Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T09:40:26.013Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Anarchy, hierarchy, and the variety of international relations

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 February 2009

Get access

Extract

Security relations between states vary along a continuum from anarchic alliances to hierarchic empires. This continuum, in turn, is defined by the parties' rights of residual control. The state's choice between alternatives is explained in a theory of relational contracting as a function of the expected costs of opportunism, which decline with relational hierarchy, and governance costs, which rise with relational hierarchy. A comparison of early postwar relations between the United States and Western Europe and the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe illustrates the theory.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1996

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Achen, Christopher H. 1988. A state with bureaucratic politics is representable as a unitary rational actor. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C., 31 August–3 September.Google Scholar
Baldwin, David A. 1985. Economic statecraft. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Barnett, Michael N., and Levy, Jack S.. 1991. Domestic sources of alliances and alignments: The case of Egypt, 1962–1973. International Organization 45:369–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Botting, Douglas. 1985. In the ruins of the reich. Boston: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Brzezinski, Zbigniew K. 1967. The Soviet bloc: Unity and conflict. Rev. ed. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, and Lalman, David. 1992. War and reason: Domestic and international imperatives. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bunce, Valerie. 1985. The empire strikes back: The transformation of the Eastern bloc from a Soviet asset to a Soviet liability. International Organization 39:146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buzan, Barry. 1991. People, states, and fear: An agenda for international security studies in the post–cold war era. 2d ed.Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner.Google Scholar
Cain, P. J., and Hopkins, A. G.. 1993. British imperialism. 2 vols. New York: Longman.Google Scholar
Campbell, John C. 1984. Soviet policy in Eastern Europe: An overview. In Soviet policy in Eastern Europe, edited by Terry, Sarah Meiklejohn. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christensen, Thomas J., and Snyder, Jack. 1990. Chain gangs and passed bucks: Predicting alliance patterns in multipolarity. International Organization 44:137–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowhey, Peter F. 1993. Domestic institutions and the credibility of international commitments: Japan and the United States. International Organization 47:299326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crane, Keith. 1986. The Soviet economic dilemma of Eastern Europe. Document R-3368–AF, Rand Corporation, Santa Monica, Calif.Google Scholar
Dallin, David J. 1942. Soviet Russia's foreign policy, 1939–1942. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
David, Steven R. 1991. Explaining Third World alignment. World Politics 43:233–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davidson, Eugene. 1961. The death and life of Germany: An account of the American occupation. New York: Knopf.Google Scholar
Dow, Gregory K. 1987. The function of authority in transaction cost economics. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8:1338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doyle, Michael W. 1986. Empires. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, Thráinn. 1990. Economic behavior and institutions. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1992. Threats to use force: Costly signals and bargaining in international crises. Ph.D. diss., University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Fearon, James D.. 1993. Ethnic war as a commitment problem, University of Chicago. Photocopy.Google Scholar
Friedberg, Aaron L. 1988. The weary titan: Britain and the experience of relative decline, 1895–1905. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Frieden, Jeffry A. 1994. International investment and colonial control: A new interpretation. International Organization 48:559–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Julian R., Bladen, Christopher, and Rosen, Steven, eds. 1970. Alliance in international politics. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.Google Scholar
Gallagher, John, and Robinson, Ronald. 1953. The imperialism of free trade. The Economic History Review 2d ser., 6:115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grosser, Alfred. 1955. The colossus again: Western Germany from defeat to rearmament. New York: Frederick A. Praeger.Google Scholar
Grossman, Sanford J., and Hart, Oliver D.. 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy 94:691719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holden, Gerard. 1989. The Warsaw pact: Soviet security and bloc politics. New York: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Holsti, Ole R., Hopmann, P. Terrence, and Sullivan, John D.. 1973. Unity and disintegration in international alliances: Comparative studies. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
James, Alan. 1986. Sovereign statehood: The basis of international society. Boston: Unwin and Hyman.Google Scholar
Jervis, Robert. 1983. Security regimes. In International Regimes, edited by Krasner, Stephen D.. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Jones, Robert A. 1990. The Soviet concept of “limited sovereignty” from Lenin to Gorbachev: The Brezhnev doctrine. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, Lawrence S. 1984. The United States and NATO: The formative years. Lexington: University Press of Kentucky.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert O. 1983. The demand for international regimes. In International Regimes, edited by Krasner, Stephen D.. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert O.. 1984. After hegemony: Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
King, Gary, Keohane, Robert O., and Verba, Sidney. 1994. Designing social inquiry: Scientific inference in qualitative research. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, Crawford, Robert G., and Alchian, Armen A.. 1978. Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics 21: 297326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LaFeber, Walter. 1993. America, Russia, and the cold war, 1945–1992. 7th ed.New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Lake, David A. 1988. Power, protection, and free trade: International sources of U.S. commercial strategy, 1887–1939. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Lake, David A.. 1992. Powerful pacifists: Democratic states and war. American Political Science Review 86: 2437.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lake, David A.. Forthcoming. Entangling relations: American foreign policy in its century.Google Scholar
Lane, Frederic C. 1979. Profits from power: Readings in protection rent and violence-controlling enterprises. Albany: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Leffler, Melvyn P. 1992. A preponderance of power: National security, the Truman administration, and the cold war. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipson, Charles. 1994. Understanding international contracts: Building institutions and sustaining agreements in an anarchic world. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, 1–4 September, New York.Google Scholar
Lipson, Charles. 1995. Techniques and problems of international contracting. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the International Studies Association, 21–25 February, Chicago.Google Scholar
Louis, Wm. Roger, ed. 1976. Imperialism: The Robinson and Gallagher controversy. New York: New Viewpoints.Google Scholar
Marer, Paul. 1984a. Intrabloc economic relations and prospects. In The Warsaw pact: Alliance in transition, edited by Holloway, David and Sharp, Jane M. O.. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Marer, Paul. 1984b. The political economy of Soviet relations with Eastern Europe. In Soviet policy in Eastern Europe, edited by Terry, Sarah Meiklejohn. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Marrese, Michael, and Vanous, Jan. 1983. Soviet subsidization of trade with Eastern Europe: A Soviet perspective. Research series no. 52, Institute of International Studies, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Martin, Lisa L. 1992. Coercive cooperation: Explaining multilateral economic sanctions. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mastny, Vojtech. 1979. Russia's road to the cold war: Diplomacy, warfare, and the politics of communism, 1941–1945. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Mearsheimer, John J. 19941995. The false promise of international institutions. International Security 19:549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrow, James D. 1991. Alliances and asymmetry: An alternative to the capability aggregation model of alliances. American Journal of Political Science 35:904–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrow, James D.. 1993. Arms versus allies: Trade-offs in the search for security. International Organization 47: 207–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrow, James D.. 1994. Game theory for political scientists. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Most, Benjamin A., and Starr, Harvey. 1984. International relations theory, foreign policy substitutability, and “nice” laws. World Politics 36:383406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niou, Emerson M. S., and Ordeshook, Peter C.. 1994. Alliances versus federations: An analysis with military and economic capabilities distinguished. Durham, N.C.: Duke University, and Pasadena: California Institute of Technology, respectively. Photocopy.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and change in economic history. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C.. 1990. Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nye, Joseph S. Jr, and Lynn-Jones, Sean M.. 1988. International security studies: A report of a conference on the state of the field. International Security 12:527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Papayoanou, Paul A. 1992. Economic interdependence and the balance of power: The strategy of commitment and great power politics. Ph.D. diss., University of California, Los Angeles.Google Scholar
Posen, Barry R. 1984. The sources of military doctrine: France, Britain, and Germany between the world wars. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1990. Nuclear deterrence theory: The search for credibility. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poznanski, Kazimiera Z. 1988. Opportunity cost in Soviet trade with Eastern Europe: Discussion of methodology and new evidence. Soviet Studies 40:290307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richter, James. 1993. Re-examining Soviet policy towards Germany in 1953. Europe-Asia Studies 45:671–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roeder, Philip G. 1993. Red sunset: The failure of Soviet politics. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Roeder, Philip G.. 1995. From hierarchy to hegemony: Patterns of security among the Soviet successor states. In Regional orders: Building security in a new world, edited by Lake, David A. and Morgan, Patrick M., Institute on Global Conflict and Cooperation, University of California, San Diego. Typescript.Google Scholar
Rosecrance, Richard. 1986. The rise of the trading state: Commerce and conquest in the modern world. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Ruggie, John Gerard. 1983. Continuity and transformation in the world polity: Toward a neorealist synthesis. World Politics 35:261–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruggie, John Gerard. 1993. Territoriality and beyond: Problematizing modernity in international relations. International Organization 47:139–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russett, Bruce, and Starr, Harvey. 1989. World politics: The menu for choice. 3d ed.New York: W. H. Freeman.Google Scholar
Schroeder, Paul W. 1976. Alliances, 1815–1945: Weapons of power and tools of management. In Historical dimensions of national security problems, edited by Knorr, Klaus. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas.Google Scholar
Schwartz, Thomas. 1987. Votes, strategies, and institutions: An introduction to the theory of collective choice. In Congress: Structure and policy, edited by McCubbins, Mathew D. and Sullivan, Terry. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shirk, Susan L. 1993. The political logic of economic reform in China. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmons, Beth A. 1993. Why innovate? Founding the Bank for International Settlements. World Politics 45:361405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siverson, Randolph M., and Emmons, Juliann. 1991. Birds of a feather: Democratic political systems and alliance choices in the twentieth century. Journal of Conflict Resolution 35:285306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siverson, Randolph M., and Starr, Harvey. 1991. The diffusion of war: A study of opportunity and willingness. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Tony. 1981. The pattern of imperialism: The United States, Great Britain, and the late-industrializing world since 1815. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Snyder, Glenn H. 1984. The security dilemma in alliance politics. World Politics 36:461–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Glenn H.. 1990. Alliance theory: A neorealist first cut. Journal of International Affairs 44:103–22.Google Scholar
Snyder, Jack. 1991. Myths of empire: Domestic politics and international ambition. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Stein, Arthur A. 1990. Why nations cooperate: Circumstance and choice in international relations. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Stone, Randall, forthcoming. Satellites and commissars: Strategy and conflict in the politics of Soviet-bloc trade. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Coercion, capital, and European states, AD 990–1990. Cambridge, Mass.: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Triska, Jan F., ed. 1986. Dominant powers and subordinate states: The United States in Latin America and the Soviet Union in Eastern Europe. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Ulam, Adam B. 1974. Expansion and coexistence: Soviet foreign policy, 1917–1973. 2d ed.New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
van Brabant, Jozef M. 1984. The USSR and socialist economic integration: A comment. Soviet Studies 36:127–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallander, Celeste A., and Keohane, Robert O.. 1995. An institutional approach to alliance theory. Working paper 95–2, Center for International Affairs, Harvard University, Cambridge, Mass.Google Scholar
Walt, Stephen M. 1987. The origins of alliances. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Walt, Stephen M.. 1991. The renaissance of security studies. International Studies Quarterly 35:211–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waltz, Kenneth. 1967. Foreign policy and domestic politics: The American and British experience. Berkeley: University of California Institute of Governmental Studies Press.Google Scholar
Waltz, Kenneth. 1979. Theory of international politics. Reading, Mass.: Addison Wesley.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., and Marshall, William J.. 1988. The industrial organization of Congress: Or, why legislatures, like firms, are not organized as markets. Journal of Political Economy 96: 132–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wendt, Alexander. 1992. Anarchy is what states make of it: The social construction of power politics. International Organization 46:391425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, William Appleman. 1972. The tragedy of American diplomacy. 2d rev. ed.New York: Dell.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Willoughby, W. W., and Fenwick, C. G.. [1919] 1974. The inquiry handbooks, vol. 16. Wilmington, Del. Reprint. Originally published as Types of restricted sovereignty and of colonial autonomy. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Yarbrough, Beth V., and Yarbrough, Robert M.. 1992. Cooperation and governance in international trade: The strategic organizational approach. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar