Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-mlc7c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T06:42:40.012Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Management of Multiple Sources of Risk in Livestock Production

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 February 2021

Melissa G.S. McKendree*
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural, Food, and Resource Economics, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI, USA
Glynn T. Tonsor
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, Kansas State University, Manhattan, KS, USA
Lee L. Schulz
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Iowa State University, Ames, IA, USA
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Firm operators continually manage multiple sources of risk. In an application to cattle feedlot operations, our objective is to determine if producers view output price and animal health risks separately or jointly. We conduct a survey with a choice experiment placing operators in forward looking, decision-making scenarios, and capture information on past risk management approaches. Evidence regarding a relationship between animal health and output price risk mitigation is mixed and depends on the decision being made. Combined, these results provide new insight into how managers approach multiple risks when facing resource constraints.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s) 2021

Firms must continually manage multiple sources of risk while operating with a resource constraint, whether that firm is a commercial fishing operation (Smith and Wilen, Reference Smith and Wilen2005), a space shuttle tile manufacturer (Pate-Cornell, Reference Paté-Cornell1996), or a livestock producer. Economists recognize potential correlations between multiple sources of risk and understand trade-offs exist between risk mitigation strategies (Smith and Wilen, Reference Smith and Wilen2005). For example, Du et al. (Reference Du, Ifft, Lu and Zilberman2015) investigated the relationship between crop producers’ use of marketing contracts and crop insurance, two risk mitigation strategies. Furthermore, Smith and Wilen (Reference Smith and Wilen2005) determined commercial fishermen’s preferences for physical and financial risks are positively correlated. Similar to fishermen and crop producers, cattle feedlot operators face multiple sources of risk, which impact profitability.

Cattle feedlot operators buy feeder cattle (approximately 1 year of age, weighing between 600 and 1,000 pounds (lbs)), feed and care for them for about 6 months, and then sell fed (or live) cattle (finish weight between 1,200 and 1,400 lbs) to a beef processor.Footnote 1 Agricultural producers, including feedlot operations, face input and output price (marketing), production, human, legal, and financial risk (Crane et al., Reference Crane, Grantz, Isaacs, Jose and Sharp2013). Past literature has often focused on price or yield risk in isolation. Few studies have sought to understand the relationship between multiple risks and no study has investigated how feedlot producers actually manage these multiple risks. Our analysis seeks to fill this gap.

Price risk is one of the largest risks faced by producers (Belasco et al., Reference Belasco, Taylor, Goodwin and Schroeder2009; Goodwin and Schroeder, Reference Goodwin and Schroeder1994). Furthermore, beef cattle producers rank cattle price variability as one of the top potential risk factors on their operation (Hall et al., Reference Hall, Knight, Coble, Baquet and Patrick2003). Accordingly, research has largely focused on the role of futures and options markets to mitigate price risk from corn price increases (input), feeder cattle price increases (input), and live cattle price decreases (output) (Hart, Babcock, and Hayes, Reference Hart, Babcock and Hayes2001; Mark, Schroeder, and Jones, Reference Mark, Schroeder and Jones2000; Schroeder and Hayenga, 1988; Tonsor and Schroeder, Reference Tonsor and Schroeder2011). Recognizing the price risk faced by livestock producers, the 2000 Agricultural Protection Act extended crop insurance to livestock. The U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA) Risk Management Agency oversees two insurance programs to help livestock producers manage price risk, the Livestock Risk Protection (LRP) and Livestock Gross Margin (LGM) programs. In 2019, both LGM and LRP were enhanced to better suit needs of livestock producers including expanded coverage to all 50 states and increased subsidy rates (Feedstuffs, 2019).

In addition to price risk, feedlot operators face production risks that extend beyond feed conversion and average daily gain (ADG). Many factors in U.S. cattle marketing practices contribute to the potential disease risk and stress of incoming cattle including cattle commingled from different sources, traveling long distances, and abrupt changes in diet and feed intake (Step et al., Reference Step, Krehbiel, DePra, Cranston, Fulton, Kirkpatrick, Gill, Payton, Montelongo and Confer2008). Given that feedlots recognize the impact different calf management practices can have on feedlot performance and carcass quality, premiums exist for value-added programs which decrease disease and production risk such as source and age verification, preconditioning and weaning programs (Blank, Saitone, and Sexton, Reference Blank, Saitone and Sexton2016; Zimmerman et al., Reference Zimmerman, Schroeder, Dhuyvetter, Olson, Stokka, Seeger and Grotelueschen2012). Furthermore, animal disease events, like bovine spongiform encephalopathy in late 2003, may be rare, but are damaging, if not devastating, to operations that experience drastic reductions in output or spikes in production costs (Schroeder et al., Reference Schroeder, Pendell, Sanderson and McReynolds2015). For this analysis, we choose to focus on one potential health and disease risk mitigation strategy—procuring feeder cattle from a single known source.

When feedlot operators make placement decisions, they can procure the quantity of feeder cattle desired from a single seller or assemble feeder cattle from multiple sources. When placed in feedlots, feeder cattle must adapt to new environments, establish a social hierarchy, and adjust to a new diet (Rambo, Reference Rambo2014). Commingling feeder cattle from multiple sources into a single pen at the feedlot versus cattle being from a single source has been associated with higher morbidity rates due to increased stress and pathogen exposure, especially in studies of bovine respiratory disease (Edwards, Reference Edwards2010; O'Connor, Sorden, and Apley, Reference O'Connor, Sorden and Apley2005; Step et al., Reference Step, Krehbiel, DePra, Cranston, Fulton, Kirkpatrick, Gill, Payton, Montelongo and Confer2008). Furthermore, Step et al. (Reference Step, Krehbiel, DePra, Cranston, Fulton, Kirkpatrick, Gill, Payton, Montelongo and Confer2008) found that calves from single source tended to have higher ADG than calves in commingled pens or calves purchased from auction markets. Health costs were also less for calves from a single source that were weaned for 45 days prior to transport than those shipped immediately after weaning or commingled from multiple sources. Abidoye and Lawrence (Reference Abidoye and Lawrence2006) found that single source cattle had superior carcass quality, health, and performance than backgrounded or commingled preconditioned cattle. Therefore, single source cattle have been shown to decrease animal health and production risks compared to cattle of unknown backgrounds or commingled cattle.

Belasco et al. (Reference Belasco, Taylor, Goodwin and Schroeder2009) developed an ex-ante model of price and yield risks associated with cattle feeding, determining that both of these risks have statistically significant impacts on the conditional mean and variability of profits. However, no study has investigated how feedlot producers actually manage multiple risk sources. Our objective is to determine if feedlot producers manage output price risk and animal health risk as two separate and independent risks or if they manage them jointly. To accomplish this, we surveyed feedlot operators about their historical use of risk management strategies and risk attitudes. We also included a choice experiment where respondents made decisions in situations intentionally designed to meet this project objective. For output (live cattle) price risk management, we focus on producers’ use of futures hedging (buying/selling futures contracts or buying options contracts), forward contracts, other programs (e.g., LRP insurance, LGM insurance), or accepting cash (spot market) price at the time of sale. For animal health risk we focus on a producers’ management of animal health within their operation, specifically feeder cattle procurement. Determining if and what kind of relationship exists between animal health and output price risk mitigation can inform the development of more complete risk mitigation strategies.

The main contribution of this research is determining whether cattle feedlot operators manage output price and animal health risk independently or jointly. Operations have a fixed budget. Therefore, feedlot operators could decide to implement increased animal health risk mitigation strategies instead of hedging using futures market contracts (substitute relationship). Conversely, animal health and output price risk mitigation strategies could be complements. For example, management practices could decrease uncertainty in production and therefore operators could better match their production to futures contracts, increasing futures contract usage. This could possibly help explain past “surprises” by analysts when producers have hedged price risk less than scholars “expected” (Goodwin and Schroeder, 1994; Moschini and Hennessy, Reference Moschini, Hennessy, Gardner and Rausser2001).

1. Conceptual Model

Producers face uncertain outcomes when utilizing risk management practices. They will choose to implement a practice if their expected utility of profits when using the practice exceeds their expected utility of profits without the practice. Following Moschini and Hennessy (Reference Moschini, Hennessy, Gardner and Rausser2001), we assume feedlot operators make decisions on output price and animal health risk management by comparing the expected utility of profit from different scenarios. Assume feedlot operator $i$ will make decisions to maximize their expected utility:

(1) $$E U_i = E \left[ U_i \left( w_{0,i} + \tilde{\pi _i} \right) \right]$$

where $E{U_{i}}$ is the expected utility of feedlot operator i, ${w_{0,i}}$ is initial wealth, and $\tilde{\pi _i}$ is profit from the cattle feeding enterprise which is a random variable (i subscripts are hereafter omitted for convenience). Profit for the cattle feeding enterprise is the sum of profit per pen ( $b$ pens):

(2) $$\tilde{\pi} =\sum \limits_b \tilde{\pi _b}.$$

Profit per pen of cattle is a function of input and output prices and quantities. However, when feedlot operators place cattle there is uncertainty about prices and quantities—making profit a random variable. Following Moschini and Hennessy (Reference Moschini, Hennessy, Gardner and Rausser2001), profit can be rewritten as:

(3) $$\tilde{\pi} = PG (x;\ \tilde{e})- rx - K$$

where P is output price, $G ( x; \tilde{e})$ is a stochastic production function where realized output depends on the input vector $x$ and a random variable $\tilde{e}$ , $r\;$ is a vector of input prices, and $K\;$ is fixed costs. This framework can be adapted to feedlot operators’ decision-making under price and animal health risk, holding all else equal. In online supplementary Appendix A, we consider two demonstrative scenarios, allowing one risk type to vary while holding the other fixed.

One link between mitigating output price risk and utilizing animal health production practices could be the expectation of total pounds of finished cattle versus the actual pounds produced. Expected and actual pounds produced can vary from weather, animal disease, and management, among other factors. These production risks can result in reductions in ADG per animal or death loss. A large variance in pounds produced per pen could alter producers’ risk mitigation strategies. For example, feedlot operators may be less likely to establish an expected selling price because they cannot properly assess the number of futures contracts needed or specifications they should agree to in a forward contract. However, if animal health production practices decrease finishing weight variability and death loss, then operators may make more informed output price risk management decisions.

Substitute, complementary, or no relationship could exist between output price risk and animal health risk mitigation strategies. Risk mitigation strategies are not free and feedlot operations have a limited budget. A feedlot operator could decide the feedlot should only invest in animal health mitigation strategies instead of also managing output price risk—an example of substitution. Alternatively, operators could view output price and animal health risk mitigation strategies as complements. Instead there could be no relationship between feedlot operators’ decisions regarding price risk and animal health risk mitigation strategies. Determining this relationship is a core component of our analysis. We hypothesize there is some relationship between output price risk and animal health risk mitigation strategies. However, to investigate this hypothesis, we need to analyze individual feedlot operators’ decision-making.

2. Data Collection

Primary data were collected from feedlot operators, see online supplementary Appendix B for the survey instrument. The survey was programmed for Web application using Qualtrics software (Qualtrics Provo, UT, USA). Feedlots in Colorado, Iowa, Kansas, Nebraska, and Texas were surveyed. These states comprise five of the eight states in the widely cited, “5-market” average price reported by the USDA. Furthermore, these states house nearly 31% of U.S. feedlots with sales for slaughter and 76% of feedlot sales according to the 2017 Census of Agriculture (USDA-NASS, 2019a). The Colorado Livestock Association, Iowa Cattlemen’s Association, Kansas Livestock Association, Nebraska Cattleman, and Texas Cattle Feeders Association distributed a uniform resource locator through an email list of members. To increase survey response and expand distribution, Feedlot Magazine also distributed the survey web address to its subscribers.Footnote 2

After answering several introductory questions on the survey, respondents were asked to participate in a choice experiment. The respondent’s past use of risk management and attitudes concerning risk were also obtained in the survey.

The survey was live from January 19, 2017 to February 14, 2017.Footnote 3 There were 588 responses.Footnote 4 However, 232 participants who did not have a feedlot enterprise and/or did not make price or animal health risk management decisions were dismissed from the survey after the qualification questions. Additionally, 75 participants who qualified to continue but did not answer the choice experiment questions were excluded—reducing the useable sample to 281.

Table 1 reports selected survey respondent characteristics. The sample is representative of U.S. feedlot producers. Feedlot operators from Iowa comprise 50% of the sample, Nebraska 19%, Texas 10%, Kansas 6%, and Colorado 5%. According to the 2017 Census of Agriculture, there were 9,309 feedlot operations with sales for slaughter in these five states: 4% from Colorado, 59% from Iowa, 11% from Kansas, 22% from Nebraska, and 4% from Texas (USDA-NASS, 2019a). Fifty-eight percent of respondents are from operations with capacity over 1,000 head. With respect to December 1, 2017, the Census of Agriculture reports operations with 1,000 or more head of cattle on feed comprised 12% of feedlots from these five states but 86% of the cattle on feed inventory (USDA-NASS, 2019a). Thus, the operations within our sample are larger than the census average but do represent the majority of feedlot inventories.Footnote 5 Just over 20% of survey participants are considered custom feeders owning less than 40% of cattle in their feedlot.Footnote 6 According to the 2017 Census of Agriculture, in these five states 7% of farms custom fed cattle shipped directly for slaughter, accounting for 42% of the sales for slaughter (USDA-NASS, 2019a).

Table 1. Summary statistics

The average respondent age is 49 years old, with a minimum and maximum age of 23 and 85 years. In the 2017 Census of Agriculture, the simple average age of cattle feedlot producers was 55 for the five surveyed states (USDA-NASS, 2019b).Footnote 7 Given that our survey was administered online, the younger average age is expected. Nearly half of the participants have at least a Bachelor’s degree. This educational attainment is similar to other studies of beef producers. In McKendree, Tonsor and Wolf (Reference McKendree, Tonsor and Wolf2018), 51% of cow–calf producers surveyed had earned at least a Bachelor’s degree.

Participants were asked questions to gauge their risk aversion following the Global Risk-Attitude Construct (GRAC) defined in Pennings and Garcia (Reference Pennings and Garcia2001). It was determined that factor variables were not needed as only one GRAC question captures risk attitudes. Therefore, participants are considered risk averse (nearly 57%) if they somewhat agree, agree, or strongly agree with the statement, “I usually like ‘playing it safe’ (for instance, ‘locking in a price’) instead of taking risks for market prices for fed cattle.”

Since animal health and price risk management are of key interest, participants were asked about their past price determination methods and past feeder cattle sourcing. Participants were considered to actively manage animal health risk if they purchased feeder cattle from a single source. Nearly 65% of participants have purchased single source calves before. This finding is consistent with NAHMS beef feedlot 2011 study which found that 56.4% of feedlots had purchased feeder cattle through direct sales. However, direct sales accounted for less than 30% of feeder cattle purchased (USDA-APHIS-VS-NAHMS, 2013). Participants were also asked how they believed calves from a single source perform compared to calves sourced with unknown backgrounds (Table 2). Over 85% of producers stated single source calves performed somewhat or much better than calves from unknown backgrounds.Footnote 8

Table 2. Participants’ response to “Compared to calves sourced from auctions with unknown backgrounds, how do you believe calves from a single source ranch perform (i.e. average daily gain, feed conversion, morbidity) in the feedlot?”

There was variability in futures hedging and forward contracting behavior, with the percentage use of each ranging from 0 to 100% (Table 3). On average, participants hedged 19% of finished cattle using futures contracts and 18% utilized forward contracts (Tables 1 and 3). Spot cash market was the most frequently used with over 50% of producers selling at least 50% of their cattle this way. LRP insurance and LGM insurance were rarely used.

Table 3. Participants’ response to “In the past 12 months, what percentage of the following pricing methods did your operation use for marketing finished cattle (should sum to 100%)”

3. Research Methodology: Past Behavior

The survey contained two questions regarding past risk management behavior which serves as the first test of whether a relationship exists between price and animal health risk management. The first question was designed to identify feeder cattle sources. Respondents were asked to allocate the percentage (summing to 100%) for each source including traditional auction; satellite/video auction; purchased direct from seller (ranch); home raised from own cow-herd; custom fed, so I did not buy or own animals; and other. We choose to look at participants’ use of purchasing direct from seller (ranch) as the health risk mitigation strategy of interest. Participants were considered to mitigate animal health risk if they purchased feeder cattle directly from the seller (ranch). The second question was designed to identify pricing methods for marketing finished cattle. Respondents were asked to allocate the percentage (summing to 100%) for each method including spot cash market; forward contract or marketing agreement; futures hedge; options hedge; LRP insurance; LGM insurance; and other. Cattle marketed using the spot price only were considered to not be mitigating price risk.

Tobit models were utilized to estimate the relationship between past behavior of purchasing feeder animals direct from seller and output price risk management. The two latent variables of interest (indicated with a * subscript), the percent of feeder cattle purchased direct from seller ( $directseller_i^*$ ), and the percent of finished cattle marketed on the spot cash market ( $spot_i^*$ ) were modeled as:

(4) $$directseller_i^{*} = {\delta_1}spo{t_i} + {\bf\it X}_{direct,i}^{\rm{'}} {\it\bf \beta} _{direct} + {\varepsilon _{direct,i}}$$
(5) $$spot_i^* = {\delta_2}directselle{r_i} + {\bf\it X}_{spot,i}' {\it\bf \beta} _{spot} + {\varepsilon _{spot,i}}$$

where the relationships between the latent variables and the observed variables are

(6) $$directselle{r_i} = \left\{ {\matrix{ {directseller_i^{\rm{*}}} \cr {0} \cr {100} \cr } {\rm{}}\matrix{ {if\;{\rm{}}0 \le directseller_i^{\rm{*}} \le 100} \cr {if\;{\rm{}}directseller_i^{\rm{*}} \lt 0} \cr {if{\rm{}}\;directseller_i^{\rm{*}} \gt 100} \cr } } \right.$$
(7) $$spo{t_i} = \left\{ {\matrix{ {spot_i^*} \cr {0} \cr {100} \cr } \matrix{ {if\;0 \le spot_i^* \le 100} \cr {if\;spot_i^* \lt 0} \cr {if\;spot_i^* \gt 100.} \cr } } \right.$$

In equations (4) and (5), ${\delta _1}$ and ${\delta _2}$ are the coefficients of interest. ${\bf\it X}_{S,i}'$ (where $\;S = direct,\;spot$ ) is a vector of explanatory variables for each individual $i$ and an intercept, ${\it\bf \beta} _S$ are coefficient estimate vectors, and ${\varepsilon _{S,i}} \sim N\left( {0,\sigma _S^2} \right)$ . Equations (4) and (5) are estimated with maximum likelihood. Models were estimated using the cmp command in Stata (Roodman, Reference Roodman2011).

4. Results and Discussion: Past Behavior

Average marginal effects (AME) for historical single source feeder cattle purchases are shown in Table 4. Model A is the base model, including an intercept and past percent of finished animals priced only on the spot market. Model B includes three additional binary explanatory variables: 1,000+ head capacity equals 1 if the feedlot’s capacity is greater than or equal to 1,000 head, 0 otherwise; risk aversion equals 1 if participants somewhat agree, agree, or strongly agree with the statement, “I usually like ‘playing it safe’ (for instance, ‘locking in a price’) instead of taking risks for market prices for fed cattle.”, 0 otherwise; and custom feeder equals 1 if the operation owned less than 40% of the calves placed on feed in the last 12 months, 0 otherwise.

Table 4. Historical direct from seller average marginal effects (N = 278)

Notes: Robust standard errors are in parenthesis. * P < 0.10, ** P < 0.05, *** P < 0.01.

The historical spot marketing AMEs are statistically significant and similar in models A and B (Table 4). Based on model B, when the historical percentage of finished cattle priced on the spot market increases by 1%, the historical percentage of feeder cattle purchased direct from seller decreases by 0.09%. Thus, those who purchase single source feeder animals were also more likely to use output price risk management as opposed to pricing fed cattle on the spot cash market. Additionally, in model B, operations with 1,000+ head capacity historically purchased approximately 7% more of their feeder animals directly from sellers than smaller operations.

A relationship is also present between historical percentage of feeder cattle purchased direct from sellers and output price risk in models C and D (Table 5). Model C seeks to explain the historical percent of cattle priced on the spot market only (no price risk mitigation), controlling for an intercept, and the historical percent of feeder cattle purchased direct from seller. Model D includes additional explanatory variables for capacity, risk aversion, and custom feeders. Based on model D, a 1% increase in the historical percentage of feeder animals purchased direct from seller decreases head priced on the spot market by 0.18% (implying an increase in cattle marketed with some risk management technique). This is similar to the relationship found in models A and B, however, larger in magnitude. Additionally, larger operations and risk averse producers priced about 13% and 22% less of their finished animals on the spot market, respectively. Thus, larger feedlots and risk averse operators are more likely to use price risk mitigation strategies.

Table 5. Historical spot marketing of finished cattle average marginal effects (N = 278)

Notes: Robust standard errors are in parenthesis. * P < 0.10, ** P < 0.05, *** P < 0.01.

These regressions of past behavior suggest a relationship exists between animal health (purchasing feeder animals directly from sellers) and output price (spot market only versus establishing a selling price) risk mitigation strategies. Overall, there is a negative relationship between historical single source feeder animal purchases and solely pricing in the spot (cash) market. Conversely, a positive relationship exists between historical single source procurement and using an output price risk mitigation strategy (not solely using the spot market for price determination). The relationship between animal health and price risk mitigation is worth further investigating and the decision under consideration (feeder cattle procurement or output price hedging) is important when documenting the relationship.

These regressions do not control for other factors that might be considered in a producer’s risk mitigation decision. For example, source premium, basis, Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME) price, and the type of output price risk management strategy were not considered. Accordingly, we leverage the ability of choice experiments to better understand a feedlot operator’s decision-making regarding risk management and to control for other information that impacts a producer’s decision. Past studies of cattle producers that utilized surveys, including choice experiments, were successful in finding results consistent with market observations (Tonsor, Reference Tonsor2018; Schumacher, Schroeder, and Tonsor, Reference Schumacher, Schroeder and Tonsor2012; Schulz and Tonsor, Reference Schulz and Tonsor2010).

5. Research Methodology: Choice Experiment

Each respondent completed a choice experiment, designed to not be overly complex, which resembled a realistic turn of cattle in a feedlot and decisions regarding either feeder cattle procurement or live cattle marketing. To assess individual feedlot operators’ decision-making process, operators were placed in a realistic decision-making mindset where they were making decisions and forming expectations around events that will happen in the future. They were asked to make decisions as if it were February 15, 2017 for feeder animals being placed in March 2017 with an expected August 2017 closeout.

A seven-treatment design (Table 6) was utilized to test if a relationship exists between animal health and output price risk management. Comparing results across scenarios isolates differences of central interest, similar to Tonsor, Schroeder, and Lusk (Reference Tonsor, Schroeder and Lusk2013). The animal health, feeder cattle procurement practice of interest was known single source feeder steers versus feeder steers of unknown background. The live cattle output price risk management strategies were futures hedge, forward contract, other, or none (accept cash price at the time of sale). An additional difference across designs is how the expected futures basis was presented. The futures hedge basis was presented two ways: unambiguous (e.g., −$1.00/cwt) or ambiguous (e.g., 35% chance of being less than −$1.00/cwt and 65% chance of being greater than −$1.00/cwt) (Di Mauro and Maffioletti, Reference Di Mauro and Maffioletti2004). Basis ambiguity was included to understand how producers form their price expectations and how basis uncertainty might alter risk mitigation decisions.

Table 6. Split-sample design

Each participant was randomly assigned to one of the seven treatments (Table 6). Treatments fall into two broad categories consistent with the initial assessment of past behavior: feeder cattle procurement (treatments 1–3) or live cattle marketing (treatments 4–7). Treatments 1–3 consisted of two choice scenarios about procuring a lot of feeder steers, see Figure 1 for an example of treatment 2. Participants were given the following information:

“Single source feeder calves, originating from a single ranch of origin, are generally considered less risky than calves with unknown histories due to their better performance and lower morbidity at the feedlot. Suppose it is February 15th. You are looking to buy feeder steers for March placement with an expectation of August finish/sale. A sale lot of 150 feeder steers, which will weigh approximately 800 lbs each at placement, are available for purchase from a single known ranch for a premium of ${random premium}/cwt over cattle purchased at an auction from unknown sources.”

Figure 1. Treatment 2 example.

Note: The two questions were presented on successive screens and not simultaneously.

Then they were asked,

“Of the 150 head of feeder steers available from the single source ranch, how many would you purchase?”

In this first question, no output pricing information is given and the exact same initial question is given in treatments 1–3. However, in the second question additional potential output pricing information is provided as an information shock. In treatments 1 and 3, participants are provided information needed for a futures hedge, including the August CME live cattle futures contract price and expected local basis. In treatment 1, the futures basis is unambiguous, but is ambiguous in treatment 3. In treatment 2, information for a forward contract, including the August CME live cattle futures contract price and offered basis, is provided. By comparing responses across the two questions, we can test our core hypothesis as it relates to feeder cattle procurement.

Treatments 4–7 each include one scenario where the participant was told they just purchased 150 head of feeder steers for March placement which they expected to sell in August (Figure 2). A random August CME live cattle futures contract price was also provided. Treatments 4 and 5 are the base treatments where no feeder cattle source information was given. In treatments 6 and 7, participants were also told the steers were purchased from a single source and given a random premium paid (information shock). After this introductory information, participants were asked how many head they would place in each of the four output pricing strategies provided—futures hedge, forward contract, other output price strategy, or accept local cash price at the time of sale. In treatments 5 and 7, an ambiguous live cattle basis for futures hedges was presented while basis was unambiguous in treatments 4 and 6. By comparing responses across treatments, we can understand if/how producers alter decisions when animal health and price risks are individually versus jointly examined. In particular, treatments 4 and 6 (non-ambiguous basis) can be compared, and treatments 5 and 7 (ambiguous basis) can be compared. To keep the manuscript concise, methods and results for treatments 4–7 can be found in online supplementary Appendix C.

Figure 2. Treatment 7 example.

Values of key variables in the choice design were randomly drawn for each participant from a range selected to match current market conditions. The source premium shown ranged from $1.00 to $10.00/cwt (Blank, Saitone, and Sexton, Reference Blank, Saitone and Sexton2016), the August CME live cattle futures contract price ranged from $95.00 to $110.00/cwt (consistent with the market as of January 9, 2017), all basis numbers ranged from −$5.00 to $5.00/cwt (consistent with historical basis numbers from the Livestock Marketing Information Center [LMIC] [2016]), and the random ambiguous basis percent ranged from 1 to 99%.

The choice experiments were hypothetical; however, our instructions specifically stated, “[…]. It is important that you make your selection as if you were actually facing these choices in operation of your feed yard.” Cheap talk scripts, such as the one provided, have been shown to reduce hypothetical bias in choice experiment research (Cummings and Taylor, Reference Cummings and Taylor1999; Lusk, Reference Lusk2003; Tonsor and Shupp, Reference Tonsor and Shupp2011). Furthermore, Lusk and Schroeder (Reference Lusk and Schroeder2004) found that although total willingness to pay was overstated in hypothetical choice experiments, marginal willingness to pay was not statistically different across hypothetical and actual payment scenarios. Thus, hypothetical bias concerns are mitigated since our core hypotheses tests depend on net differences across treatments (Tonsor, Reference Tonsor2011).

Econometrically, systems of Tobit models are utilized because the dependent variables (either feeder cattle purchased or head placed in each output price risk strategy) are continuous but censored between 0 and 150. Using these methods, marginal effects can be calculated and compared across designs to identify if relationships exist between animal health risk mitigation and output price risk mitigation.

5.1. Feeder Cattle Placement Scenarios (Treatments 1–3)

For treatments 1–3, the two latent variables of interest (indicated with a * subscript) are the total head purchased when output pricing information is not shown ( $feederheadA_i^*$ ) and total head purchased when output price information is shown ( $feederheadB_i^*$ ). These variables can be modeled as:

(8) $$feederheadA_i^* = {\bf\it X'}_{A,i}{\it\bf\beta} _A + {\varepsilon _{A,i}}$$
(9) $$feederheadB_i^* = {\bf\it X'}_{B,i}{\it\bf\beta} _B + {\varepsilon _{B,i}}$$

where the relationships between the latent variables and the observed variables are

(10) $$feederheadA_i^{\rm{}} = \left\{ {\matrix{ {feederheadA_i^{\rm{*}}} \cr {0} \cr {150} \cr } {\rm{}}\matrix{ {if\;{\rm{}}0 \le feederheadA_i^{\rm{*}} \le 150} \cr {if\;{\rm{}}feederheadA_i^{\rm{*}} \lt 0} \cr {if{\rm{}}\;feederheadA_i^{\rm{*}} \gt 150} \cr } } \right.$$
$$feederheadB_i^{\rm{}} = \left\{ {\matrix{ {feederheadB_i^{\rm{*}}} \cr {0} \cr {150} \cr } {\rm{}}\matrix{ {if\;{\rm{}}0 \le feederheadB_i^{\rm{*}} \le 150} \cr {if{\rm{}}\;feederheadB_i^{\rm{*}} \lt 0} \cr {if\;{\rm{}}feederheadB_i^{\rm{*}} \gt 150.} \cr } } \right.$$

In equations (8) and (9), ${\bf\it X}_{k,i}'$ (where $k = A,\;B$ ) is a vector of information given in the question (e.g., source premium, CME price, basis) and explanatory variables for each individual $i$ , ${\it\bf \beta} _k$ are coefficient estimate vectors, and ${\varepsilon _{k,i}} \sim N\left( {0,\sigma _k^2} \right)$ . Equations (8) and (9) are modeled jointly with maximum likelihood. The error terms ${\varepsilon _{A,i}}$ and ${\varepsilon _{B,i}}$ are specified following a bivariate normal distribution with zero mean, standard deviations $\sigma _A^2$ and $\sigma _B^2$ , and correlation $\rho $ . By estimating these equations jointly, we can test if unobservable factors are impacting total head purchased in each question. If $\rho $ is zero, then the equations can be estimated independently (Cornick, Cox, and Gould, Reference Cornick, Cox and Gould1994).

6. Results and Discussion: Choice Experiment

Summary statistics by treatment are shown in Table 1. Responses per treatment ranged from 36 to 42.

For the following models, AMEs are reported in the article; however, model coefficient estimates are in online supplementary online supplementary Appendix E.

6.1. Purchasing Feeder Cattle (Treatment 1–3)

Recall, the difference between question A and question B is participants were presented additional information (an information shock) on potential output price risk mitigation strategies in question B (futures hedge information with non-ambiguous basis in treatment 1, forward contract in treatment 2, or futures hedge with ambiguous basis in treatment 3). Likelihood ratio tests were conducted to determine if observations from treatments 1–3 could be pooled. The hypothesis that observations from the three treatments could be pooled was not rejected $\left( {{{\rm X}^2} = 7.06,{\rm{\;}}P\;{\rm{value\;}}0.99} \right)$ . Therefore, there are no differences in responses to question B based on the output price risk mitigation information given or the ambiguous versus non-ambiguous basis presentation.

The bivariate model AME from the pooled feeder cattle procurement questions (treatments 1, 2, and 3) is in Table 7. The statistically significant $\rho $ (see online supplementary Appendix Table E.3) indicates there is a relationship between question A and B residuals. Thus, these questions should be estimated jointly. Model E is the base model with explanatory variables only for the information shown (source premium, CME price, and basis). Model F includes additional explanatory variables: binary variables for operation size, custom feeder, risk aversion, and if they have purchased single source cattle before.

Table 7. Pooled feeder cattle purchasing treatments average marginal effects (treatments 1–3)

Notes: Standard errors are reported in parenthesis. 95% confidence intervals are reported in square brackets. * P < 0.10, ** P < 0.05, *** P < 0.01.

The source premium AMEs are negative, statistically significant, and similar across both models E and F. Focusing on model F, a $1.00/cwt increase in the source premium decreases feeder steers purchased (from a maximum of 150) by 10.56 and 7.81 head in questions A and B, respectively. This indicates the willingness to purchase feeder cattle decreases as source premium increases. To test our hypothesis that a relationship exists between animal health and price risk mitigation strategies, we test if the source premium AMEs in questions A (no output price risk mitigation information) and B (output price risk mitigation information is given) are statistically different. The source premium marginal effects in questions A and B are statistically different from each other ( $P\,value = 0.09$ ) in model F and marginally different from each other ( $P\,value=\,0.11$ ) in model E. Thus, there is evidence that a relationship exists between animal health and price risk mitigation as operators were less sensitive to increases in source premium whenever output price risk mitigation information (CME price and basis) is given.

6.2. Discussion of Core Hypotheses in Treatments 1–3

Investigating the AMEs, there is evidence of a complementary relationship. Finding that the source premium AME when no output pricing information is given (question A) is larger in magnitude (more elastic) than when output price hedging information is given (question B) supports this conclusion. An increase in source premium would decrease profit per head. Overall, the output hedging information shocks decrease the sensitivity to an increase in source premium.

In consumer choice studies, willingness to pay estimates vary depending on the number and mix of attributes shown (Pozo, Tonsor, and Schroeder, Reference Pozo, Tonsor and Schroeder2012; Gao and Schroeder, Reference Gao and Schroeder2009). Therefore, we recognize that having more information presented (output price risk management information) could influence coefficients and marginal effects. However, the identified relationship between source premium and output price risk mitigation information is rational. If output prices are considered strong, then more feedlots will be interested in placing feeder steers and would potentially consider paying a premium for single source steers. By purchasing single source steers, producers reduce uncertainty on the animals’ performance, which in turn increases the likelihood of actually receiving higher output prices. Conversely, if output prices are weak, then feedlots will place fewer cattle and potentially ignore single source cattle premiums.

6.3. Discussion of Core Hypotheses in Treatments 4–7

Results for treatments 4–7 are in online supplementary Appendix C. To test the core hypothesis that a relationship between animal health risk and output price risk exists, the 95% confidence intervals from the decomposed AMEs are compared across the base treatments and those with the single source information shock.Footnote 9 There is no evidence that the single source information shock changes the AME of the output hedging information.

Multiple explanations for little evidence of a relationship between incoming cattle health risk and output pricing strategies exist. First of all, the hypothetical nature of the survey and how historical seasonality in profits partially align with any one-time assessment (Schulz, Reference Schulz2019) cannot be ignored. Furthermore, livestock producers do not necessarily hedge at the time of placement but can hedge at any time during the feeding period; this is especially true if the net price from the hedge is less than the breakeven price (Schulz, Reference Schulz2016). Our findings suggest that incoming cattle characteristics do not impact output hedging decisions (at least the source of cattle in our experiment). Potentially, feedlot operators largely ignore incoming cattle characteristics because the decision is already made, likely reflecting pre-existing business relationships, and cannot be changed. Thus, this sunk decision is not considered moving forward. Furthermore, potentially animal health and price risk mitigation are handled by different managers at the feedlot. Therefore, these risks are managed independently even if they could potentially be managed jointly. This issue of risks not being considered jointly in complex systems was noted in Pate-Cornell (Reference Paté-Cornell1996) when discussing tiles for space shuttles.

Alternatively, persistence of past behavior and existing relationships with live cattle buyers was present. There could be a high cost in switching output pricing or output risk management strategies. This could be a reason for little evidence of animal health risk mitigation information impacting output hedging decisions. In the U.S., there are approximately 729,000 operations with beef cows, over 30,000 feedlots (USDA-NASS, 2019a), and 650 beef packing plants, 179 of which harvest more than 1,000 head (USDA, 2017). Therefore, there are more options to buy feeder cattle than to sell these cattle once finished. This would support our finding of a relationship between incoming cattle and output pricing risk in the feeder cattle purchasing scenarios (treatments 1–3) but no relationship in the output pricing scenarios (treatments 4–7).

7. Conclusion and Implications

To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study seeking to understand feedlot operators’ decision-making regarding both animal health and output price risk management. Our objective was to determine if feedlot operators manage these two risks jointly or independently. The animal health practice of interest was single source steers while the output price risk management strategies were futures contracts, forward contracts, other, and none (accept cash price at the time of sale). An online survey was utilized to collect primary data from feedlot operators about their use of risk management tools, producer and operation characteristics, and views on risk mitigation. A split-sample choice experiment was used, placing feedlot operators in a forward-looking mindset to better understand their risk management decision-making. Treatments 1–3 asked operators feeder steer procurement oriented questions while treatments 4–7 were output pricing oriented scenarios.

Simple Tobit models of past feeder cattle procurement and output hedging identified a negative relationship between past purchases of feeder animals from a single source and sole use of spot markets in marketing (no price risk mitigation). Therefore, a positive relationship is implied between animal health and output price risk mitigation. The split-sample choice experiment allowed for a deeper understanding of this relationship.

Using treatments 1–3, evidence of a complementary relationship between willingness to pay a source premium and output pricing information was found. Willingness to purchase single source cattle was more inelastic when output pricing information was provided. This complementary relationship could be one reason why producers do not hedge output price risk as much as analysts expect. Potentially, if more single source cattle were available, or offered at a lower premium, producers would increase their use of output price hedging. Furthermore, since there is less uncertainty in single source feeder steers performance in the feedlot (e.g., finish weight, death loss, etc.), producers could more confidently match their production to futures and forward contract specifications.

No evidence of a relationship was found between information on feeder cattle source and output pricing risk mitigation strategies in treatments 4–7. All of the AMEs for price risk management variables were not statistically different across treatments whether single source information was given or not, and many were insignificant. Potentially, these findings suggest that feedlot operators view the feeder cattle purchase as a “sunk decision” when deciding how to manage output price risk. Therefore, producers only consider another risk mitigation strategy when that decision is still applicable. Additionally, there was evidence of persistent behavior in output price hedging. This could be the result of existing relationships with cattle buyers and the relatively limited number of outlets to sell finished cattle. Potentially, this persistence could also stem from unfamiliarity with other output pricing strategies and high switching cost. The lack of a relationship between single source information and output pricing strategies could also be a function of the mitigation strategies considered. In the live cattle marketing options, no distinction was made regarding cattle quality. Conceivably, single source cattle might grade better at harvest and receive quality premiums (for those using grid pricing); however, this was not accounted for in our scenarios.

Our study is the first to look at the relationship in feedlot producers’ decision-making regarding animal health and price risk. However, there are limitations. First, a hypothetical choice experiment and self-reported survey data were used. However, by making comparisons across treatments, hypothetical bias concerns are minimized (Lusk and Schroeder, Reference Lusk and Schroeder2004; Tonsor, Reference Tonsor2011). Additionally, we recognize choice experiment findings are a function of the attributes chosen—here animal health and risk mitigation strategies (Gao and Schroeder, Reference Gao and Schroeder2009; Pozo, Tonsor, and Schroeder, Reference Pozo, Tonsor and Schroeder2012). Feedlots animal health risk mitigation strategies can be complex and dynamic. To keep the survey manageable for producer participants, we chose to proxy animal health risk mitigation with single source cattle procurement. Furthermore, there could be other benefits of single source cattle, such as lower transaction costs, that are not accounted for in this analysis. Future research could consider more complex designs to capture producers’ trade-offs in risk management decisions, or if available, use information on feedlots’ actual usage of different risk mitigation strategies.

Our findings are relevant to ongoing policy discussions regarding livestock producers’ use of LGM and LRP programs. In 2019, increased subsidy rates and other enhancements were made to these programs to better suit livestock producers needs with the hope of increasing participation. For example, effective July 1, 2019, the LRP subsidy rate increased from 13% for all coverage levels to 20–35% based on selected coverage level (Feedstuffs, 2019). Additional changes to premiums are being considered in 2020 for the 2021 marketing year (Reference WillisWillis, 2020). Our results suggest that the effectiveness of these subsidy rates at incentivizing participation will also depend on other risk mitigation strategies in place. For example, the sensitivity of participation to the subsidy rates might be less than expected if producers are also managing animal health risk. Therefore, it is important to consider other types of risk mitigation efforts that an operation may be using in addition to price risk mitigation when designing policy instruments and estimating participation.

Acknowledgements

The authors thank the Colorado Livestock Association, Feedlot Magazine, Iowa Cattlemen’s Association, Kansas Livestock Association, Nebraska Cattleman, and Texas Cattle Feeders Association for their collaboration.

Financial disclosure

This work was partially supported by USDA-NIFA Hatch under project 1016533, and multistate project 1014091.

Conflict of interest

None.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/aae.2020.31

Footnotes

1 For overview of the beef industry, see figure 1 pp 6 of U.S. Government Accountability Office (2018).

2 An operation could have received an invitation from multiple sources (i.e., their state cattlemen’s association and Feedlot Magazine). However, the “prevent ballot box stuffing” option was used in Qualtrics to prevent participants from taking the survey more than once.

3 Feedlot Magazine sent the survey invitation on January 19 and 26, Iowa Cattlemen’s Association on January 19 and 26, Kansas Livestock Association on January 19 and 30, Nebraska Cattleman on January 23 and 30, Texas Cattle Feeders Association on January 24 and 30, and Colorado Livestock Association on February 8.

4 The authors did not have access to the email lists of possible participants as the partner organizations sent the invitations to participants. Therefore, we do not know the total number of operations who received an invitation to complete the survey. As such, no response rate could be calculated because there was no defined sample.

5 The census definition of a farm is any place that produced and sold, or normally would have sold, $1,000 or more of agricultural products during the census year (USDA-NASS, 2019a).

6 The custom feeder determination was made by the researchers such that the majority of animals fed were not owned by the feedlot.

7 The cattle feedlots (North American Industry Classification System [NAICS] 112112) industry was used and comprises establishments primarily engaged in feeding cattle for fattening (OMB, 2017).

8 A reviewer aptly pointed out single source feeder calves, originating from a single ranch of origin, may not be the only source of calves that are considered less risky from an animal health standpoint. First, stocker producers could decrease animal health risk by commingling cattle and then selling them as large lots either through a traditional auction, satellite/video auction, or some other method to feedlot operators. Second, producers exist who market feeder cattle after commingling them from multiple sources who have a reputation for putting together low risk cattle from a health standpoint. We agree, however, this does not necessarily diminish the importance of single source calves to producers. To examine how these two factors may impact how feedlot producers perceive the value of single source calves, we estimated two cross tabulations from the survey data used for this analysis. Specifically, (1) “Compared to calves sourced from auctions with unknown backgrounds, how do you believe calves from a single source ranch perform (i.e. average daily gain, feed conversion, morbidity) in the feedlot?” and “What is the average placement weight of calves your feeding operation places in March?” and (2) “Compared to calves sourced from auctions with unknown backgrounds, how do you believe calves from a single source ranch perform (i.e. average daily gain, feed conversion, morbidity) in the feedlot?” and “How important is seller reputation for the feeder cattle you buy?” Using Persons ${\chi ^2}$ , we find no statistical differences in either cross-tabulation. Thus, there is additional evidence of the value single known source feeder cattle to feedlot buyers. See online supplementary appendix D for cross-tabulations and explanations.

9 Schenker and Gentleman (Reference Schenker and Gentleman2001) found that comparison of 95% confidence intervals is more conservative than standard methods of significance testing when the null hypothesis is true and falsely rejects the null hypothesis more frequently when the null hypothesis is false.

References

Abidoye, B.O., and Lawrence, J.D.. “Value of Single Source and Backgrounded Cattle as Measured by Health and Feedlot Profitability.” Paper presented at the NCR-134 Conference in St. Louis, Missouri, April 17–18, 2006. Internet site: https://ideas.repec.org/p/ags/ncrsix/19008.html Google Scholar
Belasco, E., Taylor, M., Goodwin, B., and Schroeder, T.. “Probabilistic Models of Yield, Price, and Revenue Risks for Fed Cattle Production.Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, 41(2009):91105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blank, S.C., Saitone, T.L., and Sexton, R.J.Calf and Yearling Prices in the Western United States: Spatial, Quality, and Temporal Factors in Satellite Video Auctions.Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 41,3(2016):458–80.Google Scholar
Cornick, J., Cox, T.L., and Gould, B.W.. “Fluid Milk Purchases: A Multivariate Tobit Analysis.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76(1994):7482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crane, L., Grantz, G., Isaacs, S., Jose, D., and Sharp, R.. Introduction to Risk Management. Extension Risk Management Education and Risk Management Agency report, 2013. Internet site: http://extensionrme.org/pubs/introductiontoriskmanagement.pdf (Accessed April 30, 2019).Google Scholar
Cummings, R.G., and Taylor, L.O.Unbiased Value Estimates for Environmental Goods: A Cheap Talk Design for the Contingent Valuation Method.” American Economic Review 89,3(1999):649–65. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.3.649 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Di Mauro, C., and Maffioletti, A.. “Attitudes to Risk and Attitudes to Uncertainty: Experimental Evidence.Applied Economics 36(2004):357–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Du, X., Ifft, J., Lu, L., and Zilberman, D.. “Marketing Contracts and Crop Insurance.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 97,5(2015):1360–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, T.A.Control Methods for Bovine Respiratory Disease for Feedlot Cattle.Veterinary Clinics of North America: Food Animal Practice 26,2(2010):273–84. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cvfa.2010.03.005 Google ScholarPubMed
Executive Office of the President Office of Management and Budget (OMB). North American Industry Classification System. Report for the Executive Office of the President of the United States, 2017. Internet site: https://www.census.gov/eos/www/naics/2017NAICS/2017_NAICS_Manual.pdf (Accessed April 26, 2019).Google Scholar
Gao, Z., and Schroeder, T.C.. “Effects of Label Information on Consumer Willingness-to-Pay for Food Attributes.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 91(2009):795809.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodwin, B.K., and Schroeder, T.C.. “Human Capital, Producer Education Programs, and the Adoption of Forward-Pricing Methods.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76,4(1994):936–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, D.C., Knight, T.O., Coble, K.H., Baquet, A.E., and Patrick, G.F.. “Analysis of Beef Producers” Risk Management Perceptions and Desire for Further Risk Management Education.Review of Agricultural Economics 25,2(2003):430–48. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9353.00148 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, C.E., Babcock, B.A., and Hayes, D.J.. “Livestock Revenue Insurance.Journal of Futures Markets 21(2001):553–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Livestock Marketing Information Center (LMIC) [dataset]. Livestock Marketing Information Center Spreadsheets, 2016. Internet site: https://www.lmic.info/members/spreadsheets (Accessed November 9, 2016).Google Scholar
Lusk, J.L.Effects of Cheap Talk on Consumer Willingness-to-Pay for Golden Rice.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85,4(2003):840–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lusk, J.L., and Schroeder, T.C.. “Are Choice Experiments Incentive Compatible? A Test with Quality Differentiated Beef Steaks.American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 86(2004):467–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mark, D.R., Schroeder, T.C., and Jones, R.D.. “Identifying Economic Risk in Cattle Feeding.Journal of Agribusiness 18(2000):331–44.Google Scholar
McKendree, M.G.S., Tonsor, G.T., and Wolf, C.A.. “Animal Welfare Perceptions of the U.S. Public and Cow-Calf Producers.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 50,4(2018):544–78. https://doi.org/10.1017/aae.2018.14 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moschini, G. Hennessy, D.A.Uncertainty, Risk Aversion, and Risk Management for Agricultural Producers.Handbook of Agricultural Economics. Gardner, B.L. and Rausser, G.C., eds. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers, 2001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Connor, A.M., Sorden, S.D., and Apley, M.D.. “Association Between the Existence of Calves Persistently Infected with Bovine Viral Diarrhea Virus and Commingling on Pen Morbidity in Feedlot Cattle.” American Journal of Veterinary Research 66,12(2005):2130–4. https://doi.org/10.2460/ajvr.2005.66.2130 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paté-Cornell, M.E.Global Risk Management.Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 12,2–3(1996):239–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pennings, J.M.E., and Garcia, P.. “Measuring Producers” Risk Preferences: A Global Risk-Attitude Construct.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 83(2001):9931009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pozo, V.F., Tonsor, G.T., and Schroeder, T.C.. “How Choice Experiment Design Affects Estimated Valuation of Use of Gestation Crates.Journal of Agricultural Economics 63(2012):639–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Qualtrics. (n.d.). Qualtrics (Version 2017). Internet site: https://www.qualtrics.com (Accessed February 15, 2017).Google Scholar
Rambo, N.K. “Health and Nutritional Strategies for Managing Incoming Feedlot Cattle.” Iowa State University Digital Repository, 2014. Internet site: https://lib.dr.iastate.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1022&context=driftlessconference (Accessed April 6, 2016).Google Scholar
Roodman, D.Fitting Fully Observed Recursive Mixed-Process Models with CMP.Stata Journal 11(2011):159206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schenker, N., and Gentleman, J.F.. “On Judging the Significance of Differences by Examining the Overlap between Confidence Intervals.The American Statistician 55(2001):182–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schroeder, T.C., and Hayenga, M.L.. “Comparison of Selective Hedging and Options Strategies in Cattle Feedlot Risk Management.Journal of Futures Market 8(1988):141–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schroeder, T., Pendell, D., Sanderson, M., and McReynolds, S.. “Economic Impact of Alternative FMD Emergency Vaccination Strategies in the Midwestern United States.Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 47(2015):4776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schulz, L.L. How Often Can Cattle Feeders Hedge a Profit with Futures? Iowa State University Extension and Outreach Ag Decision Maker report, 2016. Internet site: https://www.extension.iastate.edu/agdm/livestock/html/b2-54.html (Accessed April 30, 2019).Google Scholar
Schulz, L.L. Monthly Cattle Feeding Returns. Iowa State University Extension and Outreach Ag Decision Maker report, April 2019. Internet site: https://www.extension.iastate.edu/agdm/livestock/html/b1-36.html (Accessed April 30, 2019).Google Scholar
Schulz, L.L., and Tonsor, G.T.. “Cow- Calf Producer Preferences for Voluntary Traceability Systems.Journal of Agricultural Economics 61(2010):138–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumacher, T., Schroeder, T.C., and Tonsor, G.T.. “Willingness-to-Pay for Calf Health Programs and Certification Agents.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 44(2012):191202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, M.D., and Wilen, J.E.. “Heterogeneous and Correlated Risk Preferences in Commercial Fishermen: The Perfect Storm Dilemma.Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 31,1(2005):5371. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-005-2930-7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Step, D.L., Krehbiel, C.R., DePra, H.A., Cranston, J.J., Fulton, R.W., Kirkpatrick, J.G., Gill, D.R., Payton, M.E., Montelongo, M.A., and Confer, A.W.. “Effects of Commingling Beef Calves from Different Sources and Weaning Protocols During a Forty-Two-Day Receiving Period on Performance and Bovine Respiratory Disease.Journal of Animal Science 86,11(2008):3146–58.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tonsor, G.T.Consumer Inferences of Food Safety and Quality.European Review of Agricultural Economics 38,2(2011):213–35. https://doi.org/10.1093/erae/jbr011 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tonsor, G.T.Producer Decision Making under Uncertainty: Role of Past Experiences and Question Framing.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 100,4(2018):1120–35. https://doi.org/10.1093/ajae/aay034 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tonsor, G.T., and Schroeder, T.C.. “Multivariate Forecasting of a Commodity Portfolio, Application to Cattle Feeding Margins and Risk.Applied Economics 43(2011):1329–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tonsor, G.T., Schroeder, T.C., and Lusk, J.L.. “Consumer Valuation of Alternative Meat Origin Labels.Journal of Agricultural Economics 64(2013):676–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tonsor, G.T., and Shupp, R.S.. “Cheap Talk Scripts and Online Choice Experiments: Looking Beyond the Mean.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 93(2011):1015–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA). United States Livestock Slaughter. Washington, DC: National Agricultural Statistics Service report, April 2017. Internet site: https://www.nass.usda.gov/Publications/Todays_Reports/reports/lstk0417.pdf (Accessed May 24, 2017).Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Agriculture, Animal and Plant Health Inspection Service, Veterinary Services, National Animal Health Monitoring System (USDA-APHIS-VS-NAHMS). Feedlot 2011 Part IV: Health and Health Management on U.S. Feedlots with a Capacity of 1,000 or More Head. Report No. 638.0913, 2013. Internet site: https://www.aphis.usda.gov/animal_health/nahms/feedlot/downloads/feedlot2011/Feed11_dr_PartIV.pdf (Accessed April 26, 2019).Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service (USDA-NASS). 2017 Census of Agriculture, United States Summary and State Data. Volume 1, Geographic Area Series, Part 51, April 2019a. Internet site: https://www.nass.usda.gov/Publications/AgCensus/2017/Full_Report/Volume_1,_Chapter_1_US/usv1.pdf (Accessed April 26, 2019).Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service (USDA-NASS). Selected Producers” Characteristics by North American Industry Classification System, 2019b. Internet site: https://www.nass.usda.gov/Publications/AgCensus/2017/Online_Resources/Census_Data_Query_Tool/index.php (Accessed April 26, 2019).Google Scholar
U.S. Government Accountability Office. Additional Data Analysis Could Enhance Monitoring of U.S. Cattle Market. Report to Congressional Requesters No. GAO-18-296, 2018. Internet site: https://www.gao.gov/assets/700/691178.pdf (Accessed April 26, 2019).Google Scholar
Willis, B. “USDA”s Livestock Risk Protection Deserves a Second Look.” Drovers. Internet site: https://www.drovers.com/article/usdas-livestock-risk-protection-deserves-second-look (Accessed August 11, 2020).Google Scholar
Zimmerman, L.C., Schroeder, T.C., Dhuyvetter, K.C., Olson, K.C., Stokka, G.L., Seeger, J.T., and Grotelueschen, D.M.. “The Effect of Value-Added Management on Calf Prices at Superior Livestock Auction Video Markets.Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 37,1(2012):128–43.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Summary statistics

Figure 1

Table 2. Participants’ response to “Compared to calves sourced from auctions with unknown backgrounds, how do you believe calves from a single source ranch perform (i.e. average daily gain, feed conversion, morbidity) in the feedlot?”

Figure 2

Table 3. Participants’ response to “In the past 12 months, what percentage of the following pricing methods did your operation use for marketing finished cattle (should sum to 100%)”

Figure 3

Table 4. Historical direct from seller average marginal effects (N = 278)

Figure 4

Table 5. Historical spot marketing of finished cattle average marginal effects (N = 278)

Figure 5

Table 6. Split-sample design

Figure 6

Figure 1. Treatment 2 example.Note: The two questions were presented on successive screens and not simultaneously.

Figure 7

Figure 2. Treatment 7 example.

Figure 8

Table 7. Pooled feeder cattle purchasing treatments average marginal effects (treatments 1–3)

Supplementary material: PDF

McKendree et al. supplementary material

McKendree et al. supplementary material

Download McKendree et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 315 KB