Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T06:23:43.108Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Economic culture and foreign policy: the cognitive analysis of economic policy making

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Get access

Extract

Political scientists researching economic foreign policy have generally taken one of two analytic approaches. The first is based on realpolitik, the traditional application of “high” politics to the “low” politics of economics. This approach considers economics subordinate to politics. The concept of the national interest dominates; the pursuit of power—what enables the state to achieve its goals of security, welfare, and other societal values—is seen to underlie most actions. The study of foreign economic policy is thus an analysis of the distribution of power among states within the international system. By understanding a state's sources of strength and areas of vulnerability in relation to other states, the analyst will better understand the creation of foreign policy. Hans Morgenthau notes that while states may sometimes pursue economic policies for their own sake (in which case they should take little interest in their success), the more important economic policies they will favor are instruments of political power.Stephen Krasner views the state as an autonomously motivated actor, able to guide policy in pursuit of state priorities while resisting interest groups and ideologies. According to this “power theory”, the state tries to increase its economic competitiveness, ensure security of material needs, and promote its broad foreign-policy objectives. Economic policy is for the most part subordinate to and best explained by state priorities and prerogatives. Robert Tucker, Klaus Knorr, Robert Gilpin and others have also adopted this framework.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation and Cambridge University Press 1987

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. Morgenthau, Hans J., Politics among Nations (New York: Knopf, 1972), provides the classic expression of this; see p. 31.Google Scholar Others include Stephen Krasner, D., Defending the National Interest (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978)Google Scholar; Robert, Gilpin, U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation (New York: Basic, 1975).Google Scholar

2. Krasner, , Defending the National Interest, p. 4.Google Scholar

3. Gilpin, , U.S. Power; Klaus Knorr, The Power of Nations (New York: Basic, 1975)Google Scholar; Tucker, Robert W., The Inequality of Nations (New York: Basic, 1977).Google Scholar

4. As noted in Stephen Krasner, D., “State Power and the Structure in International Trade”, World Politics 28 (04 1976), pp. 317–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Keohane, Robert O., “The Theory of Hegemonic Stability”, in Holsti, Ole R., Siverson, Randolph M., and George, Alexander L., eds., Change in the International System (Boulder: Westview, 1980)Google Scholar, among others, and recently amended by Keohane's, After Hegemony (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1984).Google Scholar

5. Arthur, Stein, “The Hegemon's Dilemma”, International Organization 38 (Spring 1984), p. 357.Google Scholar

6. Although behavioralism as a methodology in political science can be traced to Charles Merriam at the University of Chicago in the 1920s, use of the term here is restricted to the analysis of international policy based on the behavior of social actors within the polity. A general critique of political behavioralism is Heinz, Eulau, ed., Behavioralism in Political Science (New York: Atherton, 1969).Google Scholar

7. Keohane, Robert O., “The Demand for International Regimes”, in International Organization 36 (Spring 1982), pp. 325–55; and Keohane, After HegemonyCrossRefGoogle Scholar

8. Thompson, Kenneth W. and Macridis, Roy C., “The Comparative Study of Foreign Policy”, in Macridis, , ed., Foreign Policy in World Politics (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1976)Google Scholar; a far greater number of variables is explored in Rummel, R. J., The Dimensionality of Nations (Beverly Hills: Sage, 1972).Google Scholar

9. The less than logical dynamics of economic policy making are particularly visible in Morton Halperin's example of a $5.8 billion foreign aid request in Bureaucratic Politics and Foreign Policy (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1974), pp. 204–6.Google Scholar

10. William, Wallace, The Foreign Policy Process in Britain (London: Royal Institute of International Affairs, 1975)Google Scholar; Mayntz, R. and Scharpf, F. W., Policymaking in the German Federal Bureaucracy (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1975)Google Scholar; Joffe, Josef, Macridis, Roy C., Epstein, Leon D. and others in Macridis, , ed., Foreign Policy and World Politics; Stephen D. Cohen, The Making of United States International Economic Policy (New York: Praeger, 1977), p. 108.Google Scholar

11. Katzenstein, Peter J., ed., Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1978).Google Scholar

12. Robert, Jervis, The Logic of Images (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1970)Google Scholar; Robert, Jervis, Perception and Misperception in International Politics (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1977)Google Scholar; Holsti, Ole R., “Cognitive Dynamics and Images of the Enemy: Dulles and Russia”, in Finlay, D., Holsti, O., and Fagen, R., Enemies in Politics (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1967)Google Scholar; Alexander, George and Juliette, George, Woodrow Wilson and Colonel House(New York: Dover, 1964)Google Scholar; Kenneth, Boulding, “National Images and International Systems”, Journal of Conflict Resolution 3, no. 2 (1959).Google Scholar

13. Holsti, , “Cognitive Dynamics”, pp. 3136.Google Scholar More recently Holsti summarized the history of attempts to include the cognitive element in foreign policy making and noted the concern about the relevance of psychology developed in the laboratory to the real world of politics. See his “Foreign Policy Viewed Cognitively”, in Robert, Axelrod, ed., Structure of Decision(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1976), pp. 2429.Google Scholar The use of cognitive analysis proposed here accords more with his recommendation for a conceptual model (ibid., p. 34) that focuses on the perceptions, analyses, and prescriptions for decision making. The cognitive mapping technique Axelrod advocates in that volume relapses into leader–specific belief structures (ibid., chap. 3).

14. Jervis, Perception and Misperception and The Logic of Images; George, Alexander L. and George, Juliette, “the ‘Operational Code’: A Neglected Approach to the Study of Political Leaders and Decision Making”, International Studies Quarterly 13 (06 1969), pp. 190222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

15. Jervis, , The Logic of Images, p. 15.Google Scholar

16. See for example their articles in International Organization 36 (Spring 1982)Google Scholar, and Susan, Strange, “What is Economic Power and Who Has it?International Journal 30 (1975)Google Scholar, which are essentially systemic approaches to political economy, concerned with outcomes from unit interactions and the capabilities distributed among the units.

17. Wilson, Edward O., Sociobiology: The New Synthesis (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1975), chap. 27.Google Scholar Wilson distinguishes between individual selection and interdemic (group) selection; he believes the latter selects for group behavioral traits (e.g., altruism) that are adaptive in the environmental context.

18. Clifford, Geertz, The Interpretation of Cultures (New York: Free, 1973), chap. 1.Google Scholar

19. Odell, John S., U.S. Monetary Policy: Markets, Power and Ideas as Sources of Change (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1982).Google Scholar

20. Apart from the extensive literature on the sociology of knowledge, the role of knowledge in foreign policy making is explored in Haas, Ernst B., “Why Collaborate?World Politics 32, no. 3 (1980), pp. 357405CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Haas, , “Words Can Hurt You; or, Who Said What to Whom about Regimes”, International Organization 36 (Spring 1982), pp. 207–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Rothstein, Robert L, “Consensual Knowledge and International Collaboration”, International Organization 38 (Autumn 1984), pp. 732–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

21. Gabriel, Almond, “Comparative Political Systems”, Journal of Politics 18, no. 3 (1956).Google Scholar

22. See, for example, Lucian, Pye, “Introduction”, in Pye, , ed., Political Culture and Political Development (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965), p. 7Google Scholar; see also Gabriel, Almond and Sidney, Verba, The Civic Culture (Boston: Little, Brown, 1965)Google Scholar, and Lucian, Pye, Politics, Personality, and Nation Building (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1962).Google Scholar

23. Almond, and Verba, , The Civic Culture, p. 12.Google Scholar

24. Pye, , “Introduction”, p. 7.Google Scholar

25. Almond, and Verba, , The Civic Culture, p. 12.Google Scholar

26. Fritz, Stern, The Failure of Illiberalism (New York: Knopf, 1972), p. 32.Google Scholar

27. Geertz, , The Interpretation of Cultures, pp. 218–19.Google Scholar

28. George, Alexander L., “Domestic Constraints in U.S. Foreign Policy: The Need for Policy Legitimacy”, in Holsti, , George, , and Siverson, , Change in International Relations, p.235.Google Scholar George calls these the normative and cognitive components but uses cognitive in a simpler sense of “base knowledge” which is quite different from the cognitive analysis discussed here.

29. Kuhn, Thomas L., The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962).Google Scholar

30. Benjamin, Ward, Ideal Worlds of Economics (New York: Basic, 1979), p. 1.Google Scholar

31. Pye, , “Introduction”, pp. 910.Google Scholar

32. This latter circumstance would not in itself disprove the utility of the variable but, rather, question the coherence and integrity of the given economic culture.

33. Cox, Robert W., “Labor and Hegemony”, International Organizational (Summer 1977), and his discussion there of Antonio Gramsci's Prison NotebooksCrossRefGoogle Scholar

34. Nef, John U. notes the rise of industrial society and its attendant psychology in Europe; The Cultural Foundations of Civilization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1959), pp. 5061.Google Scholar

35. Adam Smith recognized in The Wealth of Nations that the state could depart from pure liberalism to protect industries, regulate the issue of banknotes, provide public education, and perform other “illiberal” state functions. Jacob Viner noted the great range of departures that Smith sanctioned in his Adam Smith and Laissez Faire”, Journal of Political Economy 35, no. 2 (1927).Google Scholar There has been much debate as to how fully any nation has ever followed the true doctrine of laissez-faire, a debate reviewed by Holmes, Colin J., “Laissez–Faire in Theory and Practice: Britain 1800–1975”, Journal of Economic History 5 (1976), p. 674.Google Scholar

36. David, Thomson, England in the Nineteenth Century (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1950), p. 47.Google Scholar The 1833 Factory Acts limited children under eleven years old to no more than nine hours a day in the factory; this was an improvement upon the 1802 Act which limited child labor to twelve hours daily without nightwork.

37. Eric, Hobsbawm, Industry and Empire (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1968), p. 197.Google Scholar

38. Karl, Polanyi'sThe Great Transformation is actually about this tension and the evolving government role (Boston: Beacon, 1957).Google Scholar His definition of liberalism has three tenets: a gold standard, international free trade, and a competitive labor market (p. 138). Because the labor market was just one area in which the government had to redefine its role, I have stated the two antithetical principles that formed the basis for this judgment, points 3 and 4.

39. Rondo, Cameron, “England”, in Cameron, , ed., Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialization (New York: Oxford University Press, 1967), p. 18.Google Scholar

40. William, Cooke Taylor, The Life and Times of Robert Peel, 3 vols. (London: Peter Jackson, n.d. [1860]), 1:93.Google Scholar

41. ibid., 3:272.

42. ibid., 1:96.

43. ibid., 1:100.

44. Thomson, , England in the Nineteenth Century, p. 26.Google Scholar

45. George, Armitage-Smith, The Free Trade Movement and Its Results (1903; reprint, Freeport, N.Y.: Books for Libraries, 1969), p. 54.Google Scholar

46. Smith, , The Wealth of Nations, bk. 4, chap. 5Google Scholar; Smith ultimately had to admit that the political tenor of his times limited the freedom of economic policy making, “that [the Corn Law], though not the best in itself, is the best which the interests, prejudices, and temper of the times would admit of”.

47. Imlah, Albert H., Economic Elements of the Pax Britannica (New York: Russell & Russell, 1958), pp. 9496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

48. ibid., p. 80.

49. Bernard, Semmel, The Rise of Free Trade Imperialism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970), pp. 186–88.Google Scholar

50. The Cobden-Chevalier Treaty in fact worked to the benefit of French trade; in 1858–77 British exports to France rose from £9 million to £ £25 million, but French exports to Britain went from £13 million to £45 million over the same period.

51. Imlah, , Economic Elements, p. 40.Google Scholar

52. ibid., p. 129; figures for exports are in millions of pounds, averaged over four–year periods, 1816–1820, 1939–1942.

53. Tony, Smith, The Pattern of Imperialism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981), pp. 2930.Google Scholar He bases much of his thinking on John, Gallagher and Ronald, Robinson, “The Imperialism of Free Trade”, Economic History Review 6, no. 1 (1953).Google Scholar

54. Semmel, Free Trade Imperialism To the extent that this orthodoxy was universally adopted as a guide for proper policy making, the legitimizing force in other words, it represents a form of ideological hegemony noted in the writings of Gramsci.

55. Germany's fleet in 1850 was made up of only 3,700 vessels. Mitchell, B. R., European Historical Statistics 1750–1975 (New York: Facts on File, 1980).Google Scholar

56. Thomson, , England in the Nineteenth Century, pp. 2223.Google Scholar

57. ibid.

58. Sir Robert, Peel, Memoirs, 2 vols. (London: John Murray, 1858), 2:105.Google Scholar

59. Crosby, Travis L., Sir Robert Peel's Administration, 1841–1846 (Hamden, Conn.: Archon, 1976), p. 156.Google Scholar

60. Taylor, , Life and Times, 3:250.Google Scholar

61. Intra-Whig dissent also contributed to Russell's problems: having publicly announced himself in favor of the repeal in November, he could not have formed a government excluding Earl Grey, a prominent free-trade advocate; Grey, however, refused to sit on a cabinet that had Palmerston in the Foreign Office, and this too frustrated Russell. See Crosby, , Peel's Administration, pp. 143–44.Google Scholar

62. Peel, , Memoirs, 2:222–50.Google Scholar

63. Armitage-Smith, , Free Trade Movement, p. 70.Google Scholar

64. Cited in Semmel, , Free Trade Imperialism, p. 207.Google Scholar

65. Herbert, Heaton, “Economic Change and Growth”, in The New Cambridge Modern History, vol. 10Google Scholar, The Zenith of European Power, 18301870, p. 26.Google Scholar

66. Aydelotte, W. O., “The Conservative and Radical Interpretations of Early Victorian Social Legislation”, Victorian Studies 2 (1967), pp. 225–36.Google Scholar

67. Armitage-Smith, , Free Trade Movement, pp. 9293.Google Scholar

68. David, Thomson, “The United Kingdom and Its Worldwide Interests”, in The New Cambridge Modern History, vol. 10, p. 343.Google Scholar

69. Polanyi, , Great Transformation, pp. 115–16, passim.Google Scholar

70. Leland, Hamilton Jenks, The Migration of British Capital to 1875 (London: Thomas Nelson, 1924), pp. 158–59.Google Scholar

71. Cobden addressing an anti-Corn Law meeting in Manchester, 23 12, 1845, quoted in Armitage-Smith, p. 64, n. 1.

72. Thomson, , England in the Nineteenth Century, p 52.Google Scholar

73. One economist noted in regard to the relationship between British imports and British exports that the latter was definitely the more dependent variable; greater food imports theoretically meant greater hope for manufactured exports. Imlah, , Economic Elements, pp. 127–29, n. 19.Google Scholar

74. Philip, Harwood, at a lecture at London Mechanics Institute, 1843.Google ScholarCited, in Semmel, Free Trade Imperialism, p. 130.Google Scholar

75. Armitage, Smith, Free Trade Movement, p. 82.Google Scholar

76. Peel, , Memoirs, 2:172.Google Scholar

77. Quoted in Armitage, Smith, Free Trade Movement, p. 73.Google Scholar This may be a paraphrase of Peel's remarks in Parliament, 22 and 24 September, 1841, Hansard Parliamentary Debates, 3d Series, vol. 59 (1841), cols. 708–10, 772–74.Google Scholar

78. Jacob, Viner, Studies in the Theory of International Trade (New York: Harper, 1937), pp. 224–29.Google Scholar

79. Taylor, , Life and Times, 4:402.Google Scholar

80. Macaulay, Lord Thomas B., History of England, 4 vols. (New York: Harper, 1856), 3:67.Google Scholar

81. Lord William Melbourne in February 1839, quoted in Armitage, Smith, Free Trade Move ment, p. 69.Google Scholar

82. Semmel, , Free Trade Imperialism, p. 208.Google Scholar

83. Walter, Laqueur, Weimar: A Cultural History (New York: G. P. Putnam's, 1974), pp. 254–56Google Scholar; Erick, Eyck, A History of the Weimar Republic, 2 vols. (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1963), 2:123–23Google Scholar; Egon, Larsen, Weimar Eyewitness (London: Bachman & Turner, 1976), p. 151.Google Scholar

84. Katzenstein's recent book on comparative democratic corporatism uses an approach closer to economic culture by focusing on the timing of industrialization, the international political context, and the indigenous social structure to understand the mix of social economic arrangements specific to European countries. See Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1985), pp. 170–81, and passim.Google Scholar

85. Kindleberger, Charles P., “The Rise of Free Trade in Western Europe, 1820–1875,” Journal of Economic History 35, no. 1 (1975), p. 49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar