Article contents
Conclusion: an institutional approach to American foreign economic policy
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 22 May 2009
Extract
It may well be that Poincaré's observation is correct, that natural scientists discuss their results and social scientists their methods. if so, it is because our guides to social reality are so frail. Approaches to political investigation are difficult to separate from the substantive puzzles that drive inquiry and the results that follow. In collective enterprises, such as this volume, the problem of approach or method becomes all the more central. We are left with no choice but to reflect on the tools that we use as well as the social reality that they promise to reveal.
- Type
- Research Article
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © The IO Foundation 1988
References
I gratefully acknowledge the comments and suggestions of David Lake and Michael Mastanduno as well as the other authors in this volume. I have also received helpful comments from David Bachman, Peter Hall, Stephen Krasner, Charles Kupchan, Ken Oye, Theda Skocpol, and participants in the conference on The American State in the International Political Economy, sponsored by the Program on Interdependent Political Economy, University of Chicago, 29 April 1987.
1. Katzenstein, Peter J., “International Relations and Domestic Structures: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States,” International Organization 30 (Winter 1976), pp. 1–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Katzenstein, , “Introduction” and “ Conclusion: Domestic Structures and Strategies of Foreign Economic Policy,” in Katzenstein, , ed., Between Power and Plenty (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1978).Google Scholar
2. This point is my own judgment. My characterization of the volume should not suggest that the contributors have reached an explicit consensus.
3. March, James G. and Olsen, Johan P., “The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life,” American Political Science Review 78 (09 1984), p. 735.Google Scholar
4. Huntington makes a similar distinction between social forces and political institutions or organizations. “A social force is an ethnic, religious, territorial, economic or status group … A political organization or procedure, on the other hand, is an arrangement for maintaining order, resolving disputes, selecting authoritative leaders, and thus promoting community among two or more social forces.” Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1968), pp. 8–9.Google Scholar
5. Hall, Peter, Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France (New York: Oxford University Press, 1986), p. 233.Google Scholar
6. Stephen Lukes provides a helpful discussion of “structural” constraints. See “Power and Structure,” in Lukes, , Essays in Social Theory (New York: Columbia University Press, 1977), pp. 12–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
7. Stephen, Krasner, “Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical Dynamics,” Comparative Politics 16 (01 1984), p. 234.Google Scholar
8. A large literature in organizational theory explores this point. See discussion in Huntington, , Political Order in Changing Societies, pp. 15–17Google Scholar. See also Wilson, James Q., Political Organizations (New York: Basic Books, 1973)Google Scholar; Kaufman, Herbert, The Limits of Organizational Change (University, Ala.: University of Alabama Press, 1971).Google Scholar
9. See Skowronek, Steven, Building a New American State: The Expansion of National Administrative Capacities (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1982).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
10. Krasner, , “Approaches to the State,” p. 235.Google Scholar
11. Stinchcombe, Arthur L., “Social Structure and Organizations,” in March, James G., ed., Handbook of Organizations (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1965), p. 148.Google Scholar
12. For a general discussion of the logic of developmental explanation, see Almond, Gabriel A., “Approaches to Developmental Causation,” in Almond, , Flanagan, Scott G., and Mundt, Robert J., eds., Crisis, Choice, and Change: Historical Studies of Political Development (Boston: Little, Brown, 1973), pp. 1–42Google Scholar. The role of domestic political crisis and discontinuous policy change is emphasized in a new study of postwar Japanese politics. See Calder, Kent E., Crisis and Compensation: Policy and Stability in Changing Postwar Japan (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1988).Google Scholar
13. Lasswell, H. D., “Attention Structure and Social Structure,” in Lyman, Bryson, ed., The Communication of Ideas (New York: Harper, 1948), p. 262Google Scholar. The importance of the instrumental use of crisis was aptly expressed by Carl, Schmitt: “Sovereign is he who decides the emergency situation.“Google Scholar Cited by Neumann, Franz in “Approaches to the Study of Political Power,” Political Science Quarterly 65 (06 1950), p. 178CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Albert Hirschman brought these references to my attention.
14. Gilpin, Robert, War and Change in World Politics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1981), p. 186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
15. Krasner, , “Regimes and the Limits of Realism: Regimes as Autonomous Variables,” in Krasner, , ed., International Regimes (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1983), pp. 359–61.Google Scholar
16. The theoretical enterprise within an institutional approach remains untidy. Yet this does not mean that large-scale theoretical generalizations are not possible. See Hall, John A., Powers and Liberties: The Causes and Consequences of the Rise of the West (New York: Penguin, 1986), p. 22Google Scholar. In many respects, the institutional perspective discussed here is congenial with the broader field of historical sociology. See Skocpol, Theda, “Emerging Agendas and Recurrent Strategies in Historical Sociology,” in Skocpol, , ed., Vision and Method in Historical Sociology (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1984), pp. 356–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
17. March, and Olsen, , “The New Institutionalism.”Google Scholar
18. Ikenberry, , Reasons of State: The Oil Shocks of the 1970s and the Capacities of American Government (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1988).Google Scholar
19. On the ratification procedures, see Destler, I.M., Making Foreign Economic Policy (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1980), pp. 170–78Google Scholar. On their implementation, see Destler, I.M. and Graham, Thomas, “United States and the Tokyo Round: Lessons of a Success Story,“ The World Economy 3 (06 1980), pp. 53–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Destler, ,.”Trade Consensus-SALT Stalemate: Congress and Foreign Policy in the Seventies,” in Thomas, Mann and Ornstein, Norman J., eds., The New Congress (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1981), pp. 319–59Google Scholar; and Robert, Cassidy, “Negotiating about Negotiations,” in Franck, Thomas M., ed., The Tethered Presidency (New York: New York University Press, 1981), pp. 264–82.Google Scholar
20. Baldwin, Robert E., The Political Economy of U.S. Import Policy (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1985), pp. 177–78.Google Scholar
21. Katzenstein, , “Conclusion.”Google Scholar
22. John, Zysman, Government, Markets, and Growth: Financial Systems and the Politics of Industrial Change (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1983), p. 300.Google Scholar
23. Robert, Pastor, Congress and the Politics of U.S. Foreign Economic Policy, 1929–1976 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1980)Google Scholar; Destler, , Making Foreign Economic Policy.Google Scholar
24. Andrew, Shonfield, Modern Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power (New York: Oxford University Press, 1965), p. 298.Google Scholar
25. An extensive literature discusses this episode. The most complete analysis is Anderson, Irvine H., ARAMCO, the United States and Saudi Arabia: A Study of the Dynamics of Foreign Oil Policy, 1933–1950 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1981), pp. 42–56Google Scholar. See also Stoff, Michael B., Oil, War, and American Security: The Search for a National Policy on Foreign Oil, 1941–1947 (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1980), pp. 84–86Google Scholar; and Miller, David Aaron, Search for Security: Saudi Arabian Oil and American Foreign Policy (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1980), pp. 81–82.Google Scholar
26. Charles, Tilly, ed., The Formation of National States in Western Europe (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1975)Google Scholar; Poggi, Gianfranco, The Development of the Modern State (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1978)Google Scholar; Bendix, Reinhard, Kings and People: Power and the Mandate to Rule (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1978)Google Scholar; Mann, Micahel, “The Autonomous Power of the State: Its Origins, Mechanisms and Results,” Archives Européenes de Sociologie 25 (1984), pp. 185–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
27. The relationship between war and state-building is an issue of ongoing research. See Tilly, Charles, “Reflections on the History of European State-Making,” in Tilly, , ed., The Formation of National States in Western EuropeGoogle Scholar; and Tilly, , “War Making and State Making as Organized Crime,” in Evans, Peter B., Dietrich, Rueschemeyer, and Theda, Skocpol, eds., Bringing the State Back In (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985)Google Scholar. Michael Mann, in the reconstruction of English state finance, demonstrates that the major expenditure of the British state was on warfare, and that war or the investment in war-related capacities prompted major expansions in levels of expenditure. Michael, Mann, “State and Society, 1130–1815: An Analysis of English State Finances,” in Maurice, Zeitlin, ed., Political Power and Social Theory, vol. 1 (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, 1980)Google Scholar. Similar conclusions, explored comparatively, are reached by Rasler, Karen A. and Thompson, William R., “War Making and State Making: Governmental Expenditures, Tax Revenues, and Global Wars,” American Political Science Review 79 (06 1985), pp. 491–507CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Art, Stein, The Nation at War (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1980).Google Scholar
28. Skowronek, , Building a New American State (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1982)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hollingsworth, J. Roger, “The United States,” in Raymond, Grew, ed., Crises of Political Development in Europe and the United States (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1978).Google Scholar
29. Weber noted the importance of basic historical differences between the United States and Germany, including international position, for political development. “Destiny,” Weber argues, has encumbered Germany “with a dense population and an intensive culture, which has forced us to maintain the splendor of our old culture, so to speak, in an armed camp within a world bristling with arms … The United States does not yet know such problems. This nation will probably never encounter some of them. It has no old aristocracy; hence the tensions caused by the contrast between authoritarian tradition and the purely commercial character of modern economic conditions do not exist. Rightly it celebrates the purchase of this immense territory … without this acquisition, with powerful and warlike neighbors at its side, it would be forced to wear the coat of mail like ourselves, who constantly keep in the drawer of our desks the march order in case of war.“ Weber, “Capitalism and Rural Society in Germany,” in Gerth, H. H. and Mills, C. Wright, eds., From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology (New York: Oxford University Press, 1946), pp. 384–85Google Scholar. The importance of the state's geopolitical position in political development is stressed by Otto Hintze. See Felix, Gilbert, ed., The Historical Essays of Otto Hintze (New York: Oxford University Press, 1975)Google Scholar; and Hintze, “The State in Historical Perspective,” in Reinhard, Bendix, ed., State and Society: A Reader in Comparative Historical Sociology (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973), pp. 154–69.Google Scholar
30. Alexander, Gerschenkron, “Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective,” in Gerschenkron, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: A Book of Essays (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1962), pp. 5–30Google Scholar. The argument has been developed further by Kurth, James R., “The Political Consequences of the Product Cycle: Industrial History and Political Outcomes,” International Organization 33 (Winter 1979), pp. 1–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Kurth, , “Industrial Change and Political Change: A European Perspective,” in David, Collier, ed., The New Authoritarianism of Latin America (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1979)Google Scholar. A discussion of this theme in terms of the U.S. case is presented by Chandler, Alfred D. Jr., “Government versus Business: An American Phenomenon,” in Dunlop, John T., ed., Business and Public Policy (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980)Google Scholar; Chandler, , The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1978)Google Scholar; and Chandler, , “The Coming of Big Business,” in Woodward, C. Vann, ed., The Comparative Approach to American History (New York: Basic Books, 1968), pp. 220–35Google Scholar. David, Vogel, “Why Businessmen Distrust Their State: The Political Consciousness of American Corporate Executives,” British Journal of Political Science 8 (01 1978), pp. 45–78Google Scholar. See also Andrew, Shonfield, Modern Capitalism, pp. 298–329.Google Scholar
31. World War I did have some institutional repercussions. In the area of labor relations, see Julie, Strickland, “War, the State, and Labor: The Case of the United States, 1917–1935,” paper prepared for delivery at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association,28–31 August 1986,Washington, D.C.Google Scholar
32. For a discussion of wartime mobilization, see Dahl, Robert A. and Lindblom, Charles E., Politics, Economics, and Welfare (New York: Harper & Bros., 1953), pp. 402–12.Google Scholar
33. See Pletcher, David M., “1861–1898: Economic Growth and Diplomatic Adjustment,” in Becker, William H. and Wells, Samuel F. Jr., eds., Economics and World Power: An Assessment of American Diplomacy Since 1789 (New York: Columbia University Press, 1985).Google Scholar
34. Lake, David, “The State and American Trade Strategy in the Pre-Hegemonic Era.”Google Scholar
35. Haggard, , “The Institutional Foundations of Hegemony: Explaining the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934,“ p. 93Google Scholar; Goldstein, , “Ideas, Institutions, and American Trade Policy”Google Scholar; Pastor, , Congress and the Politics of U.S. Foreign Economic Policy, 1929–1976Google Scholar; Destler, I. M., American Trade Politics: System Under Stress (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1986).Google Scholar
36. Haggard, , “The Institutional Foundations of Hegemony,” p. 12Google Scholar. See also Lake, David A., Power, Protection, and Free Trade: International Sources of U.S. Commercial Strategy, 1887–1939 (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1988), chap. 6.Google Scholar
37. There is a growing literature on this relationship. Overviews of it can be found in Gourevitch, Peter, “The Second Image Reversed,” International Organization 32 (Autumn 1978), pp. 881–912CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Almond, Gabriel A., “Roundtable on Internal vs. External Factors in Political Development,” paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association,New Orleans,31 August 1985.Google Scholar
38. This issue is disputed. The new economic history strongly argues that the income tax was adopted because of the economic needs to reduce tariffs. See Baack, Ben and Ray, Edward John, “The Political Economy of the Origins and Development of the Federal Income Tax,” Research in Economic History, supplement 4 (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, 1985), pp. 121–38Google Scholar. On the post-Civil War role of tarrifs in raising revenue, see Condliffe, J. B., The Commerce of Nations (New York: Norton, 1950), pp. 229–30.Google Scholar
39. Hirschman notes the importance of crisis as an inducement for institutional change in his studies of economic policymaking in Latin America. Economic or political crisis may serve to concentrate attention on problems. That is, change may fail in “ordinary times” not for ”lack of knowledge, nor even for lack of motivation, but simply for lack of attention.” “Experience also shows that crisis may make it possible to take required actions against powerful groups that are normally well entrenched and invulnerable; finally, crisis may stimulate action and hence learning on a problem on which insight has been low and which for that very reason has not been tackled as long as it was in a quiescent state.” Hirschman, Albert O., Journeys Toward Progress: Studies of Economic Policy-Making in Latin America (New York: The Twentieth Century Fund, 1963), pp. 260–61.Google Scholar
40. See Lake, , Power, Protection, and Free Trade, chaps. 5 and 6Google Scholar. See also Lake, David A., ‘Export, Die, or Subsidize: The International Political-Economy of American Agriculture, 1885–1939,” presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association,28–31 August 1986,Washington, D.C.Google Scholar
41. Schattschneider, E. E., Politics, Pressures and the Tariff (Hamden, Conn.: Archon, 1963), p. 284.Google Scholar
42. See Goldstein, Judith, “The Political Economy of Trade: Institutions of Protection,” The American Political Science Review 80 (03 1986).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
43. Schumann, Franz, The Logic of World Power (New York: Pantheon, 1974), pp. 8, 21–22.Google Scholar
44. See Lake, , Power, Protection, and Free TradeGoogle Scholar. To the extent that a rational choice perspective can explain the outcomes, the salience of this point would diminish. Krasner, Stephen D., “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics 28 (04 1976), pp. 317–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
45. Goldstein presents a variant of this argument.
46. See Posen, Barry, The Sources of Military Doctrine (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1985)Google Scholar. On the way institutions influence the perceptions of their incumbents, see Douglas, Mary, How Institutions Think (Syracuse, N.Y.: Syracuse University Press, 1986), especially pp. 91–109.Google Scholar
47. The issue-area approach does not have much to say about international-centered theory. To the extent that state elites dominate policy and act in terms of systemic constraints and opportunities, however, the international explanations also become relevant.
48. Lowi, Theodore J., “American Business, Public Policy, Case-Studies, and Political Theory,” World Politics 16 (07 1964), pp. 677–715CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See later refinements and extensions by Wilson, , Political Organizations, chap. 16Google Scholar; William, Zimmerman, “Issue Area and Foreign-Policy Process: A Research Note in Search of a General Theory,” The American Political Science Review 67 (12 1973), pp. 1204–12.Google Scholar
49. Krasner, Stephen D., “United States Commercial and Monetary Policy: Unravelling the Paradox of External Strength and Internal Weakness,” in Katzenstein, , ed., Between Power and Plenty, p. 66.Google Scholar
50. Gowa, , “Public Goods and Political Institutions,” p. 27.Google Scholar
51. Ibid., p. 22.
52. Kym, Anderson and Baldwin, Robert E., “The Political Market for Protection in Industrial Countries: Empirical Evidence,” World Bank Staff Working Papers, 1981Google Scholar; Hughes, Helen and Waelbroeck, Jean, “Foreign Trade and Structural Adjustment—Is There a Threat of New Protectionism?” in Hans-Gert, Braun et al. , eds., The European Economy in the 1980s (Aldershot, Eng.: Gower, 1983)Google Scholar. For an overview, see Douglas, Nelson, “Endogenous Tariff Theory: A Critical Survey,” unpublished paper, World Bank.Google Scholar
53. Hughes, and Waelbroeck, , “Foreign Trade and Structural Adjustment,” p. 17.Google Scholar
54. On the cognitive definition of issue-areas, see Keohane, Robert O. and Nye, Joseph S., Power and Interdependence: World Politics in Transition (Boston: Little, Brown, 1977), pp. 64–65.Google Scholar
55. Mastanduno, , “Trade as a Strategic Weapon,” this volume, p. 124.Google Scholar
56. Ikenberry, , “Market Solutions for State Problems.”Google Scholar
57. Gilbert, Winham, International Trade and the Tokyo Round (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1986)Google Scholar, chap. 8; John, Ikenberry, “Manufacturing Consensus: The Institutionalization of American Private Interests in the Tokyo Round,” Princeton University, 1986Google Scholar. See also Twiggs, Joan E., The Tokyo Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations: A Case Study in Building Domestic Support for Diplomacy (New York: University Press of America, 1987).Google Scholar
58. Wilson, Graham K., “Why Is There No Corporatism in the United States.” in Gerhard, Lehmbruch and Schmitter, Philippe C., eds., Patterns of Corporatist Policy-Making (Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1982), p. 225.Google Scholar
59. See note 19.
60. Hoffmann, , “Domestic Politics and Interdependence,” in Hoffman, Janus and Minerva: Essays in the Theory and Practice of International Politics (Boulder: Westview Press, 1987), p. 274Google Scholar. First published in Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, From Marshall Plan to Global Interdependence (Paris: OECD, 1978).Google Scholar
61. See the discussion of agenda setting in Kingdon, John W., Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies (Boston: Little, Brown, 1984).Google Scholar
62. Gowa, , “Public Goods and Political Institutions: Trade and Monetary Policy Processes in the United States,” in this volume.Google Scholar
63. Weber, , Economy and Society, edited by Guenther, Roth and Claus, Wittich, vol. 1 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1978), p. 19.Google Scholar
64. Mills, , “The Uses of History,” in The Sociological Imagination (New York: Oxford University Press, 1959), p. 149.Google Scholar
65. John, Odell, U.S. International Monetary Policy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1982).Google Scholar
66. Joanne, Gowa, “Anarchy, Egoism, and Third Images: The Evolution of Cooperation and International Relations,” International Organization 40 (Winter 1986), pp. 167–86Google Scholar; Stephan, Haggard and Beth, Simmons, “Theories of International Regimes,” International Organization 41 (Summer 1987)Google Scholar; Putnam, Robert D., “The Logic of Two-Level Games: International Cooperation, Domestic Politics, and Western Summitry, 1975–1986,” paper delivered at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association,28–31 August 1986,Washington, D.C.Google Scholar; Douglas, Nelson, “The State as a Conceptual Variable: Another Look,” World Bank, unpublished paper.Google Scholar
67. Haggard, and Simmons, , “Theories of International Regimes.”Google Scholar
68. Charles Lipson stresses the importance of the evolving domestic position of the state relative to the international standards and practices of protection of foreign capital. Standing Guard: Protecting Foreign Capital in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985), especially pp. 19–26.Google Scholar
- 90
- Cited by