Article contents
Informal market governance in Japan's basic materials industries
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 22 May 2009
Abstract
Too much emphasis has been placed on formal state policies and on ties between individual firms to explain Japanese economic behavior and impediments to imports in Japanese markets. We need to look instead at informal governance by trade associations. In so doing, the concept of relational contracting should be applied not just to dyadic relationships between individual firms but also to relationships between entire industries. Whole industries engage in relational contracting to ensure the stability of both prices and supplies. These industry agreements stabilize Japanese markets but at the same time keep imports out of them. This informal governance complements state policies to support uncompetitive industries. These agreements are more likely to occur and succeed between selling and buying industries that each are relatively concentrated, when upstream products are standardized, when upstream goods constitute a smaller share of downstream production costs, when these sectors have not experienced previous conflicts that undermine cooperation, and when the Ministry of International Trade and Industry wants a domestic supply of its products.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © The IO Foundation 1994
References
1. MITI, Sankōhō no kaisetsu (Commentary on the Structurally Depressed Industries Law) (Tokyo: MITI, 1983), pp. 82–84Google Scholar.
2. Personal interview with MITI official, Tokyo, February 1992.
3. Ozawa, Terutomo, Multinationalism, Japanese Style: The Political Economy of Outward Dependency (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1979)Google Scholar.
4. On coal, see Samuels, Richard, The Business of the Japanese State (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987)Google Scholar. On aluminum refining, see Tilton, Mark, Restrained Trade: Cartels in Japan's Basic Materials Industries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar, in press).
5. Dore, Ronald, Flexible Rigidities: Industrial Policy and Structural Adjustment in the Japanese Economy 1970–1980 (London: Athlone Press, 1986)Google Scholar.
6. Williamson, Oliver R., The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relations Contracting (New York: Free Press, 1985)Google Scholar.
7. Nakatani, Iwao, “The Economic Role of the Financial Corporate Grouping,” in Aoki, Masahiko, ed., The Economic Analysis of the Japanese Firm (North Holland, Netherlands: Elsevier Science Publishers, 1984), pp. 227–58Google Scholar.
8. Dore, , Flexible Rigidities, p. 81Google Scholar.
9. For the former argument, see Anderson, Douglas, “Managing Retreat: Disinvestment Policy,” in McCraw, Thomas, ed., America Versus Japan (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1986), pp. 337–72Google Scholar; Abegglen, James C. and Stalk, George Jr, Kaisha: The Japanese Corporation (New York: Basic Books, 1985)Google Scholar; Peck, Merton J., Levin, Richard C., and Goto, Akira, “Picking Losers: Public Policy Toward Declining Industries in Japan,” Journal of Japanese Studies 13 (Spring 1987), pp. 79–123CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Shimada, Haruo, “Japanese Capitalism: The Irony of Success,” Economic Eye (Autumn, 1992), p. 30Google Scholar; Schmiegelow, Michèle, “Cutting Across Doctrines: Positive Adjustment in Japan,” International Organization 39 (Spring 1985), pp. 261–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Yamazawa, Ippei, Economic Development and International Trade: The Japanese Model (Honolulu: East-West Center, 1990)Google Scholar.
10. For the former argument, see Sheard, Paul, “Corporate Organisation and Industrial Adjustment in the Japanese Aluminum Industry,” in Sheard, Paul, ed., International Adjustment and the Japanese Firm (Saint Leonards, Australia: Allen and Unwin, 1992), pp. 125–39Google Scholar; and Dore, Flexible Rigidities.
11. For the former argument, see Noble, Gregory W., “The Japanese Industrial Policy Debate,” in Haggard, Stephan and Moon, Chung-in, eds., Pacific Dynamics: The International Politics of Industrial Change (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989), pp. 53–95Google Scholar; and Friedman, David, The Misunderstood Miracle: Industrial Development and Political Change in Japan (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1988)Google Scholar. For the latter, see McKean, Margaret, “State Strength and Public Interest,” in Allinson, Gary, ed., Political Dynamics in Contemporary Japan (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1993), pp. 72–104Google Scholar; Johnson, Chalmers, MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925–1975 (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1982)Google Scholar; and Okimoto, Daniel I., Between MITI and the Market: Japanese Industrial Policy for High Technology (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1989)Google Scholar.
12. Onoda semento hyakunen shi (A one-hundred-year history of the Onoda Cement Company) (Tokyo: Onoda Semento Kabushikigaisha, 1981), p. 687Google Scholar.
13. Personal interview with cement company official, Tokyo, November 1988.
14. Personal interview with Cement Association official, Tokyo, December 1988.
15. On MITI's push for joint sales companies, see the cement annual, Semento Nenkan, vol. 38 (Tokyo: Semento Shinbun Sha, 1986), p. 11Google Scholar. The FTC's limitations were discussed in a personal interview with cement company officials, Tokyo, November 1988.
16. Semento Nenkan, vol. 26 (1974), p. 54Google Scholar.
17. Personal interviews with Ssangyong Cement officials, Seoul, April 1988.
18. See the industrial affairs newspaper, Nihon Keizai Sangyō Shinbun, 27 May 1986.
19. Personal interviews with cement company officials, Tokyo, November 1988.
20. Ibid.
21. Personal interview with Cement Association official, Tokyo, December 1988.
22. Personal interview with employee of a “tied agent” firm (tokuyaku ten), that is, a dealer tied to a specific supplier, Tokyo, March 1988. See also Krauss, Ellis S. and Coles, Isobel, “Built-in Impediments: The Political Economy of the U.S.-Japan Construction Dispute,” in Yamamura, Kozo, ed., Japan's Economic Structure: Should It Change? (Seattle, Wash.: Society for Japanese Studies, 1990), pp. 333–58Google Scholar; and Hidenori, Itagaki, Zoku no kenkyū: sei kan zai wo gyūjiru seikai jitsutyokusha shudan no jittai (A study of the tribes: The reality of the groups of the powerholders who control the world of politics, the bureaucracy, and finance) (Tokyo: Keizaikai, 1987)Google Scholar.
23. Personal interview with an employee of a tied agent, Tokyo, March 1988.
24. Personal interview with Ssangyong officials, Seoul, March 1988.
25. Telephone interview with Japanese customs bureau official, Tokyo, December 1988.
26. Semento Nenkan, vol. 37 (1985) pp. 30–31Google Scholar.
27. Ibid., p. 30.
28. On the plan, see the economics newspaper Nihon Keizai Shinbun, September 1986.
29. Nihon Keizai Sangyō Shinbun, 9 October 1986.
30. See Mitsuo, Nishimiya, “Semento Seizōgyōsha no dokusen kinshi hō ihan jiken” (The violation of the Anti-Monopoly by cement producers), Kōsei Torihiki, no. 485 (03 1991), pp. 54–61Google Scholar; and “Japanese Cement Makers Cited for Dumping by U.S.,” Japan Economic Journal, 4 May 1991.
31. Upham, Frank K., Law and Social Change in Postwar Japan (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1987), p. 196Google Scholar.
32. Kagaku Keizai, vol. 30, no. 7 (07 1983), p. 46Google Scholar.
33. Personal interview with journalist specializing in petrochemical prices for a major Japanese newspaper, Tokyo, February 1992.
34. Nihon Keizai Shinbun, 14 November 1987.
35. “Orefuin: Juyō teimei de jukyū gyappu kakudai” (Olefins: Supply–demand gap widens with continued low demand), Kagaku Keizai, vol. 40, no. 10, special issue (08 1993), p. 27Google Scholar.
36. I thank Ward Hansen for alerting me to this comparison with the United States.
37. Nihon Keizai Shinbun, 11 May 1989.
38. Ibid.
39. Japanese newspapers take postsales pricing for granted and rarely mention it, except occasionally in contrast to Western and Korean practices; see 1989 Asahi Nenkan, p. 173; and Nihon Keizai Shinbun, 11 May 1989. It also made the news during the Persian Gulf War when petrochemical suppliers threatened to abandon the system and buyers defended it; see Nihon Keizai Shinbun, 7 November 1990. Numerous petrochemical company officials told me in interviews that the system was used throughout the petrochemical market.
40. The price of propylene, the other major feedstock, is pegged to the ethylene price.
41. Trade association leaders made their concerns clear in long zadankai (group discussion) pieces in the Sekiyu kagaku kōgyō shinbun (Petrochemical Industry Newspaper) of 1975.
42. Nihon Keizai Sangyō Shinbun, 6 September 1983.
43. See, for example, articles in Nihon Keizai Shinbun, 9 September 1987 and 11 August 1989.
44. Nihon Keizai Shinbun, 22 December 1983.
45. Nihon Keizai Sangyō Shinbun, 29 September 1990.
46. Personal interview with automobile plastics buyers, Tokyo, February 1992.
47. Ibid.
48. Nihon Keizai Sangyō Shinbun, 6 September 1983. This was also reported in Kagaku Kōgyō Nenkan, 1985, p. 204.
49. Nihon Keizai Shinbun, 27 April 1988.
50. Nihon Keizai Shinbun, 7 November 1990.
51. Personal interview with automobile plastics buyers, Tokyo, February 1992.
52. Asian Wall Street Journal, 7 November 1991.
53. Nikkei Weekly, 16 November 1991.
54. Personal interview with official of Chemical Economics Institute, Tokyo, November 1988.
55. See Ike, Brian, “The Japanese Textile Industry: Structural Adjustment and Government Policy,” Asian Survey 20 (05 1980), pp. 532–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Friedman, The Misunderstood Miracle.
56. See Asahi Shinbun, 22 July 1986; and Shinbun, Nihon Keizai, Japan Economic Almanac (Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Shinbun, 1992), p. 142Google Scholar.
57. Scherer, F. M. and Ross, David, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, 3d ed. (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1990), pp. 57–96, 235–74, and 279–84Google Scholar.
58. Yoshida, Naoko, “Makers Fail to Explain Differences in Electronics Prices,” Tokyo Business Today 61 (01/02 1993), p. 60Google Scholar.
59. Personal interview with president of Japanese aluminum refining company, Tokyo, October 1986.
60. Personal interview with newspaper reporter specializing in chemical prices for a major Japanese newspaper, Tokyo, February 1992.
61. Personal interview with detergent manufacturing company official, Tokyo, November 1988.
62. Nikkei Sangyō Shinbun, 6 April 1987.
63. Personal interview with automobile plastics buyers, Tokyo, February 1992.
64. Steinmo, Sven and Thelen, Kathleen, “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics,” in Steinmo, Sven, Thelen, Kathleen, and Longstreth, Frank, eds., Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992), pp. 1–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
65. Personal interview with aluminum rolling company official, Tokyo, January 1988.
66. MITI, Sankōhō no kaisetsu, p. 7Google Scholar.
67. Personal interview with aluminum rolling company official, Tokyo, January 1988.
68. See Putnam, Robert, “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games,” International Organization 42 (Summer 1988), pp. 427–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Mayer, Frederick W., “Managing Domestic Differences in Negotiations,” International Organization 46 (Autumn 1992), pp. 793–818CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
69. Naka, Norio, “A Multi-dimensional Approach to the United States–Japan Structural Impediments Initiative: Gaiatsu, Transgovernmental Politics, and Elite Policy Networks,” Ph.D. diss., Purdue University, 1994Google Scholar.
70. See U.S. International Trade Commission, “Gray Portland Cement and Cement Clinker from Japan: Determination of the Commission in Investigation no. 731-TA-461,” 1991Google Scholar; and Wall Street Journal, 24 April 1991.
71. U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, U.S. Imports of Merchandise, 1990–1993Google Scholar editions.
- 3
- Cited by