Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T17:35:17.490Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Politics of Speculative Attacks in Industrial Democracies

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 July 2003

Get access

Abstract

Recent models of speculative currency crises contend that market expectations of policy behavior can trigger a speculative attack. We argue that political processes and partisan objectives inform expectations about the government's commitment to the exchange rate. First, market actors anticipate periods when the partisan identity of a government may change through an election or a cabinet collapse. Second, party labels provide information to currency traders about the policy objectives of a potential government. Consequently, we contend that the probability of a speculative attack will be higher when markets expect the cabinet to end and when the cabinet dissolution is likely to produce a leftward shift in policy. A discrete timesurvival model is used to estimate the probability that a cabinet will dissolve in any given month for sixteen parliamentary democracies from 1970 to 1995. The predicted values are then used as a proxy for market expectations in a model of speculative currency crises.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 2000

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alesina, Alberto. 1989. Politics and Business Cycles in Industrial Democracies. Economic Policy 8 (spring): 5798.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Sachs, Jeffrey. 1988. Political Parties and the Business Cycle in the United States: 1948–1984. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 20 (1):6382.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Summers, Lawrence. 1993. Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic Performance: Some Comparative Evidence. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 25 (2):151–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, Grilli, Vittorio, and Milesi-Ferretti, Gian-Maria. 1994. The Political Economy of Capital Controls. In Capital Mobility: The Impact on Consumption, Investment, and Growth, edited by Leiderman, Leonardo and Razin, Assaf, 289321. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Roubini, Nouriel, with Cohen, Gerald D.. 1997. Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aliber, Robert Z. 1973. The Interest Rate Parity Theorem: A Reinterpretation. Journal of Political Economy 81 (6):1451–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allison, Paul D. 1984. Event History Analysis: Regression for Longitudinal Event Data. Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alt, James E., and King, Gary. 1994. Transfers of Governmental Power: The Meaning of Time Dependence. Comparative Political Studies 27 (2): 190210.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel. 1997. Modeling Space and Time: The Event History Approach. Unpublished manuscript, Department of Political Science, University of California, San Diego.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, Katz, Jonathan, and Tucker, Richard. 1998. Taking Time Seriously: Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable in Binary Time-Series-Cross-Section Models. American Journal of Political Science 42 (4): 1260–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernhard, William, and Leblang, David. 1998. Political Uncertainty and Exchange Rate Volatility in Parliamentary Democracies. Paper presented at the Annual Meetings of the Midwest Political Science Association, April.Google Scholar
Blomberg, S. Brock, and Hess, Gregory. 1997. Politics and Exchange Rate Forecasts. Journal of International Economics 43(1–2):189205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, Guillermo A. 1995. Varieties of Capital-Market Crises. Center for International Economics Working Paper 15. College Park: University of Maryland.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, Sara, and Reinhart, Carmen M.. 1996. Capital Flows to Latin America: Is There Evidence of Contagion Effects? In Private Capital Flows to Emerging Markets After the Mexican Crisis, edited by Calvo, Guillermo A., Goldstein, Morris, and Hochreiter, Eduard, 151–71. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Cameron, David R. 1984. Social Democracy, Corporatism, Labour Quiescence, and the Representation of Economic Interest in Advanced Capitalist Society. In Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism, edited by Goldthorpe, John H., 143–78. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Cobham, David, ed. 1994. European Monetary Upheavals. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Cukierman, Alex, Webb, Steven B., and Neyapti, Bilin. 1992. Measuring the Independence of Central Banks and Its Effect on Policy Outcomes. World Bank Economic Review 6 (3):353–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Dougals W., and Dybvig, Philip H.. 1983. Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91 (3):401–19.Google Scholar
Dornbusch, Rudiger, Goldfajn, Ilan, and Valdes, Rodrigo. 1995. Currency Crises and Collapses. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2:219–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry, Rose, Andrew K., and Wyplosz, Charles. 1995. Exchange Market Mayhem: The Antecedents and Aftermath of Speculative Attacks. Economic Policy 21:249312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry, Rose, Andrew K., and Wyplosz, Charles. 1996. Contagious Currency Crises. Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Flood, Robert P., and Garber, Peter M.. 1984. Collapsing Exchange Rate Regimes: Some Linear Examples. Journal of International Economics 17:113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, John R., Hayes, Jude C., and Stix, Helmut. 1998. Democracy and Markets: The Case of Exchange Rates. Unpublished manuscript, Department of Political Science, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis.Google Scholar
Frieden, Jeffry. 1998. The Political Economy of European Exchange Rates: An Empirical Assessment. Unpublished manuscript, Department of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge, Mass.Google Scholar
Garrett, Geoffrey. 1998. Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerlach, Stefan, and Smets, Frank. 1994. Contagious Speculative Attacks. CEPR Discussion Paper 1055. London: Center for Economic Policy Research.Google Scholar
Girton, Lance, and Roper, Don. 1977. A Monetary Model of Exchange Rate Pressure Applied to the Postwar Canadian Experience. American Economic Review 67 (4):537–48.Google Scholar
Goldfajn, Ilan, and Valdes, Rodrigo O.. 1997. Are Currency Crises Predictable? International Monetary Fund Working Paper 97/159. Washington, D.C.: IMF.Google Scholar
Grilli, Vittorio, Masciandaro, Donato, and Tabellini, Guido. 1991. Political and Monetary Institutions and Public Financial Policies in the Industrial Countries. Economic Policy 13 (October):342–92.Google Scholar
Gros, Daniel, and Thygesen, Neils. 1992. European Monetary Integration: From the European Monetary System to European Monetary Union. New York: St. Martin's Press.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas M. 1987. A Partisanship Theory of Fiscal and Monetary Regimes. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 19 (3):308–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas A. Jr, 1987. The American Political Economy: Macroeconomics and Electoral Politics. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 1998. International Capital Markets. Washington, D.C.: IMF.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF). Various years. Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions. Washington, D.C.: IMF.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF). Various years. International Financial Statistics (CD-ROM). Washington, D.C.: IMF.Google Scholar
Jeanne, Oliver. 1997. Are Currency Crises Self-Fulfilling? A Test. Journal of International Economics 43(3–4):263–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, Gary, Alt, James E., Burns, Nancy E., and Laver, Michael. 1990. A Unified Model of Cabinet Dissolution in Parliamentary Democracies. American Journal of Political Science 34 (3):846–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, Gary, Tomz, Michael, and Wittenberg, Jason. 1998. Making the Most of Statistical Analyses: Improving Interpretation and Presentation. Paper prepared for presentation at the Annual Meetings of the American Political Science Association, Boston, August.Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul. 1979. A Model of Balance-of-Payments Crises. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 11 (3):311–25.Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul. 1996. Are Currency Crises Self-Fulfilling? Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Schofield, Norman. 1990. Multiparty Government: The Politics of Coalition in Europe. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Shepsle, Kenneth A.. 1996. Making and Breaking Governments. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leblang, David A. 1997. Are Capital Controls Obsolete? Domestic and Systemic Determinants of Capital Control in the Developed and Developing World. International Studies Quarterly 41 (3):435–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1984a. A Note on the Meaning of Cabinet Durability. Comparative Political Studies 17 (2): 163–66.Google Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1984b. Democracies. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lobo, Bento, and Tufte, David. 1998. Exchange Rate Volatility: Does Politics Matter? Journal of Macroeconomics 20:351–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masson, Paul. 1998. Contagion: Monsoonal Effects, Spillovers, and Jumps Between Multiple Equilibria. International Monetary Fund Working Paper 98/142. Washington, D.C.: IMF.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice. 1994. The Logic of Currency Crises. NBER Working Paper 4640. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau for Economic Research.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice. 1996. Models of Currency Crises with Self-Fulfilling Features. European Economic Review 40(3–5): 1037–47.Google Scholar
Powell, G. Bingham Jr, 1982. Contemporary Democracies. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Quinn, Dennis P., and Inclan, Carla. 1997. The Origins of Financial Openness: A Study of Current and Capital Account Liberalization. American Journal of Political Science 41 (3):771813.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radelet, Steven, and Sachs, Jeffrey. 1998. The Onset of the East Asian Financial Crisis. Institute for International Development Working Paper. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rae, Douglas W. 1967. The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Sachs, Jeffrey, Tornell, Aaron, and Velasco, Andres. 1996. Financial Crises in Emerging Markets: The Lessons from 1995. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:147215.Google Scholar
Salant, Stephen W., and Henderson, Dale W.. 1978. Market Anticipations of Government Policies and the Price of Gold. Journal of Political Economy 86 (4):627–48.Google Scholar
Strom, Kaare, and Leipart, Jorn Y.. 1993. Policy, Institutions, and Coalition Avoidance: Norwegian Governments, 1945–1990. American Political Science Review 87 (4):870–87.Google Scholar
Tomz, Michael, Wittenberg, Jason, and King, Gary 1998. CLARIFY: Software for Interpreting and Presenting Statistical Results, ver. 1.2. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University. Available at <http://gking.harvard.edu>.Google Scholar
Warwick, Paul V. 1994. Government Survival in Parliamentary Democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Woldendrop, Jaap, Keman, Hans, and Budge, Ian, eds. 1993. Political Data 1945–1990: Party Government in 20 Democracies. European Journal of Political Research 24 (1). Special issue.Google Scholar