation bias, have been addressed in numerous empirical studies.

Studies in various fields of economic research have documented the implications from using aggregated data sets. Richter and Brorsen (Reference Richter and Brorsen2006) derive a theoretical model that shows that aggregate data create heteroskedasticity but do not create bias if the underlying model is linear. Shumway and Davis (Reference Shumway and Davis2001) show that errors in inference, stemming from aggregation, are small relative to errors attributable to incorrect choice of functional form or failure to account for time series components of the data (Shumway and Davis, Reference Shumway and Davis2001).

Given that the data in this research are aggregated, it is important to note that although bias may be present, the bias is likely minimal because the bred cow categories are relatively narrow and relationships are approximately linear. Another point of discussion is interval-censored data. Although methods exist that could be applied to the data in this research, the methods for interval-censored data would not work well because the intervals of this data are highly irregular.

Although there are many challenges associated with aggregate data sets, the studies reviewed here suggest that a lot can be learned from aggregated data. To date, no studies have made use of aggregate data, where aggregation occurs across lots, to determine the market value of livestock characteristics. This research makes use of an aggregate data set that reports prices from seven livestock auctions.

In Oklahoma, AMSFootnote 1 summarizes transactions from seven livestock auctions. The Oklahoma City AMS office granted access to their archive system, which provided all of the relevant historical auction reports.Footnote 2 The AMS auction reports include the following data: date, price, age, weight, months bred, quality, hide color, location, and sale volume. With the assistance of the Livestock Marketing Information Center (LMIC), an automated program was developed to process the text files, totaling close to 6,000 individual files. Observations with missing values and characteristics are dropped from the data set. In total, 135 observations were dropped because of inconsistencies. The final data set includes 776 weeks composed of 14,811 bred cow lots from January 5, 2000, to May 21, 2015. The price of a bred cow lot ranges from $330/head to $3,400/head. Weight ranges from 700 lb. to 1,700 lb. Complete summary statistics are included in Table 1.

Table 1. Descriptive Statistics of Selected Bred Cow Characteristics for Seven Oklahoma Auctions, January 2000–May 2015

a Heifers are coded as 1-year-olds for convenience.

b Replacement cow volume is the total number of bred cows and cow-calf pairs sold.

c U.S. Department of Agriculture market reports list the total number of cows and bulls sold, as well as the percentage of head that are slaughter cows and bulls. Multiplying the percentage of slaughter animals sold and the total number of head sold gives the total number of slaughter animals. Replacement cow volume is obtained by subtracting the number of slaughter animals sold from the total number of head sold at auction.

d Cow quality is coded as low = 1, low-average = 2, average = 3, average-high = 4, and high = 5.

Note: Includes 14,811 total observations.

In the AMS reports, prices from a set of lots are aggregated into homogenous groups with similar age, weight, and months bred classifications. Thus, the data reported are aggregate data and do not reflect individual lots sold. Figure 1 presents an example of how reporters aggregate bred cows into categories with similar characteristics. Because of aggregation, the variables price, age, months bred, and weight are reported as ranges. The midpoint of each range is used as the observation for each lot.

Figure 1. Example Bred Cow Auction Report (source: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Marketing Service)

Age ranges from 2 to 10 years. AMS reporters also report prices for bred heifers. Heifers are coded as 1-year-olds, for comparison. In this context, age is a reference for the number of calves born. The variable age is expected to have a nonlinear impact on price. As bred cows age, they will receive discounts at an increasing rate because of the reduced useful life of the capital asset. Research on optimal cow size (Bir et al., Reference Bir, DeVuyst, Rolf and Lalman2016; Doye and Lalman, Reference Doye and Lalman2011) suggests that smaller cows are optimal. The argument is that a smaller cow eats less than a large cow and can wean a relatively heavier calf if bred to a larger bull. As months bred increases, the gestating cows are expected to receive a higher price.

Each bred cow lot is assigned a measure of quality reported in five categories: high, high-average, average, average-low, and low. The market reporter determines cow quality by visual inspection. The classifications high-average and average-low are assigned when the quality of the lot is not uniform. Higher-quality cows are expected to receive premiums, whereas lower-quality cows are expected to be discounted. In addition to quality, bred cows are given a black or nonblack hide color classification. Black cows are expected to receive a higher price than nonblack cows.

Supplementary data include daily Chicago Mercantile Exchange feeder cattle and corn futures prices, obtained from the LMIC, to represent price expectations. Feeder cattle futures prices serve as a proxy for expected output prices, and corn futures prices measure expected input costs (Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Mintert, Brazle and Grunewald1988). There is expected to be a negative impact on price, as corn futures prices increase. Likewise, it is expected that there will be a positive effect on price as feeder cattle futures prices increase. These expectations are consistent with those of related studies (Bailey, Peterson, and Brorsen, Reference Bailey, Peterson and Brorsen1991; Buccola, Reference Buccola1980; Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Mintert, Brazle and Grunewald1988; Turner, Dykes, and McKissick, Reference Turner, Dykes and McKissick1991; Zimmerman et al., Reference Zimmerman, Schroeder, Dhuyvetter, Olson, Stokka, Seeger and Grotelueschen2012).

3. Bred Cow Model

In Lancaster's (Reference Lancaster1966) seminal article, “A New Approach to Consumer Theory,” he argues that utility is derived not from the good being consumed, but rather from the characteristics that a good possesses. Later, Ladd and Martin (Reference Ladd and Martin1976) took a product characteristic approach to farm production inputs. Ladd and Martin's (Reference Ladd and Martin1976) input characteristic model (ICM) illustrates how the value of production inputs is equal to the sum of the value of the input characteristics. Ladd and Martin (Reference Ladd and Martin1976) provide a theoretical framework for researchers to model livestock price determinants. A similar approach to Ladd and Martin is used here, specifically those extensions of ICM found in the livestock marketing literature.

Bred cow prices reflect supply and demand conditions in a given market at a point in time. For any given auction, supply is fixed in the short run and prices are determined by the demand for a set of bred cow characteristics. From Ladd and Martin (Reference Ladd and Martin1976), the demand for an input is influenced by the input's characteristics, which allows price to be a function of physical characteristics. Through previous extensions of ICM (Bailey, Brorsen, and Thomsen, Reference Bailey, Brorsen and Thomsen1995; Dhuyvetter et al., Reference Dhuyvetter, Schroeder, Simms, Bolze and Geske1996; Mintert et al., Reference Mintert, Blair, Schroeder and Brazle1990; Parcell, Schroeder, and Hiner, Reference Parcell, Schroeder and Hiner1995; Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Mintert, Brazle and Grunewald1988; Williams et al., Reference Williams, Raper, DeVuyst, Peel and McKinney2012; Zimmerman et al., Reference Zimmerman, Schroeder, Dhuyvetter, Olson, Stokka, Seeger and Grotelueschen2012), the price of a lot of bred cows can be specified as a function of physical characteristics (C) and market forces (M), formulated as follows:

(1) $$\begin{equation} Pric{e_{it}} = \mathop \sum \limits_k {V_{ikt}}{C_{ikt}} + \mathop \sum \limits_h {R_{ht}}{M_{ht}}, \end{equation}$$

where i refers to a lot of bred cows sold in time period t, V is the marginal value of bred cow trait k, and R is the marginal effect of market factor h (Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Mintert, Brazle and Grunewald1988). Factors included as market forces are price expectations, both input costs and output price expectations, sale location, and the week of sale. Equation (1) states that the price per head equals the sum of the marginal implicit values of each lot's characteristics times the yield of each characteristic (Ladd and Martin, Reference Ladd and Martin1976) and the price effect of each market force (Mintert et al., Reference Mintert, Blair, Schroeder and Brazle1990; Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Mintert, Brazle and Grunewald1988).

Equation (1) is estimated to get the marginal value of bred cow characteristics and market factors. Average price per head per lot is the dependent variable in equation (1). A log-log functional form is specified for all price variables. To account for location effects, common in the livestock literature, dummy variables are assigned to the seven reporting auctions. Price seasonality is accounted for by specifying a trigonometric functional form across weeks of the year. Previous research has included random effects for sale location and uses a mixed model approach to estimate the hedonic model (Williams et al., Reference Williams, Raper, DeVuyst, Peel and McKinney2012). Similarly, a random effect for each sale location/week combination is incorporated into equation (1). All other characteristics and market forces are treated as fixed effects. The empirical model estimated is

(2) \fontsize{10}{12} \selectfont{$$\begin{eqnarray} \ln \left( {Pric{e_i}} \right) &=& {\beta _0} + \sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^9 {{\beta _{1j}}Ag{e_{ij}}} + \sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^8 {{\beta _{2j}}MBre{d_{ij}}} + \sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^9 {{\beta _{3j}}W{t_{ij}}} \nonumber\\ &&+ \sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^4 {{\beta _{4j}}Qlt{y_{ij}}} + {\beta _5}Blac{k_i} + \sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^6 {{\beta _{6j}}Lo{c_{ij}}} + {\beta _7}\ln \left( {Cor{n_i}} \right) \nonumber\\ &&+\, {\beta _8}ln(Feede{r_i}) + \sum\nolimits_{(j = 1)}^2\left[ {{\beta _1}_{0j}cos\left( {\frac{{(2\pi t(i))}}{{26j}}} \right) + {\beta _1}_{1j}sin\left( {\frac{{(2\pi t(i))}}{{26j}}} \right)} \right]\nonumber\\ &&+\, {\mu}_{{s_{(i)}}} + {\varepsilon _i}, \end{eqnarray}$$}

where i is the observation number of reported categories of lots (i = 1, 2, . . ., 14,811); t(i) denotes the sale week of observation i; Pricei is the reported average price per head; Ageij represents dummy variables for age in years (3 years is reference); MBredij represents dummy variables for months bred (6 months bred is reference); Wtij represents dummy variables for cow weight in hundred pound ranges (901–1,000 lb. is reference weight); Qltyij represents dummy variables for cow quality (average quality is reference); Blacki equals 1 if hide color is black and 0 if hide color is nonblack; Locij represents dummy variables for sale location (Oklahoma City is reference); Corni is the closing corn futures price per bushel of the nearby contract for the trading day corresponding to the auction date; Feederi is the closing feeder cattle futures price per hundredweight (cwt.) of the nearby contract for the trading day corresponding to the auction date; 26j denotes the sinusoidal period; μs ( i ) is the random effect for each sale location and date combination; s(i) is the location/date combination for the ith observation; and εi is the random error term for each observation. Further description of variables is provided in Table 2.

Table 2. Description of Variables Used in the Bred Cow Hedonic Model

a When no trading occurred on the day of the sale, the previous day's closing feeder cattle and corn futures prices of the nearby contracts are used to reflect market conditions.

Previous research has modeled age and weight as linear terms, and often the significance of a quadratic term is tested (Faminow and Gum, Reference Faminow and Gum1986; Dhuyvetter et al., Reference Dhuyvetter, Schroeder, Simms, Bolze and Geske1996; Parcell, Schroeder, and Hiner, Reference Parcell, Schroeder and Hiner1995; Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Mintert, Brazle and Grunewald1988; Williams et al., Reference Williams, Raper, DeVuyst, Peel and McKinney2012). Rather than imposing a restrictive functional form, age and weight categories are included as indicator variables. Age was divided into 10 separate binary variables. Because the midpoint of each age range was used as the observation, there were 20 values that age could take. Age was rounded up to the nearest year. For example, an observation with a midpoint of 1.5 was rounded up to be 2 years. Similarly, 10 weight classes were included and assigned separate binary variables. Months bred ranges from 1 to 9 months bred. The average months bred is used as the observation for each lot; this created observations that were in 2-week increments. Months bred was rounded up to the nearest month, so that 5 months represents midpoints of 4.5 to 5 months. Nine separate binary variables were created for months bred.

The hedonic model is estimated with maximum likelihood using the MIXED procedure of SAS 9.4 (SAS Institute Inc., 2008). To estimate equation (2), an arbitrary reference lot of bred cows is selected. Three years of age is selected as the base age, and 901 to 1,000 lb. is chosen as the base weight class. Six months bred is selected as the base. Average quality is selected as the base quality. Oklahoma City is assigned as the base sale location. All estimated coefficients reflect price effects relative to the base lot.

One estimation concern is heteroskedasticity, particularly because of aggregation (Richter and Brorsen, Reference Richter and Brorsen2006). Results from a likelihood ratio test indicate the presence of heteroskedasticity arising from the variables sale volume, average weight, average age, and average months bred. Heteroskedasticity is corrected for by specifying multiplicative heteroskedasticity (Judge et al., Reference Judge, Griffiths, Hill, Kutkepohl and Lee1985) in the variance equation for the four variables as follows:

(3) $$\begin{eqnarray} E\left[ {e_i^2} \right] = \sigma _i^2 &=& {\rm{exp}}\big[ {\alpha _1} + {\alpha _2}CatVo{l_i} + {\alpha _3}AvgAg{e_i} \nonumber\\ &&+\, {\alpha _4}AvgW{t_i} + {\alpha _5}AvgMBre{d_i} \big], \end{eqnarray}$$

where AvgAgei , AvgWti , and AvgMbredi are the midpoints of each age, weight, and months bred range. CatVoli is the number of cows per category. As volume per category increases, a greater number of bred cows are aggregated into categories with similar age, weight, and months bred characteristics. Thus, as aggregation occurs over a greater number of cows, the variance of the error term is smaller.

4. Results

Parameter estimates for the bred cow hedonic model are included in Table 3. With such a large sample, most characteristics are significant at the 0.01 level. All coefficients have the expected sign. Estimates reveal significant price variation regionally and seasonally. Estimates denote percent premiums and discounts for all binary variables. Estimates for futures prices denote price elasticities. The following sections provide a discussion of each variable included in the bred cow pricing model.

Table 3. Hedonic Model Parameter Estimates of the Logarithm of Bred Cow Prices

a The random effect differs for every location and sale combination.

4.1. Effect of Cow Age

Age has a significant impact on the price received for bred cows with the exception of no significant difference between 4-year-old and 3-year-old bred cows. Bred heifers, coded as 1-year-olds, bring the greatest premiums; their respective price is 3.44% higher than 3-year-olds. Ten-year-old bred cows receive a price that is 21.05% below the price of 3-year-olds. Eight- and 9-year-olds bring discounts of 10.93% and 15.79%, respectively.

The magnitude of the effect for first-calf heifers requires some explanation. It was hypothesized that 2- and 3-year-old bred cow lots would bring the greatest premiums. First-calf heifers are more likely to have calving problems, especially those from a sale barn that may not be bred to a bull selected for calving ease. First-calf heifers are less likely to rebreed and often wean a lighter calf. However, the negatives are overshadowed by the longer useful life of a younger bred cow, which results in the high estimated premium.

Producers market both young replacements and older cull cows as bred. Buyers assign discounts at an increasing rate as cows age (Figure 2). Producers considering marketing older cows as bred should acknowledge the heavy discounts assigned as age increases. In some instances, it may be more beneficial for producers to market older cows as open rather than bred when slaughter value of the cows dominates reproductive value. As noted by Mintert et al. (Reference Mintert, Blair, Schroeder and Brazle1990), the intentions of the buyers are not known. However, the heavy discounts for age may be a result of cattle buyers purchasing cows for packing facilities.

Figure 2. Effect of Cow Age on the Logarithm of Bred Cow Prices (base age 3 years)

4.2. Effect of Cow Weight

Weight has a positive but diminishing impact on price (Figure 3). Cows weighing between 700 and 800 lb. receive a discount of 10.98%. Cows weighing between 1,601 and 1,700 lb. receive the greatest premium of 14.58%. In recent years, there has been a lot of discussion in the academic literature and popular press about optimal cow size and to some extent moderating the weight of the commercial beef cow (Doye and Lalman, Reference Doye and Lalman2011; Russell and Feuz, Reference Russell and Feuz2015; Schmid, Reference Schmid2013; Wareham, Reference Wareham2013). Using two pasture scenarios, Doye and Lalman (Reference Doye and Lalman2011) found that moderate-sized cows (1,000 lb.) were more profitable, in both cases, compared with big cows (1,400 lb.). Although their results varied depending on assumptions, Bir et al. (Reference Bir, DeVuyst, Rolf and Lalman2016) found that the lightest-weight cows they considered were most often the optimal cow size. Research has identified smaller cows as optimal, but we find buyers place the greatest value on heavier cows. Although the cows are marketed as bred, some of them could be purchased for slaughter, in which case the extra weight would be valuable.

Figure 3. Effect of Months Bred on the Logarithm of Bred Cow Prices (base months bred is 6 months)

The small marginal change in the value of weight at heavier weight classes brings to question the significance of the three heaviest weight classes relative to one another. We estimate least squares means and test for differences in least squares means to determine if the three heaviest weight classes do, in fact, receive significantly different prices. Table 4 results show that there is no significant difference in mean prices for the three weight classes of interest, but this is at least partly because of a smaller number of observations in the two largest categories. Further, it is important to note that although producers receive a significant premium for heavier cows, the price per pound received for heavier cows is less than that of lighter cows. For example, using least squares means from Table 4, cows weighing between 901 and 1,000 lb. have a mean price of $0.84/lb., whereas cows weighing between 1,401 and 1,500 lb. have a mean price of $0.63/lb.

Table 4. Means of Logarithmic Bred Cow Prices for Seven Oklahoma Auctions by Weight Class, January 2000–May 2015

a Means followed by the same letter are not significantly different at the P ≤ 0.05 level by differences in least squares means.

Note: Wt includes 10 binary variables for each hundred pound bred cow weight class.

4.3. Effect of Months Bred

Months bred has the expected impact on price. Early and midgestating cows bring discounts, whereas late-gestating cows bring premiums. The discounts assigned to early and midgestating cows range from 11.40% for 1-month bred cows to 1.62% for 5-month bred cows. Buyers pay the highest premiums (3.66%) for 8-month bred cows. There is less risk of losing a calf and lower production costs prior to the calf's birth, and revenue is received more quickly when producers purchase late-gestating cows. Nine-month bred cows do not receive a price significantly different from 6-month bred cows, but that may be partly the result of having few cows that are classified as being bred 9 months.

4.4. Effect of Hide Color and Cow Quality

Previous research has indicated that producers use hide color rather than breed to distinguish between classes of cattle (Bulut and Lawrence, Reference Bulut and Lawrence2007). Williams et al. (Reference Williams, Raper, DeVuyst, Peel and McKinney2012) find all other hide color classifications receiving discounts relative to black-hided calves. Bulut and Lawrence (Reference Bulut and Lawrence2007) report a premium of $3.34/cwt. for black-hide relative to nonblack feeder cattle. Similarly, Leupp et al. (Reference Leupp, Lardy, Daly, Wright and Paterson2009) estimate a premium of $3.48/cwt. for black calves sold in the fall. The only hide color reported for bred cows in AMS reports is black. As expected, black cows bring a premium of 6.86% relative to nonblack cows, which equates to a $5.70/cwt. premium above the average price. The estimate for hide color is larger for bred cows than those estimates found in the feeder cattle hedonic literature (Bulut and Lawrence, Reference Bulut and Lawrence2007; Leupp et al., Reference Leupp, Lardy, Daly, Wright and Paterson2009; Williams et al., Reference Williams, Raper, DeVuyst, Peel and McKinney2012).

Cow quality has breeding, calving, and health implications. Producers purchasing bred cows pay significant premiums for high and high-average quality cows. High and high-average quality bred cows garner premiums of 14.81% and 8.67%, respectively. Heavy discounts are assigned to cows perceived as low quality; the respective discount for low-quality cows is 13.78%. Lower quality may be a function of factors that cannot be changed (e.g., genetics) but may also reflect management of the cows (e.g., cows that are too thin).

4.5. Effects of Location and Seasonality

Results show significant spatial and seasonal bred cow price differences. Bred cows sold in all other locations receive significant premiums ranging from 2.03% at El Reno to 6.67% at Woodward relative to Oklahoma City. The premium estimates may reflect the cost of transporting cows from Oklahoma City to the more rural areas of the state where the majority of cow-calf operations are located. Buyers go to markets that are in close proximity to their ranches to invest in breeding animals.

To illustrate estimated price seasonality, the combined impact of the four estimated sine and cosine terms are plotted for a 52-week year (Figure 4). Buyers place the greatest value on cows sold in February and March. Prices are lowest in the summer and fall months, which is when producers are more likely to cull their herds. In addition, prices may be higher in late winter and spring as producers want to purchase cows in anticipation of summer grass pasture.

Figure 4. Seasonality of Logarithmic Bred Cow Prices for Seven Oklahoma Auctions

5. Conclusions

This research estimated hedonic prices of bred cow characteristics. Physical characteristics and market factors contribute significantly to the total value of a bred cow. Weight has a nonlinear impact on price, with cows weighing more than 1,000 lb. bringing premiums; cows weighing between 1,601 and 1,700 lb. receive the greatest premium of 14.58%. Retaining cows and marketing them during the third trimester can significantly increase value. Cows graded as low quality receive a substantial discount. Similar to previous studies, this research includes feeder cattle and corn futures prices to serve as proxy variables for market expectations (Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Mintert, Brazle and Grunewald1988; Zimmerman et al., Reference Zimmerman, Schroeder, Dhuyvetter, Olson, Stokka, Seeger and Grotelueschen2012). Results are consistent with previous research in that increases in corn futures prices have an adverse impact on bred cow prices, whereas increases in feeder cattle futures prices have a positive impact.

Animal and lot level auction data have been the most common source used in livestock hedonic studies (e.g., Avent, Ward, and Lalman, Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004; Bailey, Peterson, and Brorsen, Reference Bailey, Peterson and Brorsen1991; Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Mintert, Brazle and Grunewald1988; Schulz, Dhuyvetter, and Doran, Reference Schulz, Dhuyvetter and Doran2015). Another contribution of this research is the use of aggregate auction data. Although USDA-AMS reports prices and characteristics of all classes of cattle, no previous research has utilized these publicly available reports to assess the market value of livestock characteristics.

In an industry where marketing strategies are increasingly more important, the information presented here may allow producers to improve their cow-marketing practices. Future research should consider whether buyers may want to reduce the premiums they pay for larger cows. The results of this research could benefit both buyers and sellers of bred cows. Sellers receive significant premiums for marketing bred cows with traits that buyers deem valuable.

Footnotes

Helpful suggestions by Brian Adam and Kellie Raper on an earlier draft are gratefully acknowledged. We are thankful for data collection assistance provided by the Oklahoma City U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), Agricultural Marketing Service staff. Mitchell and Peel received support from the Breedlove Professorship of Agribusiness. Brorsen received funding from the Oklahoma Agricultural Experiment Station and USDA National Institute of Food and Agriculture, Hatch Project number OKL02939.

1 Data are from AMS market reports: KO LS753, KO LS157, KO LS752, KO LS151, KO LS757, KO LS760, and KOLS152.

2 Only the five most recent years of auction reports are publicly available through the AMS portal system.

References

Amadou, Z. “Value Enhancement Marketing Strategies for Cull Beef Cows.” Ph.D. dissertation, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, 2012.Google Scholar
Amadou, Z., Raper, K.C., Biermacher, J.T., Cook, B., and Ward, C.E.. “Net Returns from Feeding Cull Beef Cows: The Influence of Initial Body Condition Score.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 46,1(2014):139–55.Google Scholar
Avent, R.K., Ward, C.E., and Lalman, D.L.. “Market Valuation of Preconditioning Feeder Calves.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 36,1(2004):173–83.Google Scholar
Bailey, D.V., Brorsen, B.W., and Thomsen, M.R.. “Identifying Buyer Market Areas and the Impact of Buyer Concentration in Feeder Cattle Markets Using Mapping and Spatial Statistics.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77,2(1995):309–18.Google Scholar
Bailey, D.V., Peterson, M.C., and Brorsen, B.W.. “A Comparison of Video Cattle Auction and Regional Market Prices.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73,2(1991):465–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bir, C., DeVuyst, E.A., Rolf, M., and Lalman, D.. “Optimal Beef Cow Weights in the U.S. Southern Plains.” Unpublished working paper, Oklahoma State University, 2016.Google Scholar
Blank, S.C., Saitone, T.L., and Sexton, R.J.. “Calf and Yearling Prices in the Western United States: Spatial, Quality, and Temporal Factors in Satellite Video Auctions.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 41,3(2016):458–80.Google Scholar
Buccola, S.T. “ An Approach to the Analysis of Feeder Cattle Price Differentials.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62,3(1980):574–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bulut, H., and Lawrence, J.D.. “The Value of Third-Party Certification of Preconditioning Claims at Iowa Feeder Cattle Auctions.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 39,3(2007):625–40Google Scholar
Coatney, K.T., Menkhaus, D.J., and Schmitz, J.D.. “Feeder Cattle Price Determinants: An Hedonic System of Equations Approach.” Review of Agricultural Economics 18,2(1996):193211.Google Scholar
Dhuyvetter, K.C., Schroeder, T.C., Simms, D.D., Bolze, R.P. Jr., and Geske, J.. “Determinants of Purebred Beef Bull Price Differentials.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 21,2(1996):396410.Google Scholar
Doye, D., and Lalman, D.. “Moderate versus Big Cows: Do Big Cows Carry Their Weight on the Ranch?” Paper presented at the Southern Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Corpus Christi, TX, February 5–8, 2011.Google Scholar
Faminow, M.D., and Gum, R.L.. “Feeder Cattle Price Differentials in Arizona Auction Markets.” Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 11,2(1986):156–63.Google Scholar
Grunfeld, Y., and Griliches, Z.. “Is Aggregation Necessarily Bad?Review of Economics and Statistics 42,1(1960):113.Google Scholar
Gupta, K.L.Aggregation Bias in Linear Economic Models.” International Economic Review 12,2(1971):293305.Google Scholar
Judge, G.G., Griffiths, W.E., Hill, R.C., Kutkepohl, H., and Lee, T.. The Theory and Practice of Econometrics. 2nd ed. New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1985.Google Scholar
Ladd, G.W., and Martin, M.B.. “Prices and Demands for Input Characteristics.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 58,1(1976):2130.Google Scholar
Lancaster, K.J.A New Approach to Consumer Theory.” Journal of Political Economy 74,2(1966):132–57.Google Scholar
Lawrence, J.D. Profiting from the Cattle Cycle: Alternative Cow Herd Investment Strategies. Ames: Iowa State University, Beef Research Report, 2002.Google Scholar
Lee, K.C., Pesaran, M.H., and Pierse, R.G.. “Testing for Aggregation Bias in Linear Models.” Economic Journal 100,400(1990):137–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leupp, J.L., Lardy, G.P., Daly, R., Wright, C.L., and Paterson, J.A.. “Factors Influencing Price of North Dakota, South Dakota and Montana Feeder Calves.” Beef Cattle and Range Research Report. Fargo: North Dakota State University, 2009, pp. 4649.Google Scholar
Mallory, S., DeVuyst, E.A., Raper, K.C., Peel, D., and Mourer, G.. “Effect of Location Variables on Feeder Calf Basis at Oklahoma Auctions.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 41,3(2016):393405.Google Scholar
Marsh, J.M. “ Monthly Price Premiums and Discounts between Steer Calves and Yearlings.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67,2(1985):307–14.Google Scholar
Mintert, J., Blair, J., Schroeder, T., and Brazle, F.. “Analysis of Factors Affecting Cow Auction Price Differentials.” Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics 22,2(1990): 2330.Google Scholar
Parcell, J.L., Schroeder, T.C., and Hiner, F.D.. “Determinants of Cow-Calf Pair Prices.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 20,2(1995):328–40.Google Scholar
Peel, D.S., and Doye, D.. Cull Cow Grazing and Marketing Opportunities. Stillwater: Oklahoma Cooperative Extension Service, Oklahoma State University, Fact Sheet AGEC-613, 2008. Internet site: http://pods.dasnr.okstate.edu/docushare/dsweb/Get/Document-8252/AGEC-613web.pdf (Accessed August 2016).Google Scholar
Pesaran, M.H., Pierse, R.G., and Kumar, M.S.. “Econometric Analysis of Aggregation in the Context of Linear Prediction Models.” Econometrica 57,4(1989):861–88.Google Scholar
Richter, F.G.-C., and Brorsen, B.W.. “Aggregate versus Disaggregate Data in Measuring School Quality.” Journal of Productivity Analysis 25,3(2006):279–89.Google Scholar
Russell, J., and Feuz, D.. “The Optimal Cow Size for Intermountain Cow-Calf Operations.” Fact Sheet No. 3.767, Fort Collins: Colorado State University Extension Services, 2015. Internet site: http://extension.colostate.edu/topic-areas/agriculture/the-optimal-cow-size-for-intermountain-cow-calf-operations-3-767/ (Accessed July 2016).Google Scholar
Sasaki, K.An Empirical Analysis of Linear Aggregation Problems: The Case of Investment Behavior in Japanese Firms.” Journal of Econometrics 7,3(1978):313–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
SAS Institute Inc. SAS/STAT (R) 9.2 Users Guide. Cary, NC: SAS Institute Inc., 2008.Google Scholar
Schmid, K.Bigger Is Not Always Better: Finding the Right Sized Cow.” BeefResearch, November 22, 2013. Internet site: http://www.beefresearch.ca/blog/finding-the-right-sized-cow/ (Accessed July 2016).Google Scholar
Schroeder, T., Mintert, J., Brazle, F., and Grunewald, O.. “Factors Affecting Feeder Cattle Price Differentials.” Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 13,1(1988):7181.Google Scholar
Schulz, L., Dhuyvetter, K.C., and Doran, B.E.. “Factors Affecting Preconditioned Calf Price Premiums: Does Potential Buyer Competition and Seller Reputation Matter?Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 40,2(2015):220–41.Google Scholar
Schulz, L., and Gunn, P.. “Raising versus Buying Heifers for Beef Cow Replacement.” File B1-73, Ames: Iowa State University Extension and Outreach, Iowa State University, 2014. Internet site: https://www.extension.iastate.edu/agdm/livestock/html/b1-73.html (Accessed April 2016).Google Scholar
Shumway, C.R., and Davis, G.C.. “Does Consistent Aggregation Really Matter?Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 45,2(2001):161–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Theil, H. Linear Aggregation of Economic Relations. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1954.Google Scholar
Trapp, J.N.Investment and Disinvestment Principles with Nonconstant Prices and Varying Firm Size Applied to Beef-Breeding Herds.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 68,3(1986):691703.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turner, S.C., Dykes, N.S., and McKissick, J.. “Feeder Cattle Price Differentials in Georgia Teleauctions.” Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics 23,2(1991):7584.Google Scholar
Vestal, M.K., Lusk, J.L., DeVuyst, E.A., and Kropp, J.R.. “The Value of Genetic Information to Livestock Buyers: A Combined Revealed, Stated Preference Approach.” Agricultural Economics 44,3(2013):337–47.Google Scholar
Wareham, J.What Is the Ideal Cow Size?Drovers, August 13, 2013. Internet site: http://www.cattlenetwork.com/drovers/columns/What-is-the-ideal-cow-size-219406021.html (Accessed July 2016).Google Scholar
Williams, G.S., Raper, K.C., DeVuyst, E.A., Peel, D., and McKinney, D.. “Determinants of Price Differentials in Oklahoma Value-Added Feeder Cattle Auctions.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 37,1(2012): 114–27.Google Scholar
Zimmerman, L.C., Schroeder, T.C., Dhuyvetter, K.C., Olson, K.C., Stokka, G.L., Seeger, J.T., and Grotelueschen, D.M.. “The Effect of Value-Added Management on Calf Prices at Superior Livestock Auction Video Markets.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 37,1(2012):128–43.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Descriptive Statistics of Selected Bred Cow Characteristics for Seven Oklahoma Auctions, January 2000–May 2015

Figure 1

Figure 1. Example Bred Cow Auction Report (source: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Marketing Service)

Figure 2

Table 2. Description of Variables Used in the Bred Cow Hedonic Model

Figure 3

Table 3. Hedonic Model Parameter Estimates of the Logarithm of Bred Cow Prices

Figure 4

Figure 2. Effect of Cow Age on the Logarithm of Bred Cow Prices (base age 3 years)

Figure 5

Figure 3. Effect of Months Bred on the Logarithm of Bred Cow Prices (base months bred is 6 months)

Figure 6

Table 4. Means of Logarithmic Bred Cow Prices for Seven Oklahoma Auctions by Weight Class, January 2000–May 2015

Figure 7

Figure 4. Seasonality of Logarithmic Bred Cow Prices for Seven Oklahoma Auctions