Article contents
The institutional foundations of hegemony: explaining the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 22 May 2009
Extract
In 1930, Congress approved the highly restrictive Smoot–Hawley tariff, the textbook case of pressure group politics run amok. Four years later, Congress passed the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act (RTAA), surrendering much of its tariff-making authority to a policy process in which internationalists had increasing influence. While the United States had used reciprocity to expand exports before, the stick of discriminatory treatment took precedence over the carrot of liberalizing concessions. With the transfer of tariff-making authority to the executive, the United States could make credible commitments and thus exploit its market power to liberalize international trade. Despite later modifications, the RTAA set the fundamental institutional framework for trade politics.
- Type
- Research Article
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © The IO Foundation 1988
References
I am greatly indebted to Jeff Frieden, Barbara Geddes, Judith Goldstein, Joanne Gowa, Joe Grieco, Cynthia Hody, John Ikenberry, Peter Katzenstein, David Lake, Mark Levy, Michael Mastanduno, Helen Milner, Andy Moravcsik, Timothy McKeown, Doug Nelson, John Odell, Mark Peterson, Beth Simmons, Sven Steinmo, Ray Vernon, and two anonymous reviewers for their advice and assistance.
1. Francis, Bowes Sayre, Glad Adventure (New York: MacMillan, 1957), p. 170.Google Scholar
2. This result can be partly attributed to price increases over the 1930s and early 1940s. Apparent protection is the ratio of total duties collected to total value of dutiable imports. By 1945, 60% of dutiable imports were entered under specific rates; ad valorem equivalents of specific duties thus varied inversely with prices. Since concessions were greater on raw materials than on manufactures, effective protection on some manufactures probably increased over the 1930s.
3. United States Tariff Commission, Operation of the Trade Agreements Program, July 1934 to April 1948 (Washington, D.C.: GPO, 1948), Part 1, p. 84.Google Scholar
4. See Tasca, Henry J., The Reciprocal Trade Policy of the United States (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 1938), chaps. 4–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bowes Sayre, Francis, The Way Forward: The American Trade Agreements Program (New York: Macmillan, 1939).Google Scholar
5. Gardner, Lloyd, Economic Aspects of New Deal Diplomacy (Boston: Beacon, 1964), pp. 40–42, 45Google Scholar; Hoff Wilson, Joan, American Business and Foreign Policy, 1920–1933 (Lexington: University Press of Kentucky, 1971), pp. 98–100.Google Scholar
6. Conybeare, John, “Trade Wars: A Comparative Study of Anglo-Hanse, Franco-Italian and Hawley-Smoot Conflicts,” World Politics 38 (10 1985).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
7. These are hinted in Lowi's, Theodore classic piece, “American Business, Public Policy, Case Studies, and Political Theory,” World Politics 16 (07 1964)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, though, as will become clear, Lowi's interpretation of the change in trade policy from a “distributive” to a “regulatory” issue is only partly correct. Pastor, Robert takes an explicitly institutional approach to trade policy in Congress and the Politics of U.S. Foreign Economic Policy (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1980)Google Scholar; see pp. 84–93 for his interpretation of the RTAA. See also the excellent study by Robert Brenner, Steven, “Economic Interests and the Trade Agreements Program, 1937–1940: A Study of Institutions and Political Influence,” unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University, 1977Google Scholar, which influences my interpretation; Destler, I. M., American Trade Politics: System Under Stress (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1986), chap. 2.Google Scholar
8. Lowi, , “American Business, Public Policy,” pp. 699–701Google Scholar; Schattschneider, E. E., Politics, Pressure and the Tariff (New York: Prentice-Hall, 1955).Google Scholar
9. For examples of “weak state” arguments, see Katzenstein, Peter, “Conclusion: Domestic Structures and Strategies of Foreign Economic Policy,”Google Scholar and Krasner, Stephen, “United States Commercial and Monetary Policy: Unravelling the Paradox of External Strength and Internal Weakness,” in Katzenstein, , ed., Between Power and Plenty (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1978)Google Scholar; Vernon, Raymond, Two Hungry Giants: The United States and Japan in the Quest for Oil and Ores (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1983), chap. 4CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Zysman, John and Tyson, Laura, “American Industry in International Competition,” in Zysman, and Tyson, , eds., American Industry in International Competition (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1983).Google Scholar
10. This problem is visible in Krasner, Stephen, Defending the National Interest (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1978), pp. 56–57.Google Scholar
11. For some of the problems with this literature, see Ikenberry, John, “The State and Oil Shocks,” International Organization 40 (Winter 1986)Google Scholar; Milner, Helen, “Resisting the Protectionist Temptation: Industry and the Making of Trade Policy in France and the U.S. in the 1970s,” paper delivered to the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association,August 1986Google Scholar; and Lake, David, “The State and American Trade Policy in the Pre-Hegemonic Era,”Google Scholar in this volume. My arguments are very similar to Lake's, which are developed for an earlier period.
12. North, Douglass, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981), p. 32Google Scholar. See also Gowa, Joanne, “Public Goods and Political Institutions: Trade and Monetary Policy Processes in the United States,”Google Scholar in this volume.
13. On the logic of this approach, see Ikenberry, , “The State and Oil Shocks,”Google Scholar and Theda, Skocpol, “Bringing the State Back In: Strategies of Analysis in Current Research,”Google Scholar in Peter, Evans, Dietrich, Rueschemeyer, and Theda, Skocpol, eds., Bringing the State Back In (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985).Google Scholar
14. On the limits of coalitional analysis, see Margaret, Weir and Theda, Skocpol, “State Structures and the Possibilities for ‘Keynesian’ Responses to the Great Depression in Sweden, Britain and the United States,” in Evans, , Rueschemeyer, , and Skocpol, , eds., Bringing the State Back In, p. 115.Google Scholar
15. Patterson, James T., Congressional Conservatism and the New Deal (Lexington: University of Kentucky Press, 1967), chap. 1.Google Scholar
16. Whitson Fetter, Frank, “Congressional Tariff Theory,” American Economic Review 23 (09 1933), p. 416.Google Scholar
17. On 9 June 1933, FDR noted in a press conference that “Congress would never give me complete authority to write tariff schedules”; a reporter responded, “Well, they have given you everything else.” Complete Presidential Press Conferences of Franklin D. Roosevelt (New York: Da Capo, 1972), vol. 1, p. 368Google Scholar; also press conference 25 May 1933, pp. 324–25.
18. Historians credit Roosevelt with internationalist preferences, even where he was forced to modify them in reaction to circumstance. See Freidel, Frank, Franklin D. Roosevelt: Launching the New Deal (Boston: Little, Brown, 1973)Google Scholar; chap. 7; Dallek, Robert, Franklin D. Roosevelt and American Foreign Policy 1932–1945 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1979)Google Scholar; Leuchtenberg, William E., Franklin D. Roosevelt and the New Deal (New York: Harper & Row, 1963)Google Scholar; Schlesinger, Arthur M. Jr., The Coming of the New Deal (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1958)Google Scholar, section 3. Schlesinger's qualifications are discussed later.
19. From the 1933 inaugural address, in Delano Roosevelt, Franklin, Public Papers and Addresses, compiled by S. I. Rosenman (New York: Random House, 1938–1950), vol. 2 (1933), p. 14.Google Scholar
20. In 1935, FDR noted that “the amount involved in the special trade agreements is so small in dollars and cents and so small in relation to our total commerce that it is captious of George Peek to try to make this an issue.” FDR to Jesse Jones, 18 July 1935, President's Secretary's File (PSF) 73, FDR Library Hyde Park, New York.
21. See the excellent study by Rosen, Elliott A., Hoover, Roosevelt and the Brains Trust: From Depression to New Deal (New York: Columbia University Press, 1977).Google Scholar
22. Ferguson, Thomas, “From Normalcy to New Deal; Industrial Structure, Party Competition and American Public Policy in the Great Depression,” International Organization 38 (Winter 1984)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Milner, Helen, “Resisting the Protectionist Temptation,” Ph.D. diss., Harvard University, 1986Google Scholar. This explanation also mirrors revisionist interpretations that emphasize export interests. See Gardner, , Economic AspectsGoogle Scholar; Wilson, , American Business.Google Scholar
23. Ferguson, , “From Normalcy to New Deal,” p. 93.Google Scholar
24. On the interest groups organized around the trade issue, see memo, Office of the Special Assistant on Foreign Trade (SAFT), 7 May 1934, “List of Foreign Trade Associations and their Inter-Relationshps,” General Records of the SAFT (Record Group 20), National Archives. Jeff Frieden has argued most convincingly about the influence of financial interests on American foreign policy during this period. See “Sectoral Conflict in U.S. Foreign Economic Policy, 1914–1940,” this volume.
25. Department of Commerce, Foreign Trade of the United States: Calendar Year 1933 (Washington D.C.: GPO, 1934), pp. 12–14.Google Scholar
26. Wilson, , American Business, pp. 73–74Google Scholar and chap. 3, passim; “Report of the Executive Committee on Commercial Policy,” enclosed in Phillips to FDR, 23 December 1933, President's Official File (OF) 614A (cited hereafter as Executive Committee Report), FDR Library, Hyde Park, New York.
27. This point is made by Fetter, , “Congressional Tariff Making,”Google Scholar and by Wilson, , American Business, chap. 3.Google Scholar
28. Ferguson, , “From Normalcy to New Deal”Google Scholar; Wilson, , American Business, chap. 3.Google Scholar
29. See two telegrams, D. S. Ingelhart (President, W. R. Grace and Co.) to FDR, 8 June 1933, OF 61, FDR Library. The first, signed by thirty-nine large manufacturers, supported the negotiation of reciprocal trade agreements, citing growing bilateralism and systems of imperial preference as the principal reason. The second telegram reports a poll of “upwards of 150 important manufacturers” and found almost unanimous support for the reciprocal trade program. Two days later, however, FDR announced that he was not seeking trade legislation!
30. On the “internationalist” outlook, see Frieden, , “Sectoral Conflict,” this volume.Google Scholar
31. On the problem of the fragmentation of trade policy, see “The Urgent Necessity of Working Out an Adequate and Co-ordinated Method for Dealing with Commercial Policy,” Memo for the President, enclosed in Hull to FDR, 27 October 1933, OF 614 A; Executive Committee Report.
32. On the changes in the processes that governed trade in the 1930s, see Snyder, Richard, “Commercial Policy as Reflected in Treaties from 1931 to 1939,” American Economic Review 30 (12 1940)Google Scholar; Jones, Joseph M. Jr., Tariff Retaliation: Repercussions of the Smoot-Hawley Bill (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 1934)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gordon, Margaret, Barriers to World Trade: A Study of Recent Commercial Policy (New York: MacMillan, 1941)Google Scholar. The Tariff Commission began investigating reciprocal negotiations in early 1933 at the request of Congress. United States Tariff Commission, Tarijff Bargaining Under Most-Favored-Nation Treaties, Report to the United States Senate (Tariff Commission Report 62, 2d Series, GPO, 1934).
33. Examples of a structuralist view are Kindleberger, Charles P., The World in Depression, 1929–39 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973)Google Scholar; Krasner, Stephen, “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics 28 (04 1976)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Lake's, David sophisticated synthesis in “Beneath the Commerce of Nations: A Theory of International Economic Structures,” International Studies Quarterly 28 (06 1984)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Lake defines structural position in terms of both relative size and relative productivity—the first variable explaining the capacity to act as leader, the second the interest in doing so. Yet Frieden has pointed out that while relative productivity was higher than that of any other advanced industrial state in 1929, U.s. share of world trade was only 13.9%. Yet in 1960, the highpoint of American hegemony, U.S. share of world trade was 15.3%. Frieden, , “The Internationalization of American Banking and the Transformation of American Foreign Policy, 1890–1940,” paper delivered to the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association,Washington, D.C.,1–3 September 1984Google Scholar. In addition, between 1929 and 1938, U.S. share of world trade went down, while its relative productivity remained constant.
The idea of a “process” level of the international system separate from the structural level is articulated in Keohane, Robert O. and Nyc, Joseph, Power and Interdependence (Boston: Little, Brown, 1977).Google Scholar
34. House of Representatives, Reciprocal Trade Agreements. Hearings before the Committee on Ways and Means, 73d Congress, 2d session, pp. 5–6.
35. Ruggie, John, “International Regimes, Transactions and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Post-war Economic Order,” International Organization (Spring 1982)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Goldstein, Judith, “The Political Economy of Trade: the Institutions of Protection,” American Political Science Review 80 (03 1986), pp. 161–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
36. Pastor, , U.S. Foreign Economic Policy, pp. 84–93.Google Scholar
37. Schlesinger, Arthur M., The Coming of the New Deal, p. 260Google Scholar; see also Oye, Ken, “The Sterling-Dollar-Franc Triangle: Monetary Diplomacy 1929–1937,” World Politics 38 (10 1985).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
38. See Kelly, William B. Jr., “Antecedents of Present Commercial Policy, 1922–1934,” in Kelly, , ed., Studies in United Stares Commercial Policy (Chapel Hill, N.C.: University of North Carolina Press, 1963).Google Scholar
39. Wilson, , American Business, pp. 67–71Google Scholar. For a commissioner's view of the problems of the flexible provision, see John Lee, Coulter, “The Tariff Commission and the Flexible Clause,” Proceedings of the American Academy of Political Science 15 (06 1933).Google Scholar
40. In choosing Raskob to chair the National Committee, Smith wished “to let the businessmen of this country know that one of the great industrial leaders of modem times had confidence in the Democratic Party and its platform.” Cited in Mathew, and Hannah, Josephson, Al Smith: Hero of the Cities (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1969), p. 371Google Scholar. Smith's views are included in his acceptance address, Albany, 22 August 1928 and his Louisville speech, 13 October 1928, Campaign Addresses of Gov. Alfred E. Smith (Washington, D.C.: Democratic National Committee, 1929), pp. 7, 165–67.Google Scholar
41. See Cordell, Hull, Memoirs, vol. 1, pp. 142, 146Google Scholar; Rosen, , From Depression to New Deal, chap. 2.Google Scholar
42. The most careful analysis of Hull's thinking on the issue is Allen, William R., “The International Trade Philosophy of Cordell Hull, 1907–1933,” American Economic Review 63 (03 1953).Google Scholar
43. Hull, , Memoirs, vol. 1, p. 352.Google Scholar
44. He continued, “How unorthodox this was at the time may be judged by the amount of bitterness with which we were called nationalists by older economists.” Raymond, Moley, After Seven Years (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 1971), p. 23.Google Scholar
45. See Elliot, Rosen, “Intranationalism vs. Internationalism: The Interregnum Struggle for the Sanctity of the New Deal,” Political Science Quarterly 81 (06 1966).Google Scholar
46. As Tugwell, argued, “We were convinced that in order to work Out our problems of recovery and reform we would have to be insulated from European interference.”Google ScholarRexford, Tugwell, The Brains Trust (New York: Viking, 1968), p. 475Google Scholar; Rexford Tugwell, Diary, vol. 5, “June 1933 to March 1934,” pp. 9–14Google Scholar; Tugwell Papers, FDR Library, Hyde Park, N.Y.
47. The following draws on Hicks, John D., Republican Ascendency, 1921–1933 (New York: Harper & Row, 1960), pp. 195–202Google Scholar; Fite, Gilbert C., George N. Peek and the Fight for Farm Parity (Norman, Okla.: University of Oklahoma Press, 1954)Google Scholar; Rosen, , From Depresion to New Deal, pp. 188–89Google Scholar. FDR's first mention of the tariff issue in the campaign was in a speech before the New York Grange; Roosevelt, , Public Papers and Addresses, vol. 1, pp. 155–57.Google Scholar
48. As Rosen, argues, “their conflict with Hull … was rooted in the requirement for a self-contained economy and an artificial internal price structure.”Google ScholarFrom Depression to New Deal, p. 180ff. For Wallace's, views, see his New Frontiers (New York: Harcourt Brace, 1934)Google Scholar, and the critique by Taylor, Alonzo E., The New Deal and Foreign Trade (New York: MacMillan, 1935)Google Scholar. For an analysis of state intervention in agriculture, see Theda, Skocpol and Kenneth, Finegold, “State Capacity and Economic Intervention in the Early New Deal,” Political Science Quarterly 97 (Summer 1982).Google Scholar
49. Tugwell saw the fight as one between the brains trust and certain Westerners, including Senators Walsh and Pittman, against Hull, traditional Democrats, and “others in Wall Street who sold foreign securities to American investors … and wanted to speculate as they liked and therefore objected to national economic fences.” The Brains Trust, p. 476.
50. Moley, , After Seven Years, p. 47.Google Scholar
51. The speech was drafted by protectionist Senators Pittman and Walsh. Hull's representative, Charles Taussig, was pushed to the side. Ibid., p. 50; Tugwell, , The Brains Trust, pp. 478–90.Google Scholar
52. Roosevelt, , Public Papers and Addresses, vol. 1, pp. 766, 767.Google Scholar
53. This idea had already been put forward in the Collier trade bill of 1932, which contained many innovations in trade policy, but was vetoed by Hoover. Roosevelt, , Public Papers and Addresses, vol. 1, p. 769.Google Scholar
54. Moley, , After Seven Years, p. 51Google Scholar; Roosevelt, , Public Papers and Addresses, vol. 1, p. 853.Google Scholar
55. Rosen traces Norman Davis's effort to push a multilateral view in “Intranationalism vs. Internationalism,” p. 285.
56. The best overview of the London economic conference is Kindelberger, , World in Depression, chap. 9Google Scholar. The most thorough discussion of the commercial aspects of the conference are in Kottman, Richard N., Reciprocity and the North Atlantic Triangle, 1932–1938 (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1968), chap. 2Google Scholar. For the views of the principles, see Feis, Herbert, Characters in Crisis 1933 (Boston: Little, Brown, 1966) chaps. 14–20Google Scholar; Moley, Raymond, The First New Deal (New York: Harcourt Brace, 1966), chaps. 33–38Google Scholar; and Hull, , MemoirsGoogle Scholar, vol. 1, chaps. 18 and 19. Norman Davis raised hopes through successful negotiation of a limited tariff truce in May, but the many reservations expressed by its adherents called the value of the agreement into question.
57. Hull, , Memoirs, vol. 1, p. 250Google Scholar. For the draft bill see Record Group 59, 611.0031/428, National Archives.
58. Roosevelt, , Press Conferences, 31 05 1933, vol. 1, pp. 324–25.Google Scholar
59. See Frank, Freidel, Launching the New Deal, pp. 439–40, 450Google Scholar; Feis, , Characters in Crisis 1933, p. 174Google Scholar; Hull, , Memoirs, vol. 1, p. 251Google Scholar; Moley, , The First New Deal, pp. 420–22.Google Scholar
60. Hull, , Memoirs, vol. 1, p. 252.Google Scholar
61. Ibid.
62. Feis calls Hull's laments on the fate of the conference “histrionic.” Feis, , Characters in Crisis 1933, p. 175.Google Scholar
63. Leuchtenberg, William E., Franklin D. Roosevelt, p. 64.Google Scholar
64. State's relations with Henry Wallace and the AAA were less strained, but in agriculture the principle problem was promoting exports. Section 15(e) of the AAA empowered the president to levy an equal compensating tax on agricultural goods, subject to processing taxes. On the turf fights, see Steward, Dick, Trade and Hemisphere, the Good Neighbor Policy and Reciprocal Trade (Columbia: University of Missouri Press, 1975), pp. 15–16.Google Scholar
65. New York Times, 25 October and 5 November 1933.
66. New York Times, 5 November 1933. The NRA could also initiate its own investigations. Herbert Feis argues that the trade provisions were used only to prevent codes from toppling, although the United States did place import quotas on liquor, lumber, tobacco, potatoes, cotton, and sugar. Feis, , Characters in Crisis 1933, p. 262Google Scholar; Steward, , Trade and Hemisphere, p. 15ff.Google Scholar
67. This paragraph draws on Kindleberger, , World in Depression, chap. 9Google Scholar; Oye, , “The Sterling-Dollar-Franc Triangle”Google Scholar; Wicker, Elmus, “Roosevelt's 1933 Monetary Experiment,” The Journal of American History 57 (03 1971)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Moore, James R., “Sources of New Deal Economic Policy: The International Dimension,” Journal of American History 61 (12 1974)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Nicholas, Jeanette, “Roosevelt's Monetary Diplomacy in 1933.” American Historical Review 56 (01 1951).Google Scholar
68. House of Representatives, Hearings, pp. 65–66Google Scholar. Feis also recognized the importance of devaluation for trade policy in his Characters in Crisis 1933, p. 264.
69. William Phillips Diary, 8 December 1933, Houghton Library, Harvard University.
70. Feis, , Characters in Crisis, p. 262.Google Scholar
71. Sayre, , The Way Forward, p. 56Google Scholar; Hull, , Memoirs, vol. 1, p. 354.Google Scholar
72. Feis, , Characters in Crisis 1933, p. 264.Google Scholar
73. It was widely recognized that the negotiation of reciprocal agreements would require lifting protection from some industries. See Executive Committee Report, supplement 1, which offers a detailed classification scheme; Tariff Commission, “Draft Statement on Reducible Tariff Rates,” 13 February 1934, OF 60; and Willard Thorp's observations on the thinking in the Department of Commerce in Katie, Louchheim, ed., The Making of the New Deal: The Insiders Speak (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1983), pp. 275–76.Google Scholar
74. Senate Finance Committee, Hearings, p. 5.Google Scholar
75. Public Papers and Addresses, vol. 3, pp. 113–16.
76. I am thankful to David Lake for this point. See Kelly, , “Antecedents.”Google Scholar
77. Hull, , Memoirs, vol. 1, p. 356.Google Scholar
78. On the growth of executive power over the tariff, see John Day, Larkin, The President's Control of the Tariff (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1936).Google Scholar
79. “Minority Views,” in Congressional Record, 27 March 1934, pp. 5532–33Google Scholar; Vandenburg, , Congressional Record, 18 05 1934, pp. 9081–82Google Scholar. For an overview of the constitutional issues see Sayre, , The Way Forward, chap. 7.Google Scholar
80. Congressional Record, 25 May 1934, p. 9567.Google Scholar
81. This balance is the main theme of Pastor, U.S. Foreign Economic Policy.
82. Kelly, , “Antecedents,” p. 81Google Scholar; Pastor, , U.S. Foreign Economic Policy, pp. 179–85Google Scholar. On the renewals of 1937 and 1940, see Steven Robert, Brenner, “Economic Interests and the Trade Agreements Program, 1937–1940.”Google Scholar
83. For the administration's objections to public hearings, see Senate Finance Committee, Hearings, pp. 15, 29, 80–81, 130.Google Scholar
84. See Phillips Diary, 11 December 1933.
85. Peek's views also reflected more immediately the interests of the food and textile industries. Steward, , Trade and Hemisphere, p. 32.Google Scholar
86. A 70-page draft of Peek's plan for a Foreign Trade Board is enclosed with Peek to FDR, 16 July 1935. See also FDR to Peek, 17 July 1935, both in President's Secretary's File 73, FDR Library; Phillips Diary, 2 January 1934.
87. On the Peek–Hull controversy, see George, Fite, George N. Peek, chaps. 16–17Google Scholar; Steward, , Trade and Hemisphere, chap. 2Google Scholar; Peek, George N. and Crowther, Samuel, Why Quit Our Own? (New York: Van Nostrand, 1936)Google Scholar. The correspondence between Peek, FDR, and Hull, and Peek's objections are set out in “Report of the Special Adviser on Foreign Trade,” enclosed with Peek to FDR, 31 December 1934; OF 614A, cited hereafter as Report of the Special Adviser, and in a series of six articles in the Saturday Evening Post, 16 May–20 June 1936.
88. On the establishment of the Ex-Im banks, see Adams, Frederick C., Economic Diplomacy: the Export–Import Bank and American Foreign Policy 1934–1939 (Columbia: University of Missouri Press, 1976), chap. 3.Google Scholar
89. Hull, , Memoirs, vol. 1, p. 370.Google Scholar
90. Francis Bowes, Sayre, “Draft: Memorandum on Machinery for the Effectuating of a Foreign Trade Policy,” attached to Executive Committee ReportGoogle Scholar; Phillips Diary, 2 January, 27 February, 23 March, 1934.
91. See Mary Trackett, Reynolds, Interdepartmental Committees in the National Administration (New York: Columbia University Press, 1939), pp. 47–70Google Scholar; Sayre, , The Way Forward, chap. 8Google Scholar; Rexford Tugwell Diary, vol. 5, pp. 13–14; Steward, , Trade and Hemisphere, pp. 44–45.Google Scholar
92. The following passage draws on the Report of the Special Adviser.
93. See “Memorandum submitted by the Special Adviser … for consideration at its Meeting December 4 …,“ enclosed with the Report of the Special Adviser.
94. On the German deal, see Steward, , Trade and Hemisphere, pp. 52–53Google Scholar; Phillips Diary, 13 and 14 December 1934. For almost a year after that conflict, Roosevelt kept Peek around. Only after Peek had supplied the press with material critical of the reciprocal trade program, did Roosevelt finally lose his patience. FDR to Peek, 22 November 1935; Peek to FDR, 26 November 1935; FDR to Peek, 11 December 1935.
95. Sayre, , The Way Forward, p. 94.Google Scholar
96. Typical of the numerous letters protesting this arrangement is Congressman Edward Eicher to Hull, 17 August 1934, which encloses a letter from the Iowa Manufacturers Association and R. Walter Moore (State Department) to Eicher, 1 September 1934, Record Group 59, 611.0031/1013, National Archives. See also Robert Lund, chairman of the board, National Association of Manufacturers to FDR, 23 April 1935, RG 59, 611.0031/1650.
97. Brenner, , “Economic Interests,” p. 108ff.Google Scholar
98. Steiwer to FDR, 4 April 1935; FDR to Steiwer, 8 April 1935; OF 614A.
99. Six of the communications asked that particular concessions not be sought from the Belgians. See “Belgium: Committee for Reciprocity Information: Record of Correspondence, Oct. 19–Oct. 25, 1934,” RG 59, 611.0031/Committee for Reciprocity Information/75, National Archives.
100. Sayre, , The Way Forward, p. 96.Google Scholar
101. Kottman, , Reciprocity and the North Atlantic Triangle, p. 257.Google Scholar
102. Goldstein, , “The Political Economy of Trade.”Google Scholar
103. Kindleberger, Charles P., World in Depression, p. 292.Google Scholar
104. Krasner, , “State Power.”Google Scholar Contrast Lake, “Beneath the Commerce of Nations” and “The State and American Trade Policy in the Pre-hegemonic Era,” this volume.
105. Oye makes a similar argument in “The Sterling-Dollar-Franc Triangle.”
106. Pastor, , U.S. Foreign Economic PolicyGoogle Scholar; Gil, Winham, “Robert Strauss, the MTN and the Control of Faction,” Journal of World Trade Law 14 (09/10 1980)Google Scholar. Pastor virtually ignores the role of the private sector.
107. For example, Stephen, Krasner, Defending the National Interest (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1978).Google Scholar
108. Examples of recent work in American politics that gives weight to “state” actors would include the literature on agenda-setting; see John, Kingdon, Agendas, Alternatives and Public Policies (Boston: Little, Brown, 1984)Google Scholar; and on policy communities, Hugh, Heclo, “Issue Networks and the Executive Branch,” in Anthony, King, ed., The New American Political System (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1978).Google Scholar
- 88
- Cited by