Article contents
Interests, power, and multilateralism
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 22 May 2009
Abstract
Multilateralism characterizes, to varying degrees, patterns of interaction among states and the formal organizations they construct. The utility of multilateral norms or organizations varies with the type of cooperation problem states confront. Thus, the functional logic of international cooperation leads to hypotheses about the conditions under which the institution of multilateralism may be a feasible and efficient solution, as in coordination problems, and those under which it will not, as in collaboration problems. Within these constraints, powerful states choose institutions that will serve their interests, with multilateral arrangements becoming more attractive as the future is valued more highly. Multilateral institutions should be stable in circumstances of changing distributions of power, relative to more hierarchical institutions. The vulnerability of patterns of international cooperation to various exogenous changes depends on the type of strategic interaction underlying state behavior.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © The IO Foundation 1992
References
This article was originally prepared for the Ford Foundation West Coast Workshop on Multilateralism, organized by John Gerard Ruggie. The author gratefully acknowledges the Ford Foundation's financial support for this project. My thanks also to Robert Keohane and Stephen Krasner, as well as to the participants in this project, for their valuable comments on this research.
1. See Garrett, Geoffrey, “International Cooperation and Institutional Choice: The European Community's Internal Market,” International Organization 46 (Spring 1992), pp. 533–60;CrossRefGoogle ScholarRuggie, John Gerard, “Multilateralism: The Anatomy of an Institution,” International Organization 46 (Summer 1992), pp. 561–98;CrossRefGoogle ScholarCaporaso, James A., “International Relations Theory and Multilateralism: The Search for Foundations,” International Organization 46 (Summer 1992), pp. 599–632;CrossRefGoogle ScholarWeber, Steve, “Shaping the Postwar Balance of Power: Multilateralism in NATO,” International Organization 46 (Summer 1992), pp. 633–80;CrossRefGoogle ScholarKahler, Miles, “Multilateralism with Small and Large Numbers,” International Organization 46 (Summer 1992), pp. 681–708;CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Ruggie, John Gerard, ed., Multilateralism Matters: The Theory and Praxis of an Institutional Form (New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar, forthcoming). See also International Journal 45 (Autumn 1990)Google Scholar , which is a special issue on multilateralism.
2. Keohane, Robert O., “Multilateralism: An Agenda for Research,” International Journal 45 (Autumn 1990), pp. 731–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
3. Yarbrough, Beth V. and Yarbrough, Robert M., “Cooperation in the Liberalization of International Trade: After Hegemony, What?” International Organization 41 (Winter 1987), p. 4CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
4. Ruggie, , “Multilateralism,” pp. 569–74Google Scholar.
5. See Snidal, Duncan, “Coordination Versus Prisoners ‘Dilemma: Implications for International Cooperation and Regimes,” American Political Science Review 79 (12 1985), pp. 923–42;CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Stein, Arthur A., “Coordination and Collaboration: Regimes in an Anarchic World,” in Krasner, Stephen D., ed., International Regimes (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1983), pp. 115–40Google Scholar.
6. Laver, Michael, “Political Solutions to the Collective Action Problem,” Political Studies 28 (06 1980), pp. 195–209CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
7. I illustrate only two-person games here. Obviously, situations of multilateralism involve more players. However, many of the fundamental dilemmas of cooperation appear in these simple two-person illustrations.
8. The folk theorem demonstrates that cooperation can be maintained as an equilibrium in repeated prisoners' dilemmas, conditional on a low discount rate (i.e., the future is valued highly) and credible retaliatory threats. See Abreu, Dilip, “On the Theory of Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting,” Econometrica 56 (03 1988), pp. 383–96;CrossRefGoogle ScholarFriedman, James, “A Noncooperative Equilibrium for Supergames,” Review of Economic Studies 38 (01 1971), pp. 1–12;CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Axelrod, Robert, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984)Google Scholar.
9. For an example, see Milgrom, Paul, North, Douglass, and Weingast, Barry, “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Medieval Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,” Economics and Politics 1 (Spring 1989), pp. 1–23Google Scholar.
10. Yarbrough, Beth V. and Yarbrough, Robert M., “International Institutions and the New Economics of Organization,” paper delivered to the University of California, Berkeley, Institutional Analysis Workshop, 05 1990Google Scholar ; and Garrett, “International Cooperation and Institutional Choice.”
11. Keohane, Robert O., “Reciprocity in International Relations,” International Organization 40 (Winter 1986), pp. 1–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
12. Jackson, John H., “GATT Machinery and the Tokyo Round Agreements,” in Cline, William R., ed., Trade Policy in the 1980s (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1983), pp. 159–87Google Scholar.
13. Snidal, , “Coordination Versus Prisoners’ Dilemma,” pp. 929–30Google Scholar.
14. See Arrow, Kenneth J., Social Choice and Individual Values, 2d ed. (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1963), pp. 2–3;Google Scholar and McKelvey, Richard P., “Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting: Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control,” Journal of Economic Theory 12 (06 1976), pp. 472–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
15. Weingast, Barry R. and Marshall, William J., “The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets,” Journal of Political Economy 96 (02 1988), pp. 132–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
16. For example, see Oye, Kenneth A., “Explaining Cooperation Under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies,” in Oye, , ed., Cooperation Under Anarchy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1986), pp. 18–22Google Scholar.
17. Finlayson, Jock A. and Zacher, Mark W., “The GATT and the Regulation of Trade Barriers: Regime Dynamics and Functions,” in Krasner, , ed., International Regimes, pp. 273–314Google Scholar.
18. I am grateful to Patrick Morgan for suggesting this example.
19. See Kindleberger, Charles P., The World in Depression (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973)Google Scholar; Krasner, Steven D., “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics 38 (04 1976), pp. 317–43;CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Keohane, Robert O., “The Theory of Hegemonic Stability and Changes in International Regimes, 1967–1977,” in Holsti, Ole, ed., Change in the International System (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1980), pp. 131–62Google Scholar.
20. For example, see Conybeare, John A. C., Trade Wars: The Theory and Practice of International Commercial Rivalry (New York: Columbia University Press, 1987), pp. 55–72Google Scholar.
21. Stein, Arthur A., “The Hegemon's Dilemma: Great Britain, the United States, and the International Economic Order,” International Organization 38 (Spring 1984), pp. 355–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
22. Yarbrough, Beth V. and Yarbrough, Robert M., “Reciprocity, Bilateralism, and Economic ‘Hostages’: Self-enforcing Agreements in International Trade,” International Studies Quarterly 30 (03 1986), pp. 7–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
23. Conybeare, , Trade Wars, p. 278Google Scholar.
24. See Yarbrough and Yarbrough, “Cooperation in the Liberalization of International Trade.”
25. The strategic problems states confront in international monetary affairs differ substantially from those in commercial activities. Under the Bretton Woods regime, for example, the central role of the United States prevented the cooperation problem from being one of collaboration. Instead, we saw a significant asymmetry of interests, perhaps creating a suasion game as discussed below.
26. See Krasner, Stephen D., “Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier,” World Politics 43 (04 1991), pp. 336–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
27. See Garrett, Geoffrey and Weingast, Barry, “Ideas, Interests, and Institutions: Constructing the EC's Internal Market,” presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C., 28 08–1 09, 1991Google Scholar.
28. For another perspective on the functions regimes can perform in coordination games under conditions of imperfect information, see Morrow, James D., “Modelling International Regimes,” paper presented at the annual meeting of the Public Choice Society, New Orleans, La., 20–2203Google Scholar
29. Cowhey, Peter F., “The International Telecommunications Regime: The Political Roots of Regimes for High Technology,” International Organization 44 (Spring 1990), pp. 169–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
30. Eichengreen, Barry, “Hegemonic Stability Theories of the International Monetary System, in Cooper, Richard N. et al. Can Nations Agree? Issues in International Economic Cooperation (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1989), pp. 255–98Google Scholar.
31. See Mastanduno, Michael, “Trade as a Strategic Weapon: American and Alliance Export Control Policy in the Early Postwar Period,” International Organization 42 (Winter 1988), pp. 121–50;CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Martin, Lisa L., Coercive Cooperation: Explaining Multilateral Economic Sanctions (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1992)Google Scholar.
32. For discussions of this strategy, see Sebenius, James K., “Negotiation Arithmetic: Adding and Subtracting Issues and Parties,” International Organization 37 (Spring 1983), pp. 281–316CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Stein, Arthur A., “The Politics of Linkage,” World Politics 33 (10 1980), pp. 62–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and McGinnis, Michael D., “Issue Linkage and the Evolution of Cooperation,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 30 (03 1986), pp. 14170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
33. Schiff, Benjamin N., “Dominance Without Hegemony: U.S. Relations with the International Atomic Energy Agency,” in Karns, Margaret P. and Mingst, Karen A., eds., The United States and Multilateral Institutions: Patterns of Changing Instrumentality and Influence, Mershon Center Series on International Security and Foreign Policy, vol. 5 (Boston, Mass.: Unwin Hyman, 1990), pp. 57–89Google Scholar.
34. Olson, Mancur, The Logic of Collective Action (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1965)Google Scholar.
35. Domestic strategies can also influence the credibility of commitments to international agreements. See Peter Cowhey's chapter in Ruggie, Multilateralism Matters.
36. See Keohane, Robert O., After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984), pp. 91–92, for a general discussion of the role of institutions in issue linkageGoogle Scholar.
37. Stein, , “Coordination and Collaboration,” p. 119Google Scholar.
38. Jervis, Robert, “Cooperation Under the Security Dilemma,” World Politics 30 (01 1978), pp. 58–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
39. The impact of small deviations from intended strategies has led to the concept of trembling-hand equilibria. See Selten, Reinhard, “Re-examination of the Perfectness Concept for Equilibrium Points in Extensive Games,” International Journal of Game Theory, vol. 4, no. 1, 1975, pp. 25–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
40. See Kahler, “Multilateralism with Small and Large Numbers.”
41. Ruggie, , “Multilateralism,” p. 586Google Scholar.
42. Ibid., p. 577.
43. See Krasner, “Global Communications and National Power.”
44. Miles Kahler, “The United States and the International Monetary Fund: Declining Influence or Declining Interest?” in Karns, and Mingst, , The United Slates and Multilateral Institutions, p. 97Google Scholar.
45. Gallarotti, Giulio M., “Revisions in Realism: The Political Economy of Domination,” paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, Georgia, 09 1989Google Scholar.
46. Krasner, Stephen D., Structural Conflict: The Third World Against Global Liberalism (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985), p. 62Google Scholar.
47. Levi, Margaret, Of Rule and Revenue (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), p. 28Google Scholar.
48. Pollard, Robert A., Economic Security and the Origins of the Cold War, 1945–1950 (New York: Columbia University Press, 1985)Google Scholar.
49. Weber, “Shaping the Postwar Balance of Power.”
50. Gowa, Joanne, “Rational Hegemons, Excludable Goods, and Small Groups: An Epitaph for Hegemonic Stability Theory?” World Politics 41 (04 1989), pp. 307–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar . Gowa also emphasizes the point made earlier in this article that the excludibility of free trade is an essential element of its maintenance.
51. See Snyder, Glenn H., “The Security Dilemma in Alliance Politics,” World Politics 36 (07 1984), pp. 461–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gowa, Joanne, “Bipolarity, Multipolarity, and Free Trade,” American PoliticalScience Review 83 (12 1989), pp. 1245–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Waltz, Kenneth N., Theory of International Politics (Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1979)Google Scholar.
52. Snyder, , “The Security Dilemma in Alliance Politics,” p. 473Google Scholar. The question of burden sharing within the alliance, however, is an entirely different issue. Here, the asymmetry of power within the alliance put the United States into a suasion game whereby it contributed a disproportionately high level of resources to the alliance. See also Olson, Mancur and Zeckhauser, Richard, “An Economic Theory of Alliances,” Review of Economics and Statistics 48 (08 1966), pp. 266–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Oneal, John R., “Testing the Theory of Collective Action: NATO Defense Burdens, 1950–1984,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 34 (09 1990), pp. 426–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
53. Gowa, , “Bipolarity, Multipolarity, and Free Trade,” p. 1250Google Scholar.
54. Current changes in the structure of security arrangements in Europe bear out this logic. East European states are turning to NATO for security. However, NATO, wary of the reliability and stability of the new East European regimes, is insisting on a series of bilateral arrangements rather than formal incorporation into the multilateral framework.
55. For an example, see Dornbusch, Rudiger W., “Policy Options for Freer Trade: The Case for Bilateralism,” in Lawrence, Robert Z. and Schultze, Charles L., eds., An American Trade Strategy (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1990), pp. 106–34Google Scholar.
56. For a discussion of embedded goals, see Ruggie, John Gerard, “International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order,” in Krasner, , ed., International Regimes, pp. 195–231Google Scholar.
57. For an example, see Spar, Debora L., “The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment in Eastern Europe,” prepared for the Center for International Affairs project on International Institutions after the Cold War, Harvard University, Cambridge, Mass., 11 1991Google Scholar.
58. See Cowhey, “The International Telecommunications Regime.”
59. Snidal, Duncan, “The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory,” International Organization 39 (Autumn 1985), pp. 579–614CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
60. Schiff, , “Dominance without Hegemony,” p. 78.Google Scholar
- 241
- Cited by