Article contents
How Japan affects the international system
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 22 May 2009
Abstract
To cope with more than incremental change in the international system, the neorealist concept of structure and the neoliberal concept of process must be complemented by a third analytically distinguished element: the concept of action. All three concepts can be used on the systemic level of analysis of international relations theory. Their obvious differentiation is the degree of systemic consolidation, with structure at the highest, action at the lowest, and process at unstable intermediate degrees. Without analyzing prevailing models of action of important units of the international system, it is impossible to predict the possible range of outcomes of processes and structural changes in the international system.
This article offers Japan's “strategic pragmatism” as a model of action. The model, representing a functional cut across contending economic doctrines, combines relative fiscal conservatism with “progressive” provision of credit, dynamic capitalism with public policy activism, and critical rationalism with philosophical pragmatism. Japan's strategic pragmatism has not only enabled its government and enterprises to cope with uncertainty and change in their domestic and international environment but has also increased global welfare and changed the balance of strategic components of power in the international system. The spread of this model of action both within and beyond Japan's control points to a paradigm change in economic and international relations theory—that is, to the most pervasive form of systemic consolidation.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © The IO Foundation 1990
References
1. See Schmiegelow, Henrik, “Global Dimensions in US-Japan Relations,” Aussenpolitik 37 (Fall 1986), pp. 222–38Google Scholar; Schmiegelow, Michèle, “Puissance et interdependence: Le nouveau rôle mondial du Japon” (Power and interdependence: The new global role of Japan), Res Publica 29 (12 1987), pp. 555–74Google Scholar; Calder, Kent, “Japanese Foreign Economic Policy Formation: Explaining the Reactive State,” World Politics 40 (07 1988), pp. 517–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Inoguchi, Takashi, ”Four Japanese Scenarios for the Future,” International Affairs, 01 1988–1989, pp. 15–28Google Scholar.
2. For a survey, see Inoguchi, “Four Japanese Scenarios for the Future.”
3. See M. Schmiegelow, “Puissance et interdépendance.” For the most recent restatement of the tension between the two paradigms, see Keohane, Robert and Nye, Joseph S. Jr, “Power and Interdependence Revisited,” International Organization 41 (Autumn 1987), pp. 725–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Nye, Joseph, “Neorealism and Neoliberalism,” World Politics 40 (01 1988), pp. 235–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
4. Schmiegelow, Henrik, “Idealism and Realism in US Foreign Policy,” Aussenpolilik 40 (01 1989), pp. 16–30Google Scholar.
5. Singer, J. David, “The Level-of-Analysis Problem in International Relations,” in Rosenau, James N., ed., International Politics and Foreign Policy (New York: Free Press, 1969), pp. 20–29Google Scholar.
6. Schmiegelow, Michèle, “Cutting Across Doctrines: Positive Adjustment in Japan,” International Organization 39 (Spring 1985), pp. 261–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
7. Hoffman, Stanley, “Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe,” Daedalus, vol. 95, 1966, pp. 862–87Google Scholar.
8. Schmiegelow, Henrik and Schmiegelow, Michèle, “The New Mercantilism in International Relations: The Case of France's External Monetary Policy,” International Organization 29 (Spring 1975), pp. 367–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
9. See Gilpin, Robert, War and Change in World Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For a contribution to this line of thought from an historian, see Kennedy, Paul, The Rise and Fall of Great Powers: Economic Change and Military Conflict from 1500 to 2000 (New York: Random House, 1987)Google Scholar.
10. Waltz, Kenneth, Theory of International Politics (Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1979)Google Scholar.
11. For the most recent survey focusing on the neoliberal paradigm in contrast to the neorealist paradigm, see Nye, “Neorealism and Neoliberalism.” Regarding interdependence theory, see Cooper, Richard N., “Macroeconomic Policy Adjustment in Interdependent Economies,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 83 (02 1969), pp. 1–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Bergsten, C. Fred, Keohane, Robert O., and Nye, Joseph S., “International Economics and International Politics: A Framework for Analysis,” International Organization 29 (Winter 1975), pp. 20–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Regarding the transnational paradigm, see Morse, Edward L., “Transnational Economic Processes,” in Keohane, Robert O. and Nye, Joseph S.. eds., Transnational Relations and World Politics, special issue of International Organization 25 (Summer 1971), pp. 373–97Google Scholar.
12. M. Schmiegelow, “Cutting Across Doctrines.”
13. Waltz, Theory of International Politics.
14. Calder, , “Japanese Foreign Economic Policy Formation,” p. 517Google Scholar.
15. Nye, “Neorealism and Neoliberalism.”
16. For a discussion of the problem of theoretical disjunctives affecting the understanding of the Japanese case, see M. Schmiegelow, “Cutting Across Doctrines.”
17. Waltz, , Theory of International Politics, p. 161Google Scholar.
18. See Nye, Joseph, Bound to Lead: The Changing Nature of American Power (New York: Basic Books, 1989)Google Scholar.
19. For surveys of the various contending interpretations, see Schmiegelow, M., “Cutting Across Doctrines”; and Schmiegelow, Michèle and Schmiegeiow, Henrik, Strategic Pragmatism: Japanese Lessons in the Use of Economic Theory (New York: Praeger, 1989), pp. 3 and 29Google Scholar. The quote is from one of the most popular revisionist writers, van Wolferen, Karel, in “Japan: Different, Unprecedented and Dangerous,” International Herald Tribune, 7 11 1989, p. 6Google Scholar.
20. See Schmiegelow, H., “Global Dimensions in US-Japan Relations,” pp. 224 and 227Google Scholar; and Calder, , “Japanese Foreign Economic Policy Formation.” p. 535Google Scholar.
21. The estimates of Japan's external assets in 1990 and 2000 are those of NEEDS, the databank of Japan's leading economic journal, Nihon Keizai, and were reported on 24 January 1987.
22. For a discussion of the increasing dependence of U.S. industry on high-technology components from Japan, see National Research Council, Toward a New Era in US Manufacturing: The Need for a National Vision (Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 1986)Google Scholar; Schrage, Michael, “US Dependence on Japan for Parts Worries Pentagon,” Washington Post, 11 03 1986Google Scholar; Kenney, George, “Dependence and Patterns of Interdependency,” paper presented at the Second Symposium on US-Japan Science and Technology Exchange, 17–18 11 1986, Washington, D.C., pp. 17–21Google Scholar; and Iwama, M. and Magee, F. R., “Computers and Communications: Technology Interdependency Between the US and Japan,” paper presented at the Second Symposium on US-Japan Science and Technology Exchange, 17–18 11 1986, Washington, D.C., pp. 9–11Google Scholar. The perception of growing U.S. dependence on Japanese semiconductors spurred the debate in the United States about the merits of emulating Japan's industrial policy in general and precompetitive research cooperation in particular. See National Advisory Committee on Semiconductors, Report to the President and the Congress, advance edition (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 11 1989)Google Scholar.
23. See Schmiegelow, H., “Global Dimensions in US-Japan Relations,” p. 224Google Scholar. The most compelling demonstration of U.S.-Japan macroeconomic integration is offered by the “Feldstein doctrine,” which takes the U.S. budget deficit as a given structural pattern, encourages U.S. dependence on capital inflows from Japan (inflows that prevent crowding out of private capital demand by the U.S. treasury's finance requirements), and recognizes the upward pressure of these capital inflows on the dollar as an acceptable price. See Council of Economic Advisors, Economic Report to the President (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 02 1983 and February 1984)Google Scholar; and Feldstein, Martin, “The Dollar Exchange Rate,” remarks presented to the World Affairs Council in Philadelphia on 29 02 1984Google Scholar.
The pattern of macroeconomic integration has become one of the most salient features of the U.S.-Japan relationship, with Japan alone having financed one-third of the U.S. budget deficit ever since 1984. There are two conceivable interpretations of the political economy of this pattern, one in terms of the mercantilist paradigm and one in terms of the theory of economic integration. From the point of view of the mercantilist paradigm, the two countries may be seen as simultaneously involved in two grandiose zero-sum games for different stakes: Japan exporting unemployment to the United States through undervaluation of the yen and the United States importing wealth through overvaluation of the dollar. (For a categorization of the instruments of various mercantilist strategies, see Schmiegelow, Henrik, “Japan's Exchange Rate Policy: Policy Targets, Non-Policy Variables and Discretionary Adjustment,” in Schmiegelow, Michèle, ed., Japan's Response to Crisis and Change in the World Economy [Artnonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 1986], pp. 28–43.)Google Scholar However, autonomous variables have gained too much influence on capital flows since the 1980 liberalization of Japan's foreign exchange control regime to make mercantilist policy control possible even if it were attempted. Thus, whatever the policy calculations on both sides, we are left with a two-country macroeconomic equilibrium based on complementary fiscal policies, interest rate levels, capital flows, and exchange rates. If global recession is to be avoided, neither Japan nor the United States, nor the rest of the world for that matter, can afford to break out of this pattern. (See Schmiegelow, Michèle and Schmiegelow, Henrik, “The Revisionists Aren't Looking Beneath the Surface,” International Herald Tribune, 31 01 1990, p. 6.)Google Scholar Nothing similar to the U.S.-Japan macroeconomic integration exists anywhere else in the world. Members of the EC, having pursued a strategy of precarious policy harmonization by adopting a common exchange rate regime before liberalizing intra-EC capital flows, are still a considerable number of steps behind the type of macroeconomic integration evident in U.S.-Japan relations.
While Japanese portfolio investments in the United States became the principal carrier of economic integration between the two countries, direct investments on which the transnational paradigm of international relations has always focused have long failed to contribute significantly to integration in either the EC or the U.S.-Japan relationship. In the course of the 1980s, however, direct investments became at least a factor of public debate in both areas. U.S. firms in Japan had become a source of U.S. imports of a magnitude sufficient to account alone for the U.S. trade deficit with Japan. (See Pempel, T. J., “The Trade Imbalance Isn't the Problem,” Cornell International Law Journal, vol. 22, no. 3, 1989, pp. 442–44.)Google Scholar On the other hand, spectacular direct investments did have dysfunctional political side effects in European host countries as well as in the United States. When Italy's maverick tycoon de Benedetti attempted to take over Belgium's treasured Société Générale, the public outcry provoked resentments of a nature similar to U.S. reactions against Sony's acquisition of Columbia Pictures and Mitsubishi Estate's purchase of the Rockefeller Center.
The question of whether intrasectoral trade or complementary trade structures are better measures of integration through trade is still unsettled in the theory of economic integration. While trade integration in the EC is marked by intrasectoral trade, the classical pattern of complementary supply structures and thus much higher degrees of division of labor continues to distinguish the U.S.-Japan relationship. The reliability of any measure of technological interdependence is as uncertain as the epistemology of science and technology itself. But as the sources quoted in footnote 22 (above) make plain, if there is any interdependence on the higher end of marketable high-technology products, it is interdependence between the United States and Japan, with EC members risking dependence on either or both of these two if they do not manage to join their forces more effectively in the 1990s than in the previous two decades. See M. and Schmiegelow, H., Strategic Pragmatism, pp. 62–69Google Scholar.
24. Calder, , “Japanese Foreign Economic Policy Formation,” p. 537Google Scholar.
25. See H. Schmiegelow, “Global Dimensions in US-Japan Relations”; and M. Schmiegelow, “Puissance et interdépendance.”
26. van Wolferen, Karel, “The Japan Problem,” Foreign Affairs 65 (Winter 1986–1987), p. 302Google Scholar.
27. See Calder, , “Japanese Foreign Economic Policy Formation,” p. 521Google Scholar; and Schmiegelow, H., “Japan's Exchange Rate Policy,” pp. 28–43Google Scholar.
28. Yoshitomi, Masaru, “External Adjustment Almost Complete, but Conflicts with U.S. Are Continuing,” Japan Economic Journal, 10 03 1990, p. 6Google Scholar.
29. Helmut Laumer, “Japan's Distribution System: Its Social Function and Import Impeding Effects,” in Schmiegelow, M., Japan's Response to Crisis and Change in the World Economy. pp. 257–77Google Scholar.
30. See Boone, Peter and Sachs, Jeffrey, “Is Tokyo Worth Four Trillion Dollars? An Explanation for High Japanese Land Prices,” paper presented to the Japan Economic Seminar, Columbia University, New York, 18 11 1989Google Scholar.
31. van Wolferen, Karel, “The Wondrous Japanese Money Machine,” International Herald Tribune, 7 11 1989, p. 6Google Scholar.
32. Dornbusch, Rüdiger, “Getting Tough on Trade: Give Japan a Target and Say ‘Import,’“ The New York Times, 24 09 1989Google Scholar.
33. See Bell, Daniel and Kristoll, Irving, eds., The Crisis in Economic Theory (New York: Basic Books, 1982)Google Scholar.
34. Dean, James W., “The Dissolution of the Keynesian Consensus,” in Bell, and Kristoll, , The Crisis in Economic Theory, p. 25Google Scholar.
35. Robert Mundell, quoted by Drucker, Peter F. in “Toward the Next Economics,” in Bell, and Kristoll, , The Crisis in Economic Theory, p. 15Google Scholar.
36. See Fellner, William, Economic Theory Amidst Political Currents: The Spreading Interest in Monetarism and the Theory of Market Expectations (Tubingen: J. C. B. Mohr, 1982), p. 3Google Scholar; and Willes, Mark H., “Rational Expectations as a Counterrevolution,” in Bell, and Kristoll, , The Crisis in Economic Theory, pp. 81–96Google Scholar.
37. See Pempel, T. J., Policy and Politics in Japan: Creative Conservatism (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1981)Google Scholar.
38. Fellner, , Economic Theory Amidst Political Currents, p. 3Google Scholar.
39. Kahn was probably the first to use the term “Japanese superstate.” See Kahn, Herman, The Emerging Japanese Superstate: Challenge and Response (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1970)Google Scholar. See also Johnson, Chalmers, MITI and the Japanese Economic Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925–1975 (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1982)Google Scholar.
40. See, for example, Burns, Arthur, The United States and Germany (New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1986)Google Scholar; and Dahrendorf, Ralf and Soerensen, Theodore C., A Widening Atlantic? Domestic Change and Foreign Policy (New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1986)Google Scholar.
41. , M. and Schmiegelow, H., Strategic Pragmatism, pp. 118–22Google Scholar.
42. For an excellent analysis of this development, see Kaletsky, Anatole, “Unlocking the Value of Latent Assets,” Financial Times, 25 08 1989, p. 18Google Scholar.
43. See Schumpeter, Joseph, Business Cycles (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1939)Google Scholar. See also Takeo Hoshi, Anil Kashyap, and David Scharfstein, “Bank Monitoring and Investment: Evidence from the Changing Structure of Japanese Corporate Banking Relationships,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 3079; and Aoki, Masahiko, “Towards an Economic Model of the Japanese Firm,” Journal of Economic Literature 28 (03 1990)Google Scholar.
44. Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of Great Powers.
45. Regarding the exchange rate, see Schmiegelow, H., “Japan's Exchange Rate Policy,” pp. 288–94Google Scholar. Regarding the tax system, see Adams, T. F. M. and Hoshii, Iwao, A Financial History of the New Japan (Tokyo: Kodansha, 1972), pp. 71 and 124Google Scholar. Regarding fiscal policy, see Hadley, Eleanor, “The Diffusion of Keynesian Ideas in Japan,” in Hall, Peter A., ed., The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism Across Nations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1989), pp. 291–310Google Scholar.
46. Sato, Kazuo, “The Wealth Target and Saving: Theory and Japanese Evidence,” paper presented to the Japan Economic Seminar, Columbia University, New York, 28 02 1987Google Scholar.
47. Reischauer, Edwin O., East Asia: The Great Tradition (Tokyo: Charles Tuttle, 1962), pp. 519–21Google Scholar.
48. For a discussion about the distinction between the Colbertist and Gaullist brands of mercantilism, see H. and M. Schmiegelow, “The New Mercantilism in International Relations.”
49. , M. and Schmiegelow, H., Strategic Pragmatism, pp. 62–69Google Scholar.
50. Ibid., p. 30.
51. Ibid., pp. 155–80.
52. See the following works by Popper, Karl: The Poverty of Historicism (New York: Harper Torchbooks, 1960), pp. 57–66Google Scholar; and The Open Society and Its Enemies, vol. 2 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1970), pp. 237–39, 261–64, 268–69, and 363–64Google Scholar.
53. See Schumpeter's, essay entitled “The March to Socialism,” in Schumpeter, Joseph A., Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (London: Allen & Unwin, 1949), pp. 421–24Google Scholar. See also von Hayek, Friedrich, The Road to Serfdom (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956)Google Scholar.
54. See H. Schmiegelow, “Global Dimensions in US-Japan Relations”; and M. Schmiegelow, “Puissance et interdépendence.”
55. See “External Assets to Top $1 Trillion: Nation Needs Program to Fuel World Economy,” Japan Economic Journal, 24 January 1987, pp. 1 and 10; and Tomizawa, Hideki, “Japan's Marshall Plan Needs Work,” International Herald Tribune, 20 11 1987, p. 6Google Scholar.
56. See Popper, Karl, Conjectures and Refutations: The Growth of Scientific Knowledge (New York: Basic Books, 1962)Google Scholar.
57. See Huntington, Samuel, “The Change to Change: Modernization, Development and Politics,” Comparative Politics 3 (Fall 1971), pp. 238–322CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Elster, Jon, Explaining Technical Change: A Case Study in the Philosophy of Sciences (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983), pp. 49–68Google Scholar.
58. For a discussion of functional explanations as opposed to causal and intentional ones, see Merton, Robert K., Social Theory and Social Structure (Glencoe, III.: Free Press, 1957), p. 30Google Scholar; and Elster, , Explaining Technical Change, pp. 57 and 242, fn 19Google Scholar.
59. See the following works by Parsons, Talcott: The Social System (New York: Free Press, 1951), pp. 26–36Google Scholar; Societies: Evolutionary and Comparative Perspectives (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1966), pp. 5–29Google Scholar; and The System of Modern Societies (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1971), p. 6Google Scholar.
60. For a criticism of holism in solving political and technological problems from the neoliberal point of view, see Haas, Ernst B., “Is There a Hole in the Whole? Knowledge, Technology, Interdependence, and the Construction of International Regimes,” International Organization 29 (Summer 1978), pp. 851–52Google Scholar.
61. See White, Morton, Pragmatism and the American Mind: Essays and Reviews in Philosophy and Intellectual History (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1973)Google Scholar.
62. Fora discussion about Ihe difference between aggregate and individual (or “subjective”) methodology which is at the center of the debate between economists of the classical and Keynesian traditions, see von Hayek, Friedrich, Individualism and Economic Order (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948), pp. 92–118Google Scholar; Kirzner, Israel, “The ‘Austrian’ Perspective,” in Bell, and Kristoll, , The Crisis in Economic Theory, pp. 115–21Google Scholar; and Machlup, Fritz, “Schumpeter's Economic Methodology,” in Harris, S. E., ed., Schumpeter, Social Scientist (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1951), p. 100Google Scholar.
63. For Popper, piecemeal engineering is the only possible prescription for practical policy of any kind, given the fallibility of human knowledge. See Popper, Karl, The Logic of Scientific Discovery (New York: Harper Torchbooks, 1965), p. 57Google Scholar.
64. For a more detailed discussion, see , M. and Schmiegelow, H., Strategic Pragmatism, p. 12Google Scholar.
65. Ibid., pp. 41–153.
66. For a discussion of the Asian model, see ibid.; Schmiegelow, Michèle, “The Asian Newly Industrialized Economies: A Universal Model of Action,” paper presented at the Université Libre de Bruxelles, Postgraduate Program in International Policy, 17 03 1989Google Scholar; and Hillebrand, Wolfgang, Industrielle und technologische Anschlussstrategien in teilindustrialisierten Laendern: Bewertung der allokationstheoretischen Kontroverse und Schlussfolgerungen aus der Fallstudie Suedkorea (Industrial and technological catching-up strategies in semi-industrialized countries: Evaluation of the allocation theory controversy and conclusions from the case of South Korea) (Berlin: Deutsches Institut fuer Entwicklungspolitik, 1989)Google Scholar. Regarding the influence of the model on Latin American policymakers, see Fishlow, Albert, “The State of Latin American Economies,” in Inter-American Development Bank (IDB), External Debt: Crisis and Adjustment—Economic and Social Progress in Latin America (Washington, D.C.: IDB, 1985), pp. 123–48Google Scholar; and Esser, Klaus, “Lateinamerika in der Krise: Neostrukturalismus als wirtschaftspolitische Reaktion” (Latin America in crisis: Neostructuralism as an economic policy response), Vierteljah'resberichte, no. 107, 03 1987, pp. 5–17Google Scholar.
67. See Schmiegelow, Henrik, “The Mexican Debt Agreement: A Model for Solving the International Debt Problem?” Aussenpolitik 41 (Summer 1990), pp. 291–96Google Scholar.
68. See the following works of Schmiegelow, Henrik and Schmiegelow, Michèle: “Deng's Modernization and the Development Experience of the ROC: Two Cases of the Same Theory?” in Chang, King-yuh, Ideology and Politics in Twentieth-Century China (Taipei: Institute of International Relations, 1988), pp. 150–73Google Scholar; and “Eléments corporatistes des regents concepts de reTorme de l'entreprise publique en Chine” (Corporatist elements in recent reform concepts for public enterprises in China), paper presented at the Centre de Recherche et de Documentation sur la Chine Contemporaine, Paris, 7–8 06 1989Google Scholar.
69. Schmiegelow, H., “Global Dimensions in US-Japan Relations,” p. 238Google Scholar.
70. For a discussion about Czechoslovakia's first reformist finance minister, Vaçlav Klaus, and his role as a protagonist of Austrian economic theory, see Will, George, “Gorbachev's Materialism May Lead to His Undoing,” International Herald Tribune, 16 02 1990, p. 7Google Scholar. Regarding Vice-Prime Minister Valtr Komarek's advocacy of a significant residual role for the state, see de Jonquières, Guy, “Prague Split over the Pace of Economic Reforms,” Financial Times, 16 02 1990, p. 2Google Scholar.
71. Waltz, , Theory of International Politics, p. 344Google Scholar.
72. For a discussion of these methodological problems, see , M. and Schmiegelow, H., Strategic Pragmatism, pp. 11 and 25Google Scholar; Hayek, , Individualism and Economic Order, pp. 92–118Google Scholar; Kirzner, , ”The ‘Austrian’ Perspective,” pp. 115–21Google Scholar; and Machlup, , “Schumpeter's Economic Methodology,” p. 100Google Scholar.
73. See M. and H. Schmiegelow, Strategic Pragmatism; and M. Schmiegelow, “Cutting Across Doctrines.”
74. See Schmiegelow, H., “Global Dimensions in US-Japan Relations,” pp. 225, 231, and 235Google Scholar. For a more recent discussion of Japan's growing leverage in international economic policy coordination, see Calder, , “Japanese Foreign Economic Policy Formation”; and Funabashi, Yoichi, Managing the Dollar: From the Plaza to the Louvre (Washington, D.C.: Institute of International Economics, 1988)Google Scholar.
75. Schmiegelow, M., “Puissance et interddpendance,” p. 568Google Scholar.
76. See Popper's, groundbreaking early work, Logik der Forschung (The logic of scientific discovery) (Vienna: Springer-Verlag, 1934)Google Scholar, and his 1962 collection of essays, Conjectures and Refutations. See also Kuhn, Thomas, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962)Google Scholar.
77. See Meyerson, Adam, “Adam Smith's Welfare State,” Policy Review, no. 50, Fall 1989Google Scholar; and Kuttner's, Robert reaction, “When Heritage Gets Wet, Ideological Detente Can't Be Far Off,” International Herald Tribune, 27 10 1989, p. 6Google Scholar. See also Kuttner, Robert, “Dividends of Detente: For a New Politics,” International Herald Tribune, 5 12 1989, p. 6Google Scholar; and Volcker, Paul, “American Leadership: The Price Looks Bearable,” International Herald Tribune, 20 12 1989, p. 6Google Scholar.
78. Kindleberger, Charles, “Government and International Trade,” Princeton Essays in International Finance, no. 129, 07 1978Google Scholar.
- 7
- Cited by