1. Introduction
One approach for reducing soil loss caused by poorly managed pasture is to offer beef cattle producers incentives to adopt best pasture management practices (BMPs). Research on the voluntary adoption of BMPs is extensive (Baumgart-Getz, Prokopy, and Flores, Reference Baumgart-Getz, Prokopy and Flores2012; Knowler and Bradshaw, Reference Knowler and Bradshaw2007; Liu, Bruins, and Heberling, Reference Liu, Bruins and Heberling2018; Pannell, Llewellyn, and Corbeels, Reference Pannell, Llewellyn and Corbeels2014; Prokopy et al., Reference Prokopy, Floress, Klotthor-Weinkauf and Baumgart-Getz2008). A number of these studies focus on forage or pasture BMPs adopted by livestock producers (e.g., Gillespie, Kim, and Paudel, Reference Gillespie, Kim and Paudel2007; Jensen et al., Reference Jensen, Lambert, Clark, English, Yu, Larson, Holt and Hellwinckel2015; Kim, Gillespie, and Paudel, Reference Kim, Gillespie and Paudel2005, Reference Kim, Gillespie and Paudel2008). Examples of these BMPs include rotational grazing, water tanks, stream crossings, and pasture rehabilitation. The private benefits of managing pasture with one or a combination of these practices include increased forage yield, reduction in soil erosion, and improved herd health. Off-site benefits from implementing these practices include reduced sediment loading into streams and waterways, improved water quality, and increased use and nonuse values. The private benefits to producers from adopting BMPs are offset by the costs of structure installation and maintenance. From the perspective of an agency mediating public demand for off-site water quality improvements, adoption incentives are expected to increase the provision of off-sitebenefits by tilting the calculus of private operators in favor of BMP adoption. Given adoption, the extent or intensity with which a producer implements a technology is also expected to be positively related to the incentives provided (Smale and Heisey, Reference Smale and Heisey1993).
Information asymmetries between producers and implementing agencies and heterogeneity across producers and landscapes complicate the analysis of the effects incentives have on BMP adoption and the desired off-site environmental outcomes. Variations in producer willingness to adopt arise from differences in BMP suitability and effectiveness in promoting livestock production, while variations in BMP effectiveness in reducing environmental externalities can be traced to heterogeneity in landscape features and other farm and farmer characteristics. These differences manifest directly or indirectly through differences in the scope and scale at which a BMP is adopted, which can also lead to variation in performance effectiveness.
This research analyzes the results of a hypothetical choice experiment from a mail survey to elicit the willingness of beef cattle producers to adopt four pasture BMPs—rotational grazing, water tanks, stream crossings, and pasture rehabilitation—in the Oostanaula Creek watershed in East Tennessee (Hydrologic Unit Code TN06020002083;Footnote 1 details of BMPs in online supplementary Appendix I). Each of these BMPs confers both on-site (private) benefits, such as increased forage productivity, and off-site (public) benefits, such as improved water quality. Pasture improvement requires reseeding or planting grasses to increase forage yield and repair overgrazed areas (bare spots) and erosion. Water tank systems provide cattle a source of water other than streams or ponds, thereby increasing pasture utilization and reducing nutrient and sediment loading to streams. Stream crossings protect stream banks from erosion. Rotational grazing enhances forage quality and productivity by resting pasture.
Adoption of a practice is a discrete event (adoption/nonadoption), whereas the intensity (or scale) of implementation is a continuous variable (e.g., acres allocated to rotational grazing) or count (e.g., water tanks). In this study, estimation of producer response to monetary incentives maintains economic conditions consistent with profit maximizing behavior. To the authors’ knowledge, this study is the first to use a choice experiment to estimate pasture BMP adoption as a theoretically consistent system of supply equations that integrates to an indirect profit function. Best management practice supply functions are modeled as a censored system using a two-step estimation procedure while imposing convexity. An empirical application links the supply function estimates with a biophysical simulation model to determine the effect of changing incentive levels on sediment reduction. We adopt the optimization approach suggested by Govindasamy and Huffman (Reference Govindasamy and Huffman1993), Govindasamy and Cochran (Reference Govindasamy and Cochran1995), and Smith et al. (Reference Smith, Williams, Nejadhashemi, Woznicki and Leatherman2014). Smith et al. find that targeted BMP programs are more cost effective than those “randomly” implemented with an incentive equally mandated throughout a watershed. The optimization approach we apply here builds on their premise but parameterizes sedimentation reduction with econometric estimates of producer willingness to adopt and implement pasture BMPs. Applications of this method could encourage agencies to consider ex ante the effects of both own- and cross-incentive elasticities on BMP adoption and sediment abatement when setting incentives for complementary BMPs.
2. Conceptual model
The pasture BMPs analyzed are designed to increase forage productivity and reduce sedimentation. Components of forage management considered here include rotational grazing (R) and pasture improvement (P). Producers can augment forage productivity by rotating cattle on pasture and reestablishing grasses and legumes on bare soils. Cattle have access to water tanks (W) in enclosed paddocks. Producers may also connect paddocks on opposite sides of a stream with fenced crossings (stream crossings, S) to stabilize stream banks and ensure animal safety.
The changes in net revenue ($\Delta \pi$) livestock producers might expect from accepting an incentive to adopt a BMP are approximated with a symmetric normalized quadratic indirect profit function (SNQ) (Diewert and Wales, Reference Diewert and Wales1987; Kohli, Reference Kohli1993). The SNQ approximation is a linearly homogeneous, flexible functional form that allows the signs of cross-price elasticities to be unrestricted (Diewert and Wales, Reference Diewert and Wales1987). The advantage of the SNQ system, rather than the “standard” normalized quadratic profit function (Chambers, Reference Chambers1988), is that one need not arbitrarily designate a netput as a numeraire. As Paudel and McIntosh (Reference Paudel and McIntosh2007) indicated, the signs and magnitudes of elasticties calculated from the standard form of the normalized quadratic profit function may vary, depending on the numeraire choice.
Returns from adopting a practice are approximated as a second-order expansion around an arbitrary normalized indirect profit function with incentives (v) the decision variable,
where ℓ = P, R, W, S; index m aliases ${\ell}$; i indexes producers; ${\rm{o}}\left( {{u_i}} \right)$ is a truncation remainder of the expansion with an expected mean of zero and constant variance; $\left( {{b_\ell },{b_{\ell m}}} \right)$ are linear and quadratic slope parameters, respectively, with ${b_{\ell m}} = {b_{m\ell }},\ell \ne m$ (symmetry restriction); and ${c_i} = \mathop \sum \limits_{\ell = 1}^L {\omega _{i\ell }} \cdot {v_{i\ell }}$, a normalizing index with ${\omega _{i\ell }}$ a predetermined weight. We use the normalization strategy suggested by Diewert and Wales (Reference Diewert and Wales1992) such that the predetermined weights sum to 1 and vary across producers. In the absence of monetary incentives encouraging BMP adoption, $\Delta \pi = 0$.
Differentiating the profit function with respect to incentives results in a linear system of equations, with the typical BMP supply function,
where ${q_{i\ell }}$ are the BMP acres or number of structures adopted, given the offered incentive, and the u’s are independent and identically distributed errors with covariance ${\bf{\Sigma }}$. The supply system of equation (2) is differentiated with respect to own- and cross-incentives to calculate elasticities. Own- and cross-incentives characterize producer responsiveness to incentives in terms of the percentage change in the quantity of the BMP supplied for each 1% change in the incentive.
2.1. Censored system and convexity
The extent of BMP adoption is censored at zero when a producer refuses an offered incentive. This problem complicates estimation of typical producer or consumer demand systems because of cross-equation residual correlation caused by the symmetry restrictions. The applied econometrics literature has generally approached quantity-censoring problems from the consumer side, but the logic supporting the estimation procedures extends directly to estimation of indirect profit functions. Shonkwiler and Yen (Reference Shonkwiler and Yen1999) introduced an inefficient but consistent procedure to estimate constrained censored demand systems. Su and Yen (Reference Su and Yen2000) and Yen, Kan, and Su (Reference Yen, Kan and Su2002) applied the two-step approach to estimate demand for meat and fats and oils, respectively. Other two-step approaches include Perali and Chavas’s (Reference Perali and Chavas2000) minimum distance estimator. More efficient maximum likelihood (ML) estimators for censored demand systems were developed by Yen (Reference Yen2005) and applied by Yen and Lin (Reference Yen and Lin2006). Bayesian Markov chain Monte Carlo estimators have also been used to estimate demand systems with censoring (Kasteridis, Yen, and Feng, Reference Kasteridis, Yen and Feng2011).
This analysis extends the two-step censored system estimator of Yen, Kan, and Su (Reference Yen, Kan and Su2002) to model the voluntary adoption of BMPs by producers given cost share incentives. From equation (2), set ${{\beta }} = \left( {{b_P},{b_R},{b_W},{b_S},{b_{PP}},{b_{RR}},{b_{WW}},{b_{SS}},{b_{PR}},{b_{PW}},{b_{PS}},{b_{RW}},{b_{RS}},{b_{WS}}} \right)'$. Then, for the $\ell$th pasture BMP conditioned on the producer’s willingness to adopt the BMP given the offered incentive, the quantity of the BMP supplied by the producer is
where ${{\bf {z}}_i}$ are variables hypothesized to influence the producer’s decision to adopt BMP $\ell$ apart from the offered incentives; ${{\bf{\gamma }}_\ell }$ are parameters; $\epsilon_i^\ell$ is a random error term, and the product ${{\boldsymbol{\bf z}}_i}{{\boldsymbol{\gamma }}_\ell }$ is a linear index function (Maddala, Reference Maddala1983). The stochastic terms of the adoption and supply equations share common omitted factors because of the cross-equation parameter restrictions (e.g., adopt = 1 when $\epsilon_i^\ell \gt - {{\boldsymbol{\bf z}}_i}{{\boldsymbol{\gamma }}_\ell }$) and acres allocated to (or units of) a BMP. This feature could cause correlation between the residuals of the index functions and their respective quantity equations. The selection mechanism is typically modeled as a standard normal random variable with the probability of adoption ${\rm{\Phi }}\left( {{{{\bf z}}_i}{{\boldsymbol{\gamma }}_\ell }} \right)$ (the standard normal cumulative density function, CDF), and a corresponding standard normal probability density $\phi \left( {{{\bf{z}}_i}{{\boldsymbol{\gamma }}_\ell }} \right)$ (the standard normal probability density function, PDF). The parameters are estimated with probit regression and ML. It is important to note that the incentives do not appear in the index function because of the homogeneity and symmetry constraints required by the indirect profit function (e.g., Yen and Lin, Reference Yen and Lin2006). Thus, the linear index function only includes nonpecuniary variables corresponding with operator attributes and farm structure and management characteristics. The unconditional mean of the BMP quantity supplied by a producer is
where ${\lambda _\ell }$ is the covariance between the error terms of the participation decision and the quantity of the BMP adopted; that is, ${\lambda _\ell } = {\rho _\ell } \cdot {\sigma _\ell }$ (Cameron and Trivedi, Reference Cameron and Trivedi2005; Maddala, Reference Maddala1983; Shonkwiler and Yen, Reference Shonkwiler and Yen1999).
An advantage of the SNQ indirect profit function is that global convexity can be imposed using ex post procedures (Henningsen and Henning, Reference Henningsen and Henning2009; Koebel, Reference Koebel1998; Perali and Chavas, Reference Perali and Chavas2000) or by directly estimating the Cholesky factorization of the Hessian matrix (e.g., Diewert and Wales, Reference Diewert and Wales1987; Lau, Reference Lau, Fuss and McFadden1978). Any positive semidefinite matrix can be written as ${\bf{B}} = {\bf{AA}}'$, where ${\bf{A}}$ is a lower-triangular matrix. Then, for the parameters in ${\bf{B}}$,
where ${a_{SS}} = 0$ such that ${\bf{A'}1 = 0}$ (Diewert and Wales, Reference Diewert and Wales1992). This restriction ensures the homogeneity requirement ${b_{\ell \ell }} = - \sum\nolimits_{\ell = 1,\,m \ne \ell }^L {{b_{\ell m}}}$. The $\left[ {{\alpha _{\ell m}}} \right]$ elements enter directly into the system defined in equation (2) and are estimated with ML, along with the PDF and CDF evaluated at the first-stage probit ML estimates.
2.2. Estimation
The system is estimated with iterated feasible generalized nonlinear least squares (IFGNLS), which converges to the ML estimator (Zellner, Reference Zellner1962), using the ifgnls option in STATA’s nlsur routine (StataCorp, 2015). Applying IFGNLS in the second step yields consistent estimators because the ML probit estimates of ${{\gamma}}$ are consistent (Shonkwiler and Yen, Reference Shonkwiler and Yen1999).
Breusch and Pagan’s (Reference Breusch and Pagan1980) test is used to determine if the seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) error covariance matrix is diagonal. The null hypothesis is ${H_0}:{\sigma _{PR}} = {\sigma _{PW}} = {\sigma _{PS}} = {\sigma _{RW}} = {\sigma _{RS}} = {\sigma _{WS}} = 0$. Under this null, the test statistic is a chi-square random variable with six degrees of freedom and a critical value of 12.59 at the 5% level of significance. A likelihood ratio (LR) test is used to select the preferred model, with the null hypothesis ${H_0}:{\lambda _P} = {\lambda _R} = {\lambda _W} = {\lambda _S} = 0$. The test is a chi-squared random variable with four degrees of freedom and a critical value of 9.49 at the 5% level of significance.
Yen, Kan, and Su (Reference Yen, Kan and Su2002) suggest estimating the error covariance of the two-step censored system using a Murphy-Topel estimator. This application uses a jackknife covariance procedure to estimate the parameter covariance matrix (Perali and Chavas, Reference Perali and Chavas2000). The probit regression, the standard normal CDF and PDF, and the system of BMP supply equations were reestimated with IFGNLS for each jackknife replicate. Standard errors of the regression coefficients are estimated as the mean squared error difference between the replicate parameters and the parameters estimated with the original data set. Own- and cross-incentive elasticities are calculated for each jackknife replicate, with the lower 5% and upper 95% bounds determined by the elasticity distributions.
2.3. Application: adoption of survey best pasture management practices
Sediment load reductions generated by rotational grazing and the suite of the survey BMPs, including improved pasture management, water tanks, and stream crossings, are simulated by maintaining minimum pasture forage stands. The ArcSWAT (Version 2012, Release 10) graphical user interface was used to develop a Soil and Water Assessment Tool (SWAT) model of the Oostanaula Creek watershed in ArcGIS Desktop (ESRI, Version 10.5). SWAT is a physically based model developed to simulate land-management and rainfall-runoff processes in predominantly agricultural watersheds with a high level of spatial detail using hydrologic response units (HRUs). HRUs are unique combinations of soil type, slope, and land use/management practices (Gassman et al., Reference Gassman, Reyes, Green and Arnold2007).
For the adoption effects analysis, management practice modifications were made to pasture HRUs. Land use, soils, and digital elevation data were downloaded from the U.S. Department of Agriculture’s (USDA) Geospatial Data Gateway (USDA, Natural Resource Conservation Service [NRCS], 2018). Land use corresponded with the 2009 Croplands Data Layer (Johnson and Mueller, Reference Johnson and Mueller2010). Soil types were classified according to the State Soil Geographic (STATSGO) data set (Wang and Melesse, Reference Wang and Melesse2006). Slopes (0–2%, 2%–8%, 8%–16%, and >16%) were established using the National Elevation Dataset (10 m resolution; Gesch et al., Reference Gesch, Oimoen, Greenlee, Nelson, Stuek and Tyler2002). Rainfall input data for the model were obtained from the National Weather Station Coop database for two stations in Athens and Cleveland, Tennessee (Leeper, Rennie, and Palecki, Reference Leeper, Rennie and Palecki2015). Models were run from January 1990 to October 2013, with a monthly time step and a two-year startup period. Model development, calibration, and validation details are provided in online supplementary Appendix II.
A total of 466 HRUs represented the watershed’s unique land use/slope/soil combinations. Of these, 207 were classified as pasture, representing a total of 18,114 acres. Fescue forage was produced in pasture HRUs using fertilization and grazing management routines (online supplementary Appendix II). The adoption of the survey suite of BMPs was modeled through modifications to the management practice schedule for grazed fescue (“FESC”) land use category by varying the BIOMIN setting. This BIOMIN setting is used in SWAT to avoid pasture damage and increased erosion caused by overgrazing (White et al., Reference White, Storm, Busteed, Stoodley and Phillips2010). This procedure constrains minimum vegetation in kilograms of dry matter per hectare after which grazing is discontinued. A calibrated and validated model run with a BIOMIN setting of 300 was completed to assess sediment loss when the potential for severely overgrazed pastures existed. A second model run with a BIOMIN setting of 1,000 was used to assess sediment loss potential after implementing the suite of survey BMPs.
Fifty-two of the 207 pasture HRUs accounted for 90% of the annual sediment runoff from pasture (Figure 1).Footnote 2 The total area represented by these 52 HRUs was 4,821 acres. In the absence of rotational grazing on any of these pasture HRUs (BIOMIN setting of 300), the SWAT model estimated an annual sediment yield of 22,839 tons/year from the watershed’s pastureland. When rotational grazing was implemented on the 52 pasture HRUs (BIOMIN setting of 1,000), the annual sediment yield from these HRUs decreased to 13,230 tons/year. Thus, the ability to identify and differentiate land use/soil/slope combinations offers the potential for more cost-effectivesediment abatement.
The simulation focuses on the adoption of the survey suite of BMPs to increase forage productivity and reduce sediment runoff from pasture. The total program cost of achieving a sediment abatement goal for the watershed could be calculated as the solution to a cost minimization problem, subject to producer responsiveness to monetary incentives encouraging the enrollment of pasture acres into the hypothetical rotational grazing program. Along these lines, we adopt the optimization approach suggested by Govindasamy and Huffman (Reference Govindasamy and Huffman1993) and Smith et al. (Reference Smith, Williams, Nejadhashemi, Woznicki and Leatherman2014). Parameters and variables used to estimate the cost of meeting a sediment abatement target through the adoption of rotational grazing are in Table 1.
Notes: HRU, hydrologic response unit (see text for definitions); P, pasture improvement; R, rotational grazing; S, stream crossing; W, water tank.
The optimization problem minimizes the cost of reaching a watershed sediment abatement goal by choosing an HRU-specific incentive to encourage enrollment of pasture acres into the hypothetical program, subject to producer willingness to enroll acres into the program and animal water requirements.Footnote 3 By allowing incentives to vary among HRUs, we are implicitly assuming that the agency administering the incentive program has the information and authority to discriminate among land uses based on sediment loading rates.
The objective function for the optimization problem is
subject to:
The objective minimizes the total cost of enrolling private pasture into the rotational grazing program, with ${p_{R\left( k \right)}}$ the dollars per acre paid annually to producers in HRU k (equation 6). Equation (7) is the total amount of sediment loading generated by the k th HRU from areas managed with and without rotational grazing. The sediment abatement target is equation (8), which aggregates sediment (annual tons) loading across the watershed. Equation (9) is the estimated acreage supply equation for rotational grazing from the normalized quadratic profit function. The parameter $\overline c$ is the average of Diewert and Wales’s (Reference Diewert and Wales1992) price index over the sample ($\overline c$ = 351), and ${\overline \omega _R}$ the sample average of the weighting factors for rotational grazing (${\overline \omega _R}$ = 0.08). The intercept term is omitted because, in the absence of incentives, enrollment of pasture acres into the hypothetical rotational grazing program would be zero. The number of acres enrolled into the program cannot exceed the total available acres in HRU k (${T_k}$, equation 10).
The rotational grazing acreage supply equation is used to generate a watershed abatement curve. The abatement curve represents the dollars per ton the agency would have to pay in incentives to achieve an annual sediment target. Enrollment of pasture acres into rotational grazing is calculated for each HRU at the optimized incentives, corresponding with a target level of sediment. Then, using equation (7), the change in sediment loading because of the pasture managed under a rotational grazing system of BMPs (${q_{R\left( k \right)}} \cdot [{r_{0\left( k \right)}} - {r_{1\left( k \right)}}]$) is aggregated across HRUs at a given per acre incentive offered to producers to manage pasture acres using rotational grazing. The dollar per acre incentive is converted to dollar per sediment ton using the sediment yield parameters (${r_{0\left( k \right)}}$ and ${r_{1\left( k \right)}}$, Table 1) generated by SWAT. We vary the target sedimentation level Q from 13,000 to 22,800 tons/year in increments of 426 tons (24 intervals), solving the problem at each target with the General Algebraic Modeling System (GAMS Development Corporation) using a sparse nonlinear optimization procedure (snopt).
Project costs used to calculate the abatement curves include the incentives paid for the installation of water tanks. Water tanks are required when animals are in paddocks for rotational grazing and prevented from accessing streams or ponds. The number of water tanks required was calculated based on cattle water requirements and the number of beef cattle that could be supported by the optimal enrolled acreage levels for the different sediment targets. The number of beef cattle (BeefCattle) that can be supported by pasture forage in HRU k is (Undersander et al., Reference Undersander, Albert, Cosgrove, Johnson and Peterson2002)
Forage productivity (Forage Yield) is assumed to be 4,000 lb./acre (Undersander et al., Reference Undersander, Albert, Cosgrove, Johnson and Peterson2002), and animal forage requirements (Forage Access) assumes that animals require 4% of their live weight in forage per grazing day (Undersander et al., Reference Undersander, Albert, Cosgrove, Johnson and Peterson2002). Based on what is typical for the region’s pasture forage systems, we also assume a 153-day grazing period (Days Grazed) and a finishing weight of 1,250 lb. (Animal Weight).
The number of water tanks required in a rotational grazing paddock in an HRU (${q_{WT\left( k \right)}}$) was determined as the number of beef cattle supported by the HRU times the gallons per day consumed by each animal (10 gallons/animal/day; Undersander et al., Reference Undersander, Albert, Cosgrove, Johnson and Peterson2002) divided by the tank size (800 gallons):
The 75% cost share rate of $1,150 per 800-gallon tank was held constant across the water shed.
3. Data
The survey of beef cattle producers was conducted in 2011 and 2013. Respondents were mailed an initial package that included an introductory letter, a booklet questionnaire, and a return stamped envelope. A reminder postcard was mailed 1 week later, and, for nonresponders, a second packet (cover letter, questionnaire, and return envelope) was sent 2 weeks later. The sample was collected using addresses from a publicly available tax parcel list frame, which included the physical addresses, boundaries, assessed property values, and land use classifications of the parcels. Survey responses of livestock producers were collected in two waves for budgetary and logistical reasons. The first mailing was sent in March 2011 to 1,480 owners of 1,736 unique parcels classified as agricultural land. The second wave was sent in February 2013 to 3,678 unique owners of 4,720 agricultural parcels. The response rate was 32%. After removing observations with missing records and focusing only on beef cattle operations indicating access to a stream, there were 195 observations available for this analysis.
There were four sections in the survey. The questions in the first section, “Your Farm Operation,” focused on producer and farm operation characteristics and the value respondents placed on objectives related to BMPs (e.g., improving forage quality and providing cattle access to a year-round supply of clean drinking water). The second section, “Best Management Practices,” asked respondents about their previous experience with the BMPs (rotational grazing, water tanks, stream crossings, and pasture improvement) and included a hypothetical choice experiment to elicit producer willingness to adopt the BMPs. A description of the on- and off-site benefits and required actions for each BMP were provided to respondents on an informational page (online supplementary Appendix III).
Respondents were also provided per unit establishment and/or installation cost estimates for each BMP. These cost estimates—rotational grazing = $79.08/ha ($32.00/ac.), pasture improvement = $626/ha ($253.33/ac.), stream crossing = $41.63/m2 ($3.87/ft.2), and cattle water tanks = $1,533.33/tank—were determined by dividing the equipment and practice cost share dollar amounts reported by the NRCS for Tennessee by the cost share rate used by the NRCS for Tennessee (0.75).
For the choice experiment, there were 47 possible combinations of cost share amounts offered for the BMPs. The %mktex macro (SAS version 9.2) was used to determine an optimal factorial design and the optimal number (49) of practice/incentive combinations (Lambert et al., Reference Lambert, Clark, Busko, Walker, Layton and Hawkins2014). There were 49 versions of the survey mailed to respondents. The cost share amounts offered to producers were determined by multiplying the expected costs of the BMPs by 50%, 62.5%, 75%, 87.5%, 100%, 112.5%, and 125% (Table 2). Online supplementary Appendix III summarizes the distribution of cost share amounts and corresponding survey response frequencies. The survey presented respondents only with the dollar/unit amounts they would be eligible to receive for adopting a BMP. Respondents were not made aware that the dollar/unit amount corresponded with a specific cost share. The hypothetical cost share amounts varied randomly both between practices and across respondents.
Best management practice quantities that respondents were willing to adopt were scaled using a Laspeyres index benchmarked to the sum-product of the average quantity-incentivevectors of each practice. For each respondent, the index was calculated as ${I_i} = \left( {\mathop \sum \nolimits v_\ell \cdot {{\overline q }_{i\ell }}} \right)/\left( {\mathop \sum \nolimits {\overline v_\ell } \cdot {{\overline q }_{i\ell }}} \right)$, where ${v_{i\ell }}$ is the incentive offered for practice $\ell$ to respondent i; and ${\overline q _\ell}$ and ${\overline v _\ell }$ are the sample averages of the quantity adopted of, and the incentive offered for, the $\ell$th BMP, respectively. The indexed quantities used in the regressions are ${\widetilde q_{i\ell }} = {q_{i\ell }}/{I_i}$. This procedure rescales the BMP quantities to a common scale (Henningsen, Reference Henningsen2018). Indexing the practices to a common scale is important in this analysis because the BMP quantity units are different for each practice.
3.1. Operator and farm characteristics
Operator and farm characteristics are hypothesized to influence the probability of adopting one or more of the BMPs (Table 2). Operator characteristics included in the probit adoption equations are age, educational attainment, and plans to pass on the farm to a family member. Farmers with more years of education may be inclined to adopt new technologies or practices (Daberkow and McBride, Reference Daberkow and McBride2003; Roberts et al., Reference Roberts, English, Larson, Cochran, Goodman, Larkin, Marra, Martin, Shurley and Reeves2004). Younger producers may be willing to experiment with new technologies because their planning horizons are longer (Schimmelpfennig and Ebel, Reference Schimmelpfennig and Ebel2011; Watcharaanantapong et al., Reference Watcharaanantapong, Roberts, Lambert, Larson, Velandia, English, Rejesus and Wang2014). A respondent’s ties to the farm and the prospect of passing on the operation to kin could also effectively extend a respondent’s time horizon and increase the likelihood of adopting BMPs (Claytor et al., Reference Claytor, Clark, Lambert and Jensen2018). Farmers who own relatively more of the land they operate may be more likely to adopt practices they perceive would improve the aesthetic or property value of their farm (Roberts et al., Reference Roberts, English, Larson, Cochran, Goodman, Larkin, Marra, Martin, Shurley and Reeves2004). Higher property values may be associated with proximity to other parcels that have been developed for residential or commercial uses. The assessed per acre property value of the parcel may therefore also influence the decision to adopt a pasture BMP. Farm topography may also affect the decision to adopt pasture BMPs. Slope was assigned to parcels based on the majority of the area associated with the parcel classified into one of four categories represented in the watershed: 0–2%, 2%–8%, 8%–16%, and >16% slope (Medwid, Reference Medwid2016).
Farm operation variables include farm size, the percent of land farmed in pasture, and animal stocking density. Larger operations are more likely to adopt new technologies because of scale economies (Fernandez-Cornejo, Daberkow, and McBride, Reference Fernandez-Cornejo, Daberkow and McBride2001). Farms allocating relatively more of the land they manage to pasture may be more likely to incorporate pasture BMPs into their operation (Jensen et al., Reference Jensen, Lambert, Clark, English, Yu, Larson, Holt and Hellwinckel2015). Operations stocking pasture with cattle at relatively higher densities may also be more inclined to perceive the adoption of a suite of pasture BMPs as a way to sustain or increase productivity (Jensen et al., Reference Jensen, Lambert, Clark, English, Yu, Larson, Holt and Hellwinckel2015). Familiarity and experience with each of the BMPs considered in this analysis may also explain willingness to participate in the hypothetical BMP incentive program.
4. Results
Seventy-five percent (146/195) of the respondents indicated willingness to adopt pasture improvement, given the incentive offered (Table 2). On average, respondents willing to improve their pasture were willing to rehabilitate 60 acres. Fifty-three percent (104/195) of the respondents were willing to adopt rotational grazing, while 56% (109/195) were willing to adopt water tanks. Respondents willing to adopt rotational grazing would enroll an average of 73 acres into the hypothetical program. Respondents willing to adopt water tanks would, on average, install 2.6 tanks. Twenty-four percent (46/195) of the respondents were willing to adopt stream crossings. Anecdotal evidence from extension agents working with cattle operators in the study’s region reports that stream crossings are not popular with producers because of the effort needed to keep fences free of debris.
4.1. Adoption of best pasture management practices
The overall fit of the probit models ranges from 0.17 for stream crossings (McKelvey and Zavoina’s [Reference McKelvey and Zavoina1975] R 2) to 0.36 for water tanks (Table 3). Correct predictions range from 62% for rotational grazing to 80% for pasture improvement. For all probit models, the joint null hypothesis that the probit ML coefficients were not different from zero was rejected at the 1% level of significance. Variables significant at the 10% level or lower are discussed.
Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. Asterisks (***,**, and *) indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Older producers were less likely to adopt rotational grazing, water tanks, and stream crossings (Table 2). Producers with a college education were 0.10 more likely to adopt pasture improvement practices and 0.11 more likely to adopt stream crossings. Respondents planning to pass their farm on to family members were 0.22, 0.24, and 0.29 more likely to adopt rotational grazing, water tanks, and pasture rehabilitation, respectively.
Larger farms were less likely to adopt pasture improvement or rotational grazing than smaller farms, but more likely to adopt stream crossings (Table 3). Operators managing relatively more of their land as pasture were less likely to adopt rotational grazing. Respondents using higher stocking rates were also less likely to adopt rotational grazing; for a 1-unit change in the number of beef cattle grazed on pasture, the likelihood of adopting rotational grazing decreased by 0.07. This is a surprising result. On average, respondents managing relatively more cattle per acre ostensibly perceive the opportunity costs and extra level of management needed to move cattle from one paddock to another to be too high. Land tenure had a positive effect on the adoption of rotational grazing, but a negative effect on the adoption of water tanks and stream crossings. The latter results are also unexpected. The simple Pearson’s correlation (r) between land tenure and acres owned also suggests a significant inverse relationship between these two variables (r = −0.16, P < 0.05). Thus, tenure rates are relatively higher for smaller operations in the study region. A possible explanation could be that owners of relatively smaller operations are less willing to invest in structures that require additional management. Assessed property value had a negative effect on the adoption of pasture improvement and rotational grazing. For a dollar increase in the assessed property value of a parcel, the probability of adopting pasture improvement decreased by 0.03 and the probability of adopting rotational grazing decreased by 0.05. One explanation for this finding might be that owners of more highly valued property perceive the opportunity cost of beef cattle production to be higher and are, thus, less committed to producing cattle in the future.
There is evidence of interrelationships between the BMPs used by operators and willingness to adopt the choice experiment’s BMPs (Table 3). Producers who had either previously improved pasture or who already practiced rotational grazing were 0.15 more likely to be willing to adopt or increase the extent to which they had adopted rotational grazing. Similarly, producers who had previously improved pasture were 0.17 more likely to be willing to adopt water tanks. Producers who already used water tanks were 0.12 more likely to be willing to install additional water tanks through the hypothetical cost share program. The results were mixed for willingness to adopt stream crossings. Producers who used tanks to water cattle were 0.14 less likely to adopt a stream crossing system at the offered cost share rate, while producers who had already installed or managed stream crossing systems were 0.10 more likely to be willing to adopt additional stream crossings.
4.2. Response to incentives and pasture BMP adoption
SUR and SUR with sample selection estimates of the SNQ profit function violated the convexity requirement. Both models were reestimated, imposing convexity. The null hypothesis that the coefficients on the PDF variables in equation (4) were jointly equal to zero was rejected at the 1% level of significance (LR test = 33, degrees of freedom = 4). The Breusch-Pagan test for diagonality of the system’s error covariance matrix was rejected at the 1% level (test statistic = 121, degrees of freedom = 6; Table 4). The preferred model is therefore the SNQ indirect profit function estimated as a two-step SUR with convexity imposed.
Notes: 1/, Parameter labels are described in equations (1) and (2). 2/, The null hypothesis is that the off-diagonal elements of the error covariance matrix are zero. The statistic is a chi-squared random variable, with a critical value of 12.59 at the 5% level of significance. P, prescribed grazing; R, rotational grazing; S, stream crossing; W, water tank.
Complementary effects are evident for water tanks and rotational grazing according to their cross-incentive supply elasticities (Table 5). When the cost share incentives of rotational grazing and water tanks are simultaneously increased by 1%, their combined effect results in a 1.3% change in acres enrolled into the hypothetical rotational grazing program. Larger percent increases in the rotational grazing and water tank costs shares induced an even larger response. If the cost share rates for rotational grazing and water tanks were increased by 14.49% and 12.56% to their market values (100% cost share), then the corresponding change in acres in rotational grazing are 17.58%. For water tanks and rotational grazing, the incentive for their adoption appears to “crowd in” private investment in the form of additional acres in rotational grazing or additional water tanks (Fleming, Reference Fleming2017).
A 1% increase in the incentive offered to adopt pasture improving practices corresponds with a −0.11% decrease in areas respondents are willing to manage with a rotational grazing system, thereby “crowding out” private investment (Fleming, Reference Fleming2017). The incentive for water tanks crowds out willingness to improve pasture as a 1% increase in the incentive offered to adopt a water tank is associated with a 0.54% decrease in the number of pasture acres respondents are willing to rehabilitate (Table 5).
4.3. Application results
The maximum number of acres that could be enrolled into the hypothetical rotational grazing program, subject to the optimization model’s constraints and parameters, is 1,891 (Figure 2a), or 39% of the total acres included in the simulation sample. The acreage supply curve becomes perfectly inelastic at the cost share rate of $198/acre, which corresponds with a sediment abatement target of 8,520 tons/year (Figure 2b). The maximum feasible sediment abatement target of 8,520 tons/year corresponds with a 37% reduction in sedimentation for the 52 HRUs included in the simulation, and a 31% overall reduction in sediment loading for all 207 pasture HRUs in the watershed. At this level of sediment abatement, total incentive payments for enrolled acres and water tanks are estimated to be $170,000 per year (Figure 2c), or roughly $20/ton of decreased sediment yield (Figure 2d).
5. Conclusions
This study uses the results of a hypothetical choice experiment measuring cattle producer willingness to adopt four pasture-based best management practices (rotational grazing, pasture improvement, water tanks, and stream crossings) to estimate a theoretically consistent system of supply (or extent of adoption) equations. The usual constraints of homogeneity, symmetry, and convexity were imposed, and a two-step nonlinear procedure was used to estimate the indirect profit function. The supply equation for any one practice quantifies the relationship between acres or units of the practice likely to be adopted by livestock producers and the incentive level offered for the adoption of the practice (the own-incentive), holding the incentive levels for the other practices (the cross-incentives) constant.
The supply equation for rotational grazing was linked to a SWAT to simulate the effects of the adoption of rotational grazing on sediment yields to generate an aggregate sediment abatement curve for a watershed in East Tennessee. The sediment abatement curve summarizes the relationship between the land class-specific incentive levels for rotational grazing and watershed-level reductions in sediment yield. Thus, the abatement curve differentiates among the land classes based on sediment yield rates and implicitly assumes an incentive program that can target land classes because of this difference.
Application of the methods used here would enable agencies to consider the effects of both own- and cross-incentive elasticities on practice adoption and sedimentation abatement when defining and setting incentives for a suite of best management practices. Previous studies established the existence of cross-incentive effects but did not apply methods to account for these effects when setting incentive rates. Thus, this study extends this literature by proposing an empirical strategy for generating theoretically consistent own- and cross-incentive effects for a suite of pasture management best management practices and then linking these effects with a biophysical simulation model to generate sediment reduction cost curves as well as the corresponding acreage supply/cost rate schedule. In this way, the article proposes an approach for resolving some of the complexities involved in setting incentive rates that will both entice producers to adopt BMPs while cost-effectively achieving desirable environmental outcomes.
The results should be put into perspective. The findings of the choice experiment are subject to all of the usual qualifications regarding hypothetical markets. In addition, there were limitations to the choice experiment performed for this analysis. Landowners who used pasture to raise beef cattle with access to streams were the larger population of interest in this study. The number of landowners meeting these criteria was unknown before the survey. This means the sample used may underrepresent the population of interest. In terms of the estimation of the best management practice supply equations, the two-step procedure used here generates consistent estimates, but these estimates are inefficient compared with full-information ML estimators. However, the advantage of the two-step estimator rests in the relative ease at which nonlinearities can be introduced into supply equations to impose a function consistent with profit maximizing behavior. An empirical challenge remains to specify fully the system proposed here as a “full-information” system of censored equations with curvature imposed by the procedures used here.Footnote 4
Further, one might expect willingness to adopt to vary with the characteristics of the land classes. For example, owners of steeper land classes might be more willing to adopt erosion-reducing practices because of higher erosion rates and, possibly, lower opportunity costs. Thus, additional research could focus on differentiating between land classes both in terms of sediment yields and between producer willingness to adopt best pasture practices.
Supplementary material
To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/aae.2019.42.
Acknowledgments
The authors thank the editor and three anonymous reviewers whose comments and suggestions greatly improved earlier versions of the manuscript. Any remaining errors are those of the authors. The views herein are solely those of the authors.
Financial support
This research was funded by the U.S. Department of Agriculture under Award No. 2009-51130-06047, the Willard Sparks Endowment, Chair of Agricultural Sciences and Natural Resources.
Conflict of interest
None.