Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T15:36:59.507Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Effectiveness of Monetary Policy Anchors: Firm-Level Evidence

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 October 2010

J. Lawrence Broz
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego. E-mail: [email protected]
Michael Plouffe
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego. E-mail: [email protected]
Get access

Abstract

Analyses of monetary policy posit that exchange-rate pegs, inflation targets, and central bank independence can help anchor private-sector inflation expectations. Yet there are few direct tests of this argument. We offer cross-national, micro-level evidence on the effectiveness of monetary anchors in controlling private-sector inflation concerns. Using firm-level data from eighty-one countries (approximately 10,000 firms), we find evidence that “international” anchors (exchange-rate commitments) correlate significantly with a substantial reduction in private-sector concerns about inflation while “domestic” anchors (inflation targeting and central bank independence) do not. Our conjecture is that private-sector inflation expectations are more responsive to exchange-rate anchors because they are more transparent, more constraining, and more costly than domestic anchoring arrangements.

Type
Research Note
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Alesina, Alberto, and Summers, Lawrence H.. 1993. Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic Performance: Some Comparative Evidence. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 25 (2):151–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ammer, John, and Freeman, Richard T.. 1995. Inflation Targeting in the 1990s: The Experiences of New Zealand, Canada, and the United Kingdom. Journal of Economics and Business 47 (2):165–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkenson, Andrew, and Kehoe, Patrick J.. 2001. The Advantage of Transparent Instruments of Monetary Policy. NBER Working Paper No. 8681. Cambridge, Mass: National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, Laurence, and Sheridan, Niamh. 2005. Does Inflation Targeting Matter? In The Inflation-Targeting Debate, edited by Bernanke, Ben S. and Woodford, Michael, 249–82. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Banaian, King, Burdekin, R.C.K., and Willett, Thomas D.. 1995. On the Political Economy of Central Bank Independence. In Monetarism and the Methodology of Economics: Essays in Honor of Thomas Mayer, edited by Hoover, Kevin D. and Sheffri, Steven M., 178–97. Brookfield, Vt.: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert J., and Gordon, David B.. 1983. A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model. Journal of Political Economy 91 (4):589610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S., and Mishkin, Frederic S.. 1997. Inflation Targeting: A New Framework for Monetary Policy? Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (2):97116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernhard, William. 2002. Exchange Rate Stability and Political Accountability in the European Monetary System. European Union Center Working Paper 1 (1). Urbana: University of Illinois.Google Scholar
Bernhard, William, Broz, J. Lawrence, and Clark, William Roberts. 2002. The Political Economy of Monetary Institutions. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Broz, J. Lawrence. 2002. Political System Transparency and Monetary Commitment Regimes. International Organization 56 (4):861–87.Google Scholar
Broz, J. Lawrence, Frieden, Jeffry, and Weymouth, Stephen. 2008. Exchange Rate Policy Attitudes: Direct Evidence from Survey Data. IMF Staff Papers 55 (3):417–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, Guillermo A., and Végh, Carlos. 1999. Inflation Stabilization and BOP Crises in Developing Countries. In Handbook of Macroeconomics, 1C, edited by Taylor, John B. and Woodford, Michael, 1531–614. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Canavan, Chris, and Tommasi, Mariano. 1997. On the Credibility of Alternative Exchange-Rate Regimes. Journal of Developmental Economics 54 (1):101–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cecchetti, Stephen G., and Ehrmann, Michael. 2002. Does Inflation Targeting Increase Output Volatility? An International Comparison of Policymakers' Preferences and Outcomes. In Monetary Policy: Rules and Transmission Mechanisms, edited by Loayza, Norman and Schmidt-Hebbel, Klaus, 247–74. Santiago: Central Bank of Chile.Google Scholar
Cooper, Richard. 1971. Currency Devaluation in Developing Countries. Princeton Essays in International Finance No. 86. Princeton, N.J.: International Finance Section, Princeton University.Google Scholar
Crowe, Christopher. 2006. Testing the Transparency Benefits of Inflation Targeting: Evidence from Private Sector Forecasts. Working Paper 06/289. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crowe, Christopher, and Meade, Ellen E.. 2007. The Evolution of Central Bank Governance around the World. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (4):6990.Google Scholar
Cukierman, Alex. 1992. Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and Independence: Theory and Evidence. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Cukierman, Alex, Webb, Steven B., and Neyapti, Bilin. 1992. Measuring the Independence of Central Banks and Its Effect on Policy Outcomes. World Bank Economic Review 6 (3):353–98.Google Scholar
de Haan, Jakob, and Kooi, Willem. 2000. Does Central Bank Independence Really Matter? New Evidence for Developing Countries Using a New Indicator. Journal of Banking and Finance 24 (4):643–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flood, Robert, and Isard, Peter. 1989. Monetary Policy Strategies. IMF Staff Papers 36 (3):612–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forder, James. 2000. Central Bank Independence and Credibility: Is There a Shred of Evidence? International Finance 3 (1):167–85.Google Scholar
Frankel, Jeffrey A. 1999. No Single Currency Regime Is Right for All Countries or at All Times. Princeton Essays in International Finance No. 215. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghosh, Atish R., Gulde, Anne-Marie, and Wolf, Holger C.. 2002. Exchange Rate Regimes, Choices and Consequences. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Giavazzi, Francesco, and Pagano, Marco. 1988. The Advantage of Tying One's Hands: EMS Discipline and Central Bank Credibility. European Economic Review 32 (5):1055–75.Google Scholar
Gürkaynak, Refet S., Levin, Andrew T., and Swanson, Eric T.. 2006. Does Inflation Targeting Anchor Long-Run Inflation Expectations? Evidence from Long-Term Bond Yields in the U.S., U.K., and Sweden. Working Paper No. 2006-09. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keefer, Philip, and Stasavage, David. 2003. The Limits of Delegation: Veto Players, Central Bank Independence, and the Credibility of Monetary Policy. American Political Science Review 97 (3):407–23.Google Scholar
Levin, Andrew T., Natalucci, Fabio M., and Piger, Jeremy M.. 2004. The Macroeconomic Effects of Inflation Targeting. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 86 (4):5180.Google Scholar
Levy-Yeyati, Eduardo, and Sturzenegger, Federico. 2005. Classifying Exchange Rate Regimes: Deeds vs. Words. European Economic Review 49 (6):1603–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne. 1992. Optimal Commitment in Monetary Policy: Credibility Versus Flexibility. American Economic Review 82 (1):273–86.Google Scholar
Mahadeva, Lavan, and Sterne, Gabriel. 2000. Monetary Frameworks in a Global Context. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. Gregory, Reis, Ricardo, and Wolfers, Justin. 2003. Disagreement About Inflation Expectations. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 18:209–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCallum, Bennett T. 1995. Two Fallacies Concerning Central-Bank Independence. American Economic Review 85 (2):207–11.Google Scholar
Mishkin, Frederic S. 1999. International Experiences with Different Monetary Policy Regimes. Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (3):579605.Google Scholar
Mishkin, Frederic S. 2004. Can Inflation Targeting Work in Emerging Market Countries? NBER Working Paper No. 10646. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mishkin, Frederic S., and Posen, Adam S.. 1997. “Inflation Targeting: Lessons from Four Countries.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 3(3): 9110.Google Scholar
Mishkin, Frederic S., and Schmidt-Hebbel, Klaus. 2002. One Decade of Inflation Targeting in the World: What Do We Know and What Do We Need to Know? In Inflation Targeting: Design, Performance, Challenges, edited by Loayza, Norman V. and Soto, Raimundo, 171219. Santiago: Central Bank of Chile.Google Scholar
Mishkin, Frederic S., and Schmidt-Hebbel, Klaus. 2007. Does Inflation Targeting Make a Difference? NBER Working Paper No. 12876. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Polillo, Simone, and Guillén, Mauro F.. 2005. Globalization Pressures and the State: The Global Spread of Central Bank Independence. American Journal of Sociology 110 (6):1764–802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reinhart, Carmen M., and Rogoff, Kenneth S.. 2004. The Modern History of Exchange Rate Arrangements: A Reinterpretation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (1):148.Google Scholar
Rogoff, Kenneth. 1985. The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100 (4):1169–90.Google Scholar
Tavlas, George, Dellas, Harris, and Stockman, Alan C.. 2008. The Classification and Performance of Alternative Exchange-Rate Systems. European Economic Review 52 (6):941–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tomz, Michael, Wittenberg, Jason, and King, Gary. 1998. CLARIFY: Software for Interpreting and Presenting Statistical Results. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University.Google Scholar
Walsh, Carl E. 1995. Optimal Contracts for Central Bankers. American Economic Review 85 (1):150–67.Google Scholar