Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t8hqh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T13:44:15.952Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Party-System Polarization and Individual Perceptions of Party Differences: Two Divergent Effects on Turnout

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 January 2024

Sigrid Rossteutscher
Affiliation:
Department of Social Sciences, Goethe University Frankfurt am Main, Frankfurt am Main, Germany
Lars-Christopher Stövsand*
Affiliation:
Department of Social Sciences, Goethe University Frankfurt am Main, Frankfurt am Main, Germany
*
Corresponding author: Lars-Christopher Stövsand; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In this article, we argue that party-system polarization and subjective perceptions of ideological party differences are conceptually and empirically distinct phenomena that affect electoral participation differently. Looking at 84 elections worldwide, we show that party-system polarization, and the sharp conflicts associated with it, depresses turnout because many citizens are put off by extreme party positions and unrewarding polemics. By contrast, the individual perception of differences between parties increases turnout because more citizens can find a party that is close to their own position and identify others as being further away. These opposite effects are possible because party-system polarization leads only some individuals to perceive differences between parties but leads others to avoid the emotionalized political arena. Moreover, individuals' ability to recognize differences between parties is not necessarily a consequence of party-system polarization. The contradictory findings in previous research are due to a conceptual and empirical blurring of these two essentially different aspects.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Government and Opposition Ltd

Populist and extreme (right-wing and left-wing) parties are challenging democracies around the world and mobilizing substantial parts of their countries' electorates. Often, these are new parties that take extreme ideological positions and mobilize against the so-called ‘mainstream party cartel’, which they accuse of ignoring the real interest of the people. By forcing the traditional parties to react to their challenge, the extreme parties contribute to an increasing polarization in party systems. Moreover, almost all representative democracies have experienced a substantial decline in turnout during the last several decades – the most basic and most essential form of participation in representative democracy (Franklin Reference Franklin2004; Lijphart Reference Lijphart1997). In this article, we concentrate on turnout and examine the role of polarization in explaining individual electoral participation.

To date, evidence on the impact of polarization on turnout is ‘deeply ambiguous’ (Rogowski Reference Rogowski2014: 479, 481; see also Leininger and Meijers Reference Leininger and Meijers2021; Moral Reference Moral2017: 936). As we argue and show, this ambiguity is caused by both a conceptual and an empirical blurring of two distinct mechanisms: (1) party-system polarization depresses turnout among moderate citizens and non-partisans, and (2) individual perceptions of party differences increase electoral participation among all citizens. In the literature on turnout, party polarization aids those voters who see no differences between the parties; otherwise, they would not know which party to vote for – and thus abstain (Downs Reference Downs1957a; Franklin Reference Franklin2004). The higher the level of polarization, the easier it is for even those not so politically sophisticated citizens to recognize parties' diverse ideological standpoints and issue agendas (Ellger Reference Ellger2023; Lachat Reference Lachat2008; Levendusky Reference Levendusky2010; Lupu Reference Lupu2015). As a result, they find some parties to be close to their views and others to be far away. Polarization increases choice and the individual value of the vote and is thus essentially ‘good’ for participation.

We argue that, although both narratives talk about polarization, they refer to two essentially different phenomena: party polarization as a system trait on the one hand, and polarization as individual perceptions of differences between parties on the other. We further argue that these two notions of polarization call for different modes of operationalization. At present, large parts of this rich body of literature fail to differentiate between the macro-level effects of party-system polarization and the micro-level effects of perceived party differences (for rare exceptions, see e.g. Enders and Armaly Reference Enders and Armaly2019; Lupu Reference Lupu2015; Moral Reference Moral2017). As we point out, party-system polarization is only one of several, partly idiosyncratic, sources of individual perceptions of party differences. System polarization and individual perceptions of difference correlate only weakly (see the empirical findings below). This is the case because there are citizens in heavily polarized party systems who do not discern any differences between parties in their country's party system and, vice versa, citizens in centrist party systems who perceive huge differences between parties. Under the condition of system polarization, we expect low turnout because it disengages moderate citizens and non-partisans, which – as we show – represent substantial parts of the electorate in most countries. By contrast, an individual's perception of party differences will always increase their likelihood of participating in elections. Our results confirm the expected differential effects of party-system polarization and perceived party differences. System-level polarization decreases turnout, especially among moderate citizens and non-partisans, whereas perceiving differences in parties' ideological positions mobilizes citizens, irrespective of their ideological position or party identification.

The next section introduces these two stories of polarization in detail. We present our data and operationalization in the subsequent section. Thereafter we discuss the empirical findings and robustness checks and conclude with an evaluation of our results in light of the theoretical discussion.

Political polarization and its effects on turnout

Story 1: The harmful consequences of party-system polarization

This first story refers to system effects. Polarization is a system constellation with two parties or party blocs that are similarly strong in terms of vote share and thus block one another. This results in a dysfunctional government or government gridlock (Abramowitz Reference Abramowitz2013; McCarty Reference McCarty, Hopkins and Sides2015). This system tears the society apart and endangers social cohesion because the two segments are unable to communicate with each other (Hetherington Reference Hetherington2009). In a polarized society, ‘consent over basic values is rarely achieved’ (Rapp Reference Rapp2016: 35). Both sides believe that they are right and that the other side is evil, corrupt or simply stupid (Abramowitz Reference Abramowitz2013; Hetherington Reference Hetherington2009; Mason Reference Mason, Hopkins and Sides2015). Thus, the society exists in a permanent state of political warfare, where everything is focused on winning the next election and there is no focus on governing between elections (Mason Reference Mason, Hopkins and Sides2015; Theriault Reference Theriault, Hopkins and Sides2015). In this situation, no one can remain neutral, the centre begins to ‘disappear’ (Abramowitz Reference Abramowitz2010) and everyone is eventually partisan (Mason Reference Mason, Hopkins and Sides2015; Stonecash Reference Stonecash, Hopkins and Sides2015). The bipolarity no longer concerns single issues but rather entire issue packages that are increasingly intertwined with individuals' basic identities and value orientations (Carsey and Layman Reference Carsey, Layman, Hopkins and Sides2015; Jacoby Reference Jacoby2014; Layman and Carsey Reference Layman and Carsey2002; McCarty Reference McCarty, Hopkins and Sides2015). Instead of cleavages based on economic status or class, society is torn apart by a ‘culture war’ (Abramowitz Reference Abramowitz2013, Reference Abramowitz, Hopkins and Sides2015; see already Hunter Reference Hunter1991). In this situation, politics focuses less on finding solutions for political problems, but rather on invoking social and political identities. It is dominated by two partisan tribes that aim to defeat one another. Note that bipolarity is not at all restricted to two-party systems. In the contemporary multiparty landscape of Europe, for example, polarization is driven by the advent and lasting electoral success of right-wing radical or populist parties (e.g. Bischof and Wagner Reference Bischof and Wagner2019; Ellger Reference Ellger2023; Leininger and Meijers Reference Leininger and Meijers2021; Tavits Reference Tavits2006).

Voter turnout will be initially high and party competition fierce in such a Clausewitzian ‘friend’ or ‘foe’ constellation because it is impossible not to take sides. But will the political community survive such a permanent conflict in the long run? For Joan-María Esteban and Debraj Ray, ‘polarization is closely linked to the generation of tensions, to the possibilities of articulated rebellion and revolt, and to the existence of social unrest in general’ (Reference Esteban and Ray1994: 820). However, many non-partisans and ideologically moderate voters are not at all polarized.

Hence, ordinary citizens are often moderate, they cluster around the ideological centre and are turned off by polarized party positions, permanent partisan hatred and ongoing ‘negative campaigning’ (Ansolabehere and Iyengar Reference Ansolabehere and Iyengar1997; Ansolabehere et al. Reference Ansolabehere, Iyengar, Adam and Valentino1994, Reference Ansolabehere, Iyengar and Simon1999). Those involved in the polarized camps engage in extreme mobilizing efforts (Kleiner Reference Kleiner2018; Rogowski Reference Rogowski2014), which negatively affects those in between. When politics does not revolve around policies but anger and hatred between two groups, moderates and non-partisan citizens perceive political polarization not as policy or ideological polarization but instead as a noisy battle arena which is not of concern to them since they do not belong to any battle camp. Those in between no longer perceive the policy differences behind the noise because they turn their backs on politics, repelled by the constant hatred and attack campaigning. They do not feel represented and thus abstain from voting (Dassonneville and Çakır Reference Dassonneville, Çakır and Dalton2021; Fiorina et al. Reference Fiorina, Abrams and Pope2005; Kleiner Reference Kleiner2018; Levendusky and Malhotra Reference Levendusky and Malhotra2016; Moral Reference Moral2017).

Story 2: The beneficial consequences of party polarization

This second story relates to an individual-level process. Although most authors who emphasize that polarization increases turnout use the term polarization, they do not mean polarization in terms of a bi-modal or ‘two-spike’ (Esteban and Ray Reference Esteban and Ray1994: 825) distribution of party systems, but rather in terms of party distribution along the ideological continuum (Sani and Sartori Reference Sani, Sartori, Daalder and Mair1983: 329). Hence, this literature is inspired by the spatial model as put forth by Anthony Downs (Reference Downs1957a). Downs assumed that parties and voters can be aligned along a left–right continuum that serves as a kind of ‘super-issue’ – that is, an ideological space that encompasses all issues and provides a shortcut for parties and voters (see also Dalton Reference Dalton2008: 904; Fuchs and Klingemann Reference Fuchs, Klingemann and Jennings1990; Laver and Hunt Reference Laver and Hunt1992; Lipset et al. Reference Lipset, Lazarsfeld, Barton, Linz and Lindzey1954; Lupu Reference Lupu2015: 338; Sani and Sartori Reference Sani, Sartori, Daalder and Mair1983: 310; Van der Meer et al. Reference Van der Meer, van Deth and Scheepers2009; Weßels and Schmitt Reference Weßels and Schmitt2008). Put simply, the spatial model predicts that if the nearest party is far away from a citizen's viewpoint, that citizen will abstain from voting. This is exactly the case for moderate citizens in a heavily polarized party system or for extreme citizens in centrist party systems (Ford Reference Ford, Hopkins and Sides2015: 128). However, abstention and indifference are also very likely if parties are equidistant to the voter's position (Downs Reference Downs1957a), or if a citizen's expected party differential is close to zero (Downs Reference Downs1957b: 139) because all parties look alike.

Polarization, understood as the distinctiveness of parties concerning their ideological position, increases voter turnout (Dassonneville and Çakır Reference Dassonneville, Çakır and Dalton2021; Ellger Reference Ellger2023; Hobolt and Hoerner Reference Hobolt and Hoerner2020; Key Reference Key1966; Leighley and Nagler Reference Leighley and Nagler2014; Lupu Reference Lupu2015; Moral Reference Moral2017; Schäfer and Debus Reference Schäfer and Debus2018). Accordingly, heavily polarized party systems and heavily centrist party systems may similarly depress voter turnout because both ideal types ignore the ideological positions of portions of the electorate (Downs Reference Downs1957a: 117ff.): ‘Polarization leaves moderate voters without a voice in politics; centrism leaves voters at the extremes without a voice, and similarly unhappy about it’ (Ford Reference Ford, Hopkins and Sides2015: 128). In other words, electoral choice options can be both too distinct and not distinct enough, and ‘the quality of electoral democracy suffers at both ends of the scale’ (Schmitt and Freire Reference Schmitt, Freire, Sanders, Magalhaes and Tóka2012: 66). The mechanism is that citizens are able to perceive differences between parties and thus differentiate between a party close to their own position and others that are further away (Blais et al. Reference Blais, Singh, Dumitrescu and Thomassen2014; Hobolt and Hoerner Reference Hobolt and Hoerner2020; Leighley and Nagler Reference Leighley and Nagler2014: 8). Polarization increases ‘the clarity of the cues elites send to voters’ (Levendusky Reference Levendusky2010: 114) and thus allows voters to make more sophisticated decisions at a ‘lower cognitive cost’ (Lachat Reference Lachat2008: 688). Elections are ultimately about choices between candidates or parties – and choice is a perception of differences and not necessarily a perception of party-system polarization.

In this line of reasoning some scholars ascribe a corrective function to populism, since it increases ideological representation and fosters electoral participation among those population segments that are alienated from the party system (Huber and Ruth Reference Huber and Ruth2017; Mudde and Rovira Kaltwasser Reference Mudde, Rovira Kaltwasser, Mudde and Kaltwasser2012; see, however, Anduiza et al. Reference Anduiza, Guinjoan and Rico2019; Immerzeel and Pickup Reference Immerzeel and Pickup2015; Schwander et al. Reference Schwander, Gohla and Schäfer2020).

Assuming that citizens' preferences are spread along the left–right continuum, an ideal matching party system would thus not be polarized but encompass parties with very diverse ideological positions, both moderate and extreme. In such a situation, turnout is high because all voters, regardless of their own ideological position, find a party close to their own standpoint and see others as being distant (Moral Reference Moral2017: 941).

Is there a third story?

How can one make sense of these two stories that lead to divergent expectations regarding turnout? The remainder of this article shows that both types of polarization are conceptually and empirically distinct. Party-system polarization dampens turnout in one segment of the electorate and increases electoral participation in another. Moderates and non-partisans tend to abstain because they only find parties that are far away from their own standpoint (Dassonneville and Çakır Reference Dassonneville, Çakır and Dalton2021). By contrast, extreme and partisan citizens are incentivized to cast their vote since they find parties both close to their own views and further away from other parties. This is the case because partisans and extreme voters behave as engaged players in their respective party teams (e.g. Mason Reference Mason, Hopkins and Sides2015). Those who are not part of the competing teams are taken aback by negative campaigning, noise and hatred that characterize party-system polarization. This constant noise obscures the parties' problem-solving strategies for those citizens who are already not strongly involved; those citizens resemble neutral observers who came to enjoy the match and are shocked by the hate choirs and pyrotechnics in the fan blocks. They resolve not to return to the stadium.

Why do we believe that Story 2 is also correct? This is the case because the level of party-system polarization is only one of many different factors that contribute to an individual's perception of differences between parties. However, these perceptions influence behaviour regardless of whether they are rooted in party-system polarization or another source (Adams et al. Reference Adams, Ezrow and Somer-Topcu2011; Dalton Reference Dalton2008: 909; Enders and Armaly Reference Enders and Armaly2019: 816; Kenyon Reference Kenyon2014). We do not even know whether citizens register party positions (Lupu Reference Lupu2015: 334). Individual perceptions of party differences might as well originate from perceptions about candidates' images, their impressions of the campaigns, media consumption, or the amount of attention they pay to politics. They might be a result of discussions among the family, peers, co-workers or members of organizations with which a person is associated. They might also be filtered by partisan identity, projections of disgust or preference for specific parties, conflicts about single issues that are important to a voter, or based on simple misperceptions. They may even be the result of more or less polarized party constellations during a person's formative years, or simply correlate with a person's age, educational background, level of political sophistication or socioeconomic status. What matters is whether or not individuals subjectively perceive differences between the choice set. Citizens who perceive clear differences should participate in elections – regardless of their ideological position – because one party will be closer to their views than other parties.

Thus, we agree with Mert Moral (Reference Moral2017: 942) that individual perceptions of party differences will increase turnout, but we disagree with his expectation about the positive impact of party-system polarization. Based on Story 1, we expect that the noise, negativism and the spirit of non-compromise related to party-system polarization leads instead to lower turnout rates – particularly if an electorate has many non-partisans and moderate citizens. In short, while we argue that party-system polarization depresses turnout among non-partisans and moderates, many citizens may be unaware of party-system polarization. Or, they overwrite the ‘noise’ of hostile party competition with their own idiosyncratic perceptions. In any given electorate both processes can be at work at the same time. Thus, we contend that many citizens are not attentive to party competition but base their perception of party differences on the manifold options spelled out above. As Moral says, ‘citizens’ perceptions of and responses to party polarization are hardly uniform’ (Reference Moral2017: 936).

Thus, we conclude that both stories about the impact of polarization are correct. Too often, however, they are conceptually blurred, which leads to the ambiguity that characterizes the present state of ‘polarization’ research (Moral Reference Moral2017; Rogowski Reference Rogowski2014). It is no coincidence, then, that analyses basing the polarization measurement on subjective perceptions show a mobilizing effect, while analyses based on more ‘objective’ measures conclude that polarization depresses turnout (Moral Reference Moral2017: 938). Strictly speaking, only system polarization – that is, a bipolar and uncompromising party-system constellation – is a clear indication of polarization. On the individual level, by contrast, polarization refers to citizens' ability to perceive differences between the competing parties. Therefore, we contend that the term polarization is misleading for describing this micro-level process. Naturally, party-system polarization might be one arrangement that enables individuals to sort their parties along the ideological spectrum. However, as we argued above, it is only one of many possible origins for individuals' perceptions of party differences. Consequently, party-system polarization and individual perceptions of party differences call for different modes of operationalization. The next section addresses this point in greater detail.

From this discussion on party-system polarization and individually perceived party differences, we derive the following hypotheses. The first two concern the divergent main effects:

Hypothesis 1: As party-system polarization increases, the level of individual turnout decreases.

Hypothesis 2: As individuals perceive more and greater differences between parties, individual turnout increases.

These divergent effects are caused by two independent mechanisms, as spelled out in the following hypotheses:

Hypothesis 3: Individual perceptions of party differences increase turnout among all voters, which includes moderate and more extreme citizens, partisans and non-partisans alike.

Hypothesis 4: Party-system polarization decreases turnout among moderate citizens and non-partisans and increases turnout of more extreme voters and partisans.

Data and operationalization

We use data from the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems (CSES), which is a collaborative research programme of election study teams from around the world. Participating countries include a common module of survey questions in their post-election studies (see http://www.cses.org/). Specifically, this article uses data from waves 3 and 4 – that is, data collected between 2006 and 2011 (Module 3), and 2011 and 2016 (Module 4).Footnote 1 Single case studies have dominated past research, most of which focus on the USA (e.g. Abramowitz Reference Abramowitz2010; Abramowitz and Stone Reference Abramowitz and Stone2006; Enders and Armaly Reference Enders and Armaly2019; Fiorina et al. Reference Fiorina, Abrams and Pope2005; Hetherington Reference Hetherington, Nivola and Brady2008, Reference Hetherington2009; Levendusky and Malhotra Reference Levendusky and Malhotra2016; Rogowski Reference Rogowski2014; Westfall et al. Reference Westfall, van Boven, Chambers and Judd2015; for other single case studies, see, e.g. Ford Reference Ford, Hopkins and Sides2015; Munzert and Bauer Reference Munzert and Bauer2013; Wolf and Roßteutscher Reference Wolf and Roßteutscher2013). Some studies use aggregate data (Dalton Reference Dalton2008; Siaroff and Merer Reference Siaroff and Merer2002; Steiner and Martin Reference Steiner and Martin2012) and the few comparative studies based on individual data are limited in scope, as they focus exclusively on (Western) European countries (Kleiner Reference Kleiner2016, Reference Kleiner2018; Lachat Reference Lachat2008; Moral Reference Moral2017). Hence, this is one of the first truly comparative accounts of the impact of polarization on voter turnout worldwide (most recently Dassonneville and Çakır Reference Dassonneville, Çakır and Dalton2021; see also Lupu Reference Lupu2015 or Ezrow et al. Reference Ezrow, Tavits and Homola2014, but both with a focus on partisanship). The original data set contains information on 144,381 respondents from 95 election studies in 47 countries; 11 additional studies were excluded as their questionnaires lacked decisive questions.Footnote 2 Belarus (2008) was also dropped because most candidates were not affiliated with any party. On the individual level, we excluded respondents with missing values on the dependent or core predictor variables. As a result, the analyses are based on 88,397 individuals from 84 election studies in 43 countries (see Table A1 in the Supplementary Material for final case numbers per country and election year included in this study).Footnote 3

The dependent variable is a dummy that differentiates between respondents who self-reported either participating in (1) or abstaining from (0) the election. Our main predictor variables are the two measures of polarization: party-system polarization and individual perceptions of party differences. There are several options for measuring polarization.Footnote 4 We decided in favour of the formula developed by Russell Dalton (Reference Dalton2008; similar Ezrow Reference Ezrow2008; Lupu Reference Lupu2015). First, it integrates parties' positions on the left–right continuum and accounts for party size (see also Esteban and Ray Reference Esteban and Ray1994; Van der Meer et al. Reference Van der Meer, van Deth and Scheepers2009). We believe that it makes a difference in terms of the degree of polarization whether parties at the extreme poles of the ideological spectrum are tiny or large (Alvarez and Nagler Reference Alvarez and Nagler2004; Dassonneville and Çakır Reference Dassonneville, Çakır and Dalton2021; Ezrow and Xezonakis Reference Ezrow and Xezonakis2011). Vice versa, the size of centre parties is also crucial. If centre parties encompass a majority of the popular vote, party systems are less polarized even if there are niche parties at the extremes (see also Lupu Reference Lupu2015; Moral Reference Moral2017). By contrast, if extreme parties are large and centre parties are negligible in terms of voter support, a party system is heavily polarized. Second, unlike measures based on the mean absolute differences between parties, this model does not suffer from biases originating from differences in the absolute number of parties (Schmitt and Franzmann Reference Schmitt and Franzmann2017). Finally, it accounts for parties in the ideological centre of a party system, in contrast to measures based on the ideological range of a party system or the mere number of – subjectively defined – extreme parties (e.g. Abedi Reference Abedi2002; Crepaz Reference Crepaz1990).Footnote 5 Among the marginally different calculation formulas available that acknowledge dispersion and size, all produce highly similar results (see Moral Reference Moral2017 for a comparison). The formula thus is as follows:Footnote 6

$$\eqalign{{\rm Party\ System\ Polarization} = & {\rm \;SQRT} \bigg \{{\sum ( {{\rm party\ vote\ shar}{\rm e}_i} ) } \cr & \quad\times {( [ {{\rm party}\;L/R\;{\rm scor}{\rm e}_i} } \cr & \quad{{ { {- {\rm \;weighted\ party\ system\ average}\;L/R\;{\rm score}} ] /5} ) }^2} \bigg \} , \; } $$

where i represents individual parties.

The measure of individual perceptions of party differentiation builds on individual perceptions of party positions. All respondents were asked to position their country's parties on the left–right continuum. We thus calculate an individual score of perceived party differences for each respondent. Although there are more dimensions that organize party competition,Footnote 7 the left–right measure is still the most general measure of party conflict that encompasses, at least partially, other potentially important divides (see, e.g. Freire Reference Freire2008; Fuchs and Klingemann Reference Fuchs, Klingemann and Jennings1990; Huber Reference Huber1989; Knutsen Reference Knutsen1995; Roßteutscher and Scherer Reference Roßteutscher, Scherer, Weßels, Schoen and Gabriel2013). Moreover, it is the only dimension for which expert and individual party ratings are available. Respondents could not always position every party, and there were particularly high rates of missing values for the smaller parties. Hence, we consider only parties with a vote share of 4% or more.Footnote 8 Note that we decided against imputing mean values because we assume that parties that individuals cannot rate are also not part of their choice set.Footnote 9 All respondents with only one or no single party estimate were dropped from the analyses. Since there is no measure of perceived party size available, we used the relative vote shares of the positioned parties. As CSES surveys are conducted directly after an election, we assume that respondents possess a fairly correct idea about the relative strength of their national parties. That said, using an index formula with unweighted party positions yielded identical results (see section on robustness below).Footnote 10 Hence our findings are independent of whether this assumption holds or not.

As we argue above, party-system polarization is essentially different from individual perceptions of party differences. Due to a lack of independent sources, scholars often use the aggregated individual perceptions as a measure of system polarization.Footnote 11 We believe this is a poor idea because individuals draw on different, hardly comparable, sources to estimate their parties (Lupu Reference Lupu2015: 338; Rogowski Reference Rogowski2014: 481). Country means only reflect a valid measure of system polarization if most individuals share a minimal understanding of party positions. If, however, some believe that party differences are large, while others think there are no differences, the mean value hardly reflects reality. Such differences emerge naturally if individuals' perceptions of party differences are based on the very diverse and idiosyncratic sources spelled out above. Moreover, if the perception of party differences is systematically related to other theoretically relevant variables, aggregation may simply produce a distorted measure. This is exactly the case here. Individual perceptions of party differences correlate positively with extreme positions on the ideological scale (Pearson's r = 0.27, p < 0.001) and partisanship (strong partisanship r = 0.15, p < 0.001, weak partisanship r = 0.06, p < 0.001; no partisanship r = −0.16, p < 0.001).Footnote 12 In short, country means are highly dependent on the distribution of these characteristics in the respective sample.Footnote 13

Therefore, to arrive at a measure of party-system polarization, we refer to the expert ratings obtained by CSES (see also Lupu Reference Lupu2015). The experts include the members of the consortium or the academic project team responsible for data collection in a given country, who, like respondents, were asked to position their country's political parties on the left–right continuum. These experts, all of them scholars of political science and electoral research, are politically highly sophisticated and, we assume, closely familiar with the state of their respective party system. Hence, the expert ratings are used as an exogenous measure of party-system polarization – that is, all respondents in a given country/election year are coded with an identical party-system polarization score based on the country's expert ratings.Footnote 14

Applying the Dalton formula to both, we now have an expert measure for party-system polarization and an individual measure for the subjective perception of party differences (for distributions see Figures A3 and A4 in the Supplementary Material). Hypothetically, the two measures stretch from 0 (all parties on the exact same spot of the left–right continuum) to 10 (two identically large parties positioned at the extremes).

With regard to our core independent variables on the individual level, we distinguish moderate voters (self-assessed 4, 5, 6 on the 0 to 10 left–right scale) from extreme voters (0–3 and 7–10).Footnote 15 We further differentiate between non-partisans, those who weakly identify with a party (‘leaners’), and those who strongly identify with a party, by constructing three corresponding dummy variables. Based on the rich literature on turnout (e.g. Abendschön and Roßteutscher Reference Abendschön, Roßteutscher, Poguntke, Roßteutscher, Schmitt-Beck and Zmerli2015; Armingeon and Schädel Reference Armingeon and Schädel2015; Franklin Reference Franklin2004; Gallego Reference Gallego2015; Leighley and Nagler Reference Leighley and Nagler2014; Lijphart Reference Lijphart1997; Schäfer et al. Reference Schäfer, Roßteutscher and Abendschön2020), we include the following variables as controls because we know that they also explain electoral participation: we use educational levels as a proxy for political sophistication, since no better suited variables are available.Footnote 16 We distinguish those who have completed higher education (upper secondary or higher), coded as 1, from those with less than upper secondary education (0). We differentiate first-time voters (depending on voting age regulations, i.e. roughly 21 or younger), from more experienced voters (coded 0). Further, we include age in years, gender (1 for male, 0 for women), current employment status (1 for unemployed, 0 for not unemployed), satisfaction with democracy measured on a scale ranging from 1 ‘not at all satisfied’ to 4 ‘very satisfied’ and individual self-placement on the left–right scale (0 to 10). All continuous variables are z-transformed.

On the country level, we control for the share of moderate and non-partisan citizens – that is, the relative share of the electorate in a given country that self-assesses as a 4, 5, or 6 on the left–right scale and the relative share that claims to be unaffiliated to a party, respectively (for distributions see Figures A8 and A9 in the Supplementary Material). As further control variables, we include election year and, from the World Bank, the general unemployment rate and the GDP per capita one year before the election. Democratic regime age is extracted from the Polity IV project to account for the possibility that long-standing democracies have higher (or lower) turnout. To control for party-system fragmentation, we include the Corrected Effective Number of Electoral Parties (Taagepera Reference Taagepera1997). As voting is compulsory in some of the countries, we include a binary variable for enforced compulsory voting schemes. Finally, to account for the fact that survey data are heavily biased with regard to turnout because of over-reporting and selection bias in particular (Sciarini and Goldberg Reference Sciarini and Goldberg2016), we include a macro-level variable that represents the difference between aggregated turnout based on survey responses and the officially registered turnout.Footnote 17 All continuous variables were once again z-transformed. To account for the multilevel data structure and the nature of the dichotomous dependent variable, we subsequently conduct multilevel logistic regressions with two levels – the individual and the election level. Although our main interest is in the hypothetically divergent impact of party-system polarization and the subjectively perceived party differences (H1 and H2), our further hypotheses call for interaction terms: between individually perceived party differences and moderate/non-partisan positions (H3) and party-system polarization and moderate/non-partisan positions (H4). Table A2 in the Supplementary Material describes all of the variables involved.

Empirical findings

We claim that party-system polarization and individual perceptions of party differences are conceptually and empirically distinct. The correlation between political polarization based on expert ratings and individual (not aggregated) perceptions of party differences is very low (Pearson's r = 0.17, p < 0.001, see also Figures A3–A5 in the Supplementary Material for the correlation and univariate distributions).Footnote 18 Hence, operationalizing polarization by aggregating country means reveals very distinct results compared to expert judgements. Thus, aggregating individual perceptions is a suboptimal measure of system polarization. We subsequently use the expert ratings as an exogenous measure of party-system polarization.

Now we test our hypotheses with multivariate analyses. Table A7 (in the Supplementary Material) presents the full model estimates. First, we present a main effects model and then test our hypotheses based on interaction terms. As for the main effects hypotheses (H1 and H2), both are statistically and substantially significant. Party-system polarization depresses turnout (odds ratio of 0.78**), but an individual's perception of party differences increases the likelihood of voting (odds ratio of 1.21***). Figure 1 presents the probabilities of individual turnout (a) under the condition of party-system polarization and (b) under the condition of individually perceived party differences.

Figure 1. Direct Turnout Effect of Party System Polarization (Left) and Individuals' Perceptions of Party Differences (Right) with 95% Confidence Intervals

Note: x-axis scale units denote changes in standard deviation from mean.

In both instances, the effect size is not trivial and, as assumed, it runs in different directions. In the case of low party-system polarization (left panel), turnout rates are more than 90%, compared to a maximally polarized system where turnout is roughly 12 percentage points lower.Footnote 19 In terms of individual perceptions of party differences, the probability of turnout changes by about 10%, depending on an individual's ability to perceive clear party differences. Hence, system polarization relates to lower turnout and individual difference perceptions correlate with higher participation.Footnote 20 Other variables in the model (see M1 in Table A7) reveal that moderate citizens have a lower turnout rate than extreme citizens (see also Dassonneville and Çakır Reference Dassonneville, Çakır and Dalton2021) – and there is no difference between a left-leaning and a right-leaning respondent (for similar findings, see Van der Meer et al. Reference Van der Meer, van Deth and Scheepers2009: 1439). We also find that partisans vote at much higher rates than non-partisans. Moreover, as an electorate's share of moderate citizens increases, so too does abstention; as the share of non-partisans increases, so too does the turnout.Footnote 21 As for our controls, evidence confirms the results of turnout research. Education increases turnout and newly enfranchised cohorts tend to abstain. Older citizens vote at higher rates, while unemployment decreases participation, and there is no gender gap. However, satisfaction with democracy exerts clear positive effects. Looking at macro-level controls, neither regime age, GDP per capita, unemployment rate, turnout over-reporting nor survey year impact electoral participation. Compulsory voting exerts a strong positive effect and the corrected effective number of electoral parties a negative effect.

In H3, we expected that difference perceptions would increase turnout among all voters – moderate and extreme voters, partisans and non-partisans alike. Figure 2 displays the interaction between difference perceptions moderated by individual ideological position and partisanship (see Table A7, Models M2 and M3). Looking at individuals' ideological positions (left panel in Figure 2), extreme citizens always show a slightly higher turnout rate than moderates. Note, however, that confidence intervals overlap. Hence, this difference is not statistically significant. However, in both groups, turnout increases continuously with higher difference perceptions. The change in turnout probability amounts to roughly 10 percentage points, comparing citizens with the lowest and the highest difference perceptions. Turning to partisanship (right panel in Figure 2), non-partisans benefit more from increasing difference perceptions (an increase in turnout of about 11 percentage points) than partisans. Note, however, that partisans, particularly those who identify strongly, turn out at very high rates either way. Even those who perceive no differences whatsoever have a turnout rate close to 90%.

Figure 2. The Effect of Perceived Party Differences by Moderate/Extreme Position (Left) and Different Levels of Partisanship (Right) with 95% Confidence Intervals

Note: x-axis scale units denote changes in standard deviation from mean.

Identifying with a party is a sufficient motivation for voting (for similar findings, see Lachat Reference Lachat2008: 694), and because of ceiling effects, difference perceptions can only moderately increase partisans' turnout rates. In summary, increases in perceptions of differences between parties increase turnout among all citizens alike, as predicted in H3.

Subsequently, we test our hypotheses concerning the moderating effects of party-system polarization. H4 assumes that system polarization decreases turnout among moderates and non-partisans (compared to extreme citizens and partisans). Figure 3 visualizes the interaction effects from the multilevel logistic regression (see models M4 and M5 in Table A7). Beginning with ideological positions (left panel), both moderates and extremists have the highest predicted turnout (above 90%) when system polarization is low. Turnout decreases steadily with increasing levels of polarization. Despite being true for both groups, the turnout decline is stronger among moderates. Turnout declines among moderates by 15 percentage points when comparing a party system with the lowest polarization level to one with the highest polarization level. Among extreme citizens, the decrease amounts to roughly 10 percentage points. The difference between both groups is statistically significant, yet confidence intervals overlap (see model M4 in Table A7). Party-system polarization suppresses turnout in both groups, but to a much lower degree among extremists than moderates.

Figure 3. The Effect of Party System Polarization by Moderate/Extreme Position (Left) and Levels of Partisanship (Right) with 95% Confidence Intervals

Note: x-axis scale units denote changes in standard deviation from mean.

A different picture emerges for partisanship (right panel). Strong partisans remain unaffected by system polarization. In every constellation, their turnout is clearly above 90%. By contrast, persons with weak party identification react to increasing system polarization with declining turnout. However, the decline is modest (clearly above 90% to slightly below 90%) compared to non-partisans. When party-system polarization is low, non-partisans vote at a rate of 88% – that is, with only slightly lower levels than both partisan groups. From low to high levels of system polarization, their turnout rate decreases by about ten percentage points. Hence, hostile party environments lead non-partisans to disengage, while partisans are unaffected by centrist party systems. Although Figure 3 tells a rather clear story, this effect is statistically insignificant (model M5 in Table A7), hence we cannot be certain that our hypothesis is confirmed.

Robustness

To verify whether our results are robust, we tested alternatives concerning case selection, variable construction and model estimation. To address case selection, we reran the models with five specifications: (1) excluding systems with compulsory voting schemesFootnote 22 (for the results see Table A10 in the Supplementary Material); (2) excluding non-OECD countries (see Table A11); (3) excluding two-party systems (see Table A12); (4) excluding party-system polarization outliers – that is, with index values lower than 2 and higher than 6Footnote 23 (see Table A13) – and (5) excluding countries that Freedom House rates either non-free or partially free (i.e. with a score above 2.5)Footnote 24 (see Table A14). On the variable level, we model seven variants: (1) we include parties with a vote share of above 2% (instead of 4%) (see Table A15); (2) we impute means for missing individuals' party ratings (compared to treating them as missing values) (see Table A16); (3) we operationalize ‘moderateness’ on a continuum (instead of the dummy variable) (see Table A17); (4) we use polarization indices unweighted by party size (see Table A18); (5) we use the ideological distance between the most extreme parties as polarization indices (see Table A19); (6) we use aggregated perceived party differences as a party-system polarization measure (see Table A20); and (7) we use our party-system polarization measure but control for aggregated perceived party differences (see Table A21). Regarding model estimation, we rerun the analyses using election-fixed effects (see Table A22) and country-fixed effects (see Table A23). Table 1 summarizes the results.

Table 1. Robustness Checks

Note: x indicates the confirmation of the hypothesis. +Indicates p < 0.1 significance level.

Regarding the main effects of system polarization and individual difference perceptions (H1 and H2), which are this article's focus, every possible variant results in identical findings: strongly depressing effects of system polarization and strong positive effects of perceived party differences. Hence, our core hypotheses concerning the divergent impact of those two conceptually distinct aspects are highly robust. The same applies to our assumption regarding the participatory impact of perceived party differences among all groups of an electorate (H3), although the effect is significantly smaller for strong partisans than for non-partisans in some instances. Regarding the cross-level interaction between system polarization and moderate and non-partisan citizens (H4), robustness checks support our results. The significant effect of moderateness holds in nine out of fourteen model specifications; the non-significant effect of partisanship repeats in all but one of the models. Thus, H4 is confirmed for moderateness but rejected for partisanship.Footnote 25

Conclusion

This article aims to show that party-system polarization, on the one hand, and individuals' perceptions of party differences, on the other, are two conceptually and empirically distinct phenomena that impact individual turnout differently. Most citizens, particularly if they are ideologically moderate and non-partisan, are disengaged by hostile party positions, negative campaigning and party elites who prohibit compromise. Hence, under party-system polarization, turnout is relatively low. By contrast, if individuals perceive differences between parties, the likelihood is great that, among these parties, one is closer to their views than the others. In this constellation, electoral outcomes are relevant to an individual and, hence, turnout is relatively high. Perceptions of party differences may be caused by party-system polarization. However, many other reasons exist as to why some individuals perceive differences and others do not – ranging from socialization heritage, candidates' images, specific issues and private networks to simple misconceptions. As we demonstrated, the perception of differences between parties increases turnout among all citizens, including ideological moderates and extremists, as well as partisans and non-partisans. However, party-system polarization exerts depressing effects on electoral participation, particularly among moderates and non-partisans. By contrast, more extreme citizens and especially partisans are unaffected by system polarization; they participate in elections regardless – even in centrist party systems (for similar findings, see, e.g. Putnam Reference Putnam2000: 342; Van der Meer et al. Reference Van der Meer, van Deth and Scheepers2009: 1430). Extreme positions and, in particular, strong partisanship are sufficient motives for participation (Lachat Reference Lachat2008).

That said, our findings are based on cross-sectional data and, hence, we cannot capture dynamic aspects of polarization. For instance, the results do not reveal whether partisans have a temporal limit of tolerance. How long do they endure a party system that neglects their extreme and partisan attitudes? We also do not know whether moderates in heavily polarized systems tend to develop more extreme positions and, in the longer run, join the competing camps, as suggested by Alan Abramowitz (Reference Abramowitz2010), Jeff Stonecash (Reference Stonecash, Hopkins and Sides2015) or Lilliana Mason (Reference Mason, Hopkins and Sides2015). This limitation also implies important methodological issues as there is a possible non-equivalence between cross-sectional and longitudinal relationships and concerns about causality and omitted variable bias (see, for example, Fairbrother Reference Fairbrother2014; Schmidt-Catran and Fairbrother Reference Schmidt-Catran and Fairbrother2016). Lacking comparative panel data, however, we conclude, for the time being, that unpolarized party systems provide the best conditions for high turnout. Such systems coincide with the demand of moderates and non-partisans (who represent large fractions of the electorate) and deter neither extremists nor partisans from voting. Future research should address whether centrist party systems with high shares of extreme and partisan citizens lead to changing party positions or the emergence of new parties at the ideological fringes in the longer run.

To end on a more methodological note, constructing a metric for party-system polarization from the aggregated means of individually perceived ideological differences between the parties in a country is inferior to exogenous measures and may produce misleading results that contribute to the unsatisfactory state of current polarization research. This is the case because the perceptions do not mirror party-system polarization, but rather individuals' impressions of whether there are parties close to their views and others further away. As we argue above, such individual perceptions may be due to several factors, of which party-system polarization is only one. Hence, aggregated means represent the average perceptions of differences (whatever the source) – and not of system polarization. Although it was beyond the scope of this article, future studies will have to examine the sources of individual perceptions of party differences.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2023.43.

Acknowledgements

This research did not receive any specific grant from funding agencies in the public, commercial or not-for-profit sectors.

Footnotes

1 Earlier waves differ in partisanship measures.

2 Perceived party positions are unavailable for Taiwan 2012. Respondents' positions are unavailable for Thailand 2011. Satisfaction with democracy is unavailable for Argentina 2015 and Chile 2009. Partisanship strength is unavailable for Finland 2015, Ireland 2011 and Kenya 2013. Unemployment is unavailable for Brazil 2006. Corrected Effective Number of Electoral Parties is unavailable for France 2012 and Romania 2014. See model composition below.

3 In the sample there are 13 countries with one election study, 20 countries with two election studies, nine countries with three election studies and one country with four election studies. To account for the country level we reran the analyses with country-fixed effects (see section on robustness below).

4 Schmitt and Franzmann (Reference Schmitt and Franzmann2017) count 210 different variants.

5 We nonetheless reran all analyses with the polarization index unweighted by party size, and with the ideological distance between the most extreme parties in a party system. The measures yield identical results (see section on robustness below).

6 We do not use the party vote share in relation to all votes. Instead, we use the vote share in relation to votes given to all parties for which we account. This is necessary to achieve a valid comparable measure.

7 Examples are the authoritarian–libertarian (Flanagan Reference Flanagan1987), materialist–postmaterialist (Inglehart Reference Inglehart1990) and more recently winners–losers of globalization (Kriesi et al. Reference Kriesi, Grande, Lachat, Dolezal, Bornschier and Frey2006) or the national–cosmopolitan (Hooghe and Marks Reference Hooghe and Marks2018) divides.

8 We reran all analyses with a 2% threshold yielding identical results (see robustness section below).

9 Using imputed mean party positions yielded identical results (see robustness section below).

10 We reran all analyses with a perceived party-differences measure unweighted by party size and with a measure of perceived ideological distance between the most extreme parties and the individual-level standard deviation of perceived party positions. Both measures yield identical results (see robustness section below).

11 Even authors who distinguish between factual party-system polarization and individual perceptions rely on aggregated individual data (see e.g. Enders and Armaly Reference Enders and Armaly2019; Lupu Reference Lupu2015; Moral Reference Moral2017).

12 At the same time, the distribution of perceived differences in each group features high variance.

13 See Westfall et al. (Reference Westfall, van Boven, Chambers and Judd2015) and Levendusky and Malhotra (Reference Levendusky and Malhotra2016) for similar findings.

14 Possible alternatives such as expert ratings analyses based on election manifestos provide data for a much smaller subset of countries.

15 We use the proximity to the central point on the left–right scale as an alternative operationalization and yield identical results (see robustness section).

16 CSES does not include political interest measures and political knowledge is not comparable across countries. Indeed, after wave 4, the CSES consortium decided to remove political knowledge from the questionnaire (Gidengil and Zechmeister Reference Gidengil and Zechmeister2016). We also tested the correct estimation of the ideological order of the party system's two largest parties as an alternative to education. The results remained unchanged.

17 The difference is lowest in Spain 2008 (4%) and highest in Mexico 2015 (43%). The average deviation is 19%.

18 The correlation between the aggregated perceived party differences and the party-system polarization based on expert ratings is positive but far from perfect (Pearson's r = 0.45, p < 0.001; see Figure A6 in the Supplementary Material, see also Lupu Reference Lupu2015 for similar findings).

19 Excluding extreme cases yields identical results (see robustness section below).

20 Including an interaction term between party-system polarization and perceived party differences, we find that perceived differences boost turnout probability from 70 to 85% in highly polarized systems while difference perceptions do not increase turnout in hardly polarized polities. We attribute this difference to ceiling effects, since, in hardly polarized systems, turnout probability is above 90% even among citizens who do not see any differences between parties.

21 This effect disappears when individual-level partisanship is excluded.

22 Australia 2007 and 2013, Brazil 2010 and 2014, Peru 2011 and 2016, Thailand 2007, Turkey 2011 and 2015, Uruguay 2009.

23 System polarization lower than 2: Germany 2009, Romania 2009, Thailand 2007, Taiwan 2008. System polarization higher than 6: Czech Republic 2006 and 2010, Montenegro 2012.

24 Partially free: Hong Kong 2008 and 2012, Mexico 2012 and 2015, Philippines 2010 and 2016, Turkey 2011 and 2015. Not free: Thailand 2007.

25 In addition to these robustness checks, we also tested whether the results are conditional on political sophistication. To this end, we first reran the analyses in subsets divided by educational level and second tested interaction effects regarding education level and the two polarization measures. We then used a political sophistication measure that builds on the correct ideological ranking of the party system's two main parties and reran the analyses with the correct ranking measure as control variable. Fourth, we reran the analyses in subsets divided by this correct ranking measure. The results show that our results are robust and largely independent from political sophistication. For more details on these additional analyses, see A24 in the Supplementary Material.

References

Abedi, A (2002) Challenges to Established Parties: The Effects of Party System Features on the Electoral Fortunes of Anti-Political-Establishment Parties. European Journal of Political Research 41(4), 551583. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.t01-1-00022.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abendschön, S and Roßteutscher, S (2015) Political Socialization and Inequality: The Role of Primary Schools. In Poguntke, T, Roßteutscher, S, Schmitt-Beck, R and Zmerli, S (eds), Citizenship and Democracy in an Era of Crisis. London: Routledge, pp. 135154.Google Scholar
Abramowitz, AI (2010) The Disappearing Center: Engaged Citizens, Polarization, and American Democracy. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Abramowitz, AI (2013) The Polarized Public? Why American Government Is So Dysfunctional. Boston, MA: Pearson Education.Google Scholar
Abramowitz, AI (2015) How Race and Religion Have Polarized American Voters. In Hopkins, DJ and Sides, J (eds), Political Polarization in American Politics. New York: Bloomsbury, pp. 8087.Google Scholar
Abramowitz, AI and Stone, WJ (2006) The Bush Effect: Polarization, Turnout, and Activism in the 2004 Presidential Election. Presidential Studies Quarterly 36(2), 141154. http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1741-5705.2006.00295.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adams, J, Ezrow, L and Somer-Topcu, Z (2011) Is Anybody Listening? Evidence That Voters Do Not Respond to European Parties’ Policy Statements during Elections. American Journal of Political Science 55(2), 370382. http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2010.00489.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvarez, R and Nagler, J (2004) Party System Compactness: Measurement and Consequences. Political Analysis 12(1), 4662. https://doi.org/10.1093/pan/mph003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anduiza, E, Guinjoan, M and Rico, G (2019) Populism, Participation, and Political Equality. European Political Science Review 11(1), 109124. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1755773918000243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansolabehere, SD and Iyengar, S (1997) Going Negative: How Political Advertisements Shrink and Polarize the Electorate. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, SD, Iyengar, S, Adam, A and Valentino, N (1994) Does Attack Advertising Demobilize the Electorate? American Political Science Review 88(4), 829838. https://doi.org/10.2307/2082710.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansolabehere, SD, Iyengar, S and Simon, A (1999) Replicating Experiments Using Aggregate and Survey Data: The Case of Negative Advertising and Turnout. American Political Science Review 93(4), 901909. https://doi.org/10.2307/2586120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armingeon, K and Schädel, L (2015) Social Inequality in Political Participation: The Dark Sides of Individualisation. West European Politics 38(1), 127. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2014.929341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bischof, D and Wagner, M (2019) Do Voters Polarize When Radical Parties Enter Parliament? American Journal of Political Science 63(4), 888904. https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12449.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blais, A, Singh, S and Dumitrescu, D (2014) Political Institutions, Perceptions of Representation, and the Turnout Decision. In Thomassen, J (ed.), Elections and Democracy: Representation and Accountability. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 99112.10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198716334.003.0006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carsey, T and Layman, G (2015) Our Politics Is Polarized on More Issues than Ever Before. In Hopkins, DJ and Sides, J (eds), Political Polarization in American Politics. New York: Bloomsbury, pp. 2331.Google Scholar
Crepaz, MML (1990) The Impact of Party Polarization and Postmaterialism on Voter Turnout: A Comparative Study of 16 Industrial Democracies. European Journal of Political Research 18(2), 183205. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.1990.tb00228.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dalton, RJ (2008) The Quantity and the Quality of Party Systems: Party System Polarization, Its Measurement, and Its Consequences. Comparative Political Studies 41(7), 899920. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414008315860.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dassonneville, R and Çakır, S (2021) Party System Polarization and Electoral Behavior. In Dalton, R (ed.), Oxford Research Encyclopedia in Politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Downs, A (1957a) An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Downs, A (1957b) An Economic Theory of Political Action in a Democracy. Journal of Political Economy 65(2), 135150. https://doi.org/10.1086/257897.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellger, F (2023) The Mobilizing Effect of Party System Polarization. Evidence in Europe. Comparative Political Studies, published online, September, 129. https://doi.org/10.1177/00104140231194059.Google Scholar
Enders, AM and Armaly, MT (2019) The Differential Effects of Actual and Perceived Polarization. Political Behavior 41, 815839. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-018-9476-2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Esteban, J-M and Ray, D (1994) On the Measurement of Polarization. Econometrica 62(4), 819851. https://doi.org/10.2307/2951734.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ezrow, L (2008) Parties’ Policy Programmes and the Dog That Didn't Bark: No Evidence That Proportional Systems Promote Extreme Party Positioning. British Journal of Political Science 38(3), 479497. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123408000240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ezrow, L and Xezonakis, G (2011) Citizen Satisfaction with Democracy and Parties’ Policy Offerings. Comparative Political Studies 44(9), 11521178. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414011405461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ezrow, L, Tavits, M and Homola, J (2014) Voter Polarization, Strength of Partisanship, and Support for Extremist Parties. Comparative Political Studies 47(11), 15581583. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414013512605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fairbrother, M (2014) Two Multilevel Modeling Techniques for Analyzing Comparative Longitudinal Survey Datasets. Political Science Research and Methods 2(1), 119140. https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2013.24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorina, MP, Abrams, SJ and Pope, JC (2005) Culture War? The Myth of Polarized America. New York: Pearson Longman.Google Scholar
Flanagan, SC (1987) Value Change in Industrial Societies. American Political Science Review 81(4), 13031319. https://doi.org/10.2307/1962590.Google Scholar
Ford, R (2015) In Britain, Polarization Could be the Solution. In Hopkins, DJ and Sides, J (eds), Political Polarization in American Politics. New York: Bloomsbury, pp. 126134.Google Scholar
Franklin, MN (2004) Voter Turnout and the Dynamics of Electoral Competition in Established Democracies since 1945. New York: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511616884CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freire, A (2008) Party Polarization and Citizens’ Left–Right Orientations. Party Politics 14(2), 189209. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068807085889.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fuchs, D and Klingemann, H-D (1990) The Left–Right Schema. In Jennings, MK et al. (eds), Continuities in Political Action: A Longitudinal Study of Political Orientations in Three Western Democracies. Berlin and New York: Walter de Gruyter, pp. 203234.10.1515/9783110882193.203CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gallego, A (2015) Unequal Political Participation Worldwide. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gidengil, E and Zechmeister, E (2016) The Tough Decision to Remove Political Knowledge from the CSES Module 5. CSES blog, 6 December, https://cses.org/2016/12/06/the-tough-decision-to-remove-political-knowledge-from-the-cses-module-5/.Google Scholar
Hetherington, MJ (2008) Turned Off or Turned On? How Polarization Affects Political Engagement. In Nivola, PS and Brady, DW (eds), Red and Blue Nation? Consequences and Correction of America's Polarized Politics. Harrisonburg, VA: Brookings Institution Press, pp. 154.Google Scholar
Hetherington, MJ (2009) Putting Polarization in Perspective. British Journal of Political Science 39(2), 413448. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123408000501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobolt, SB and Hoerner, JM (2020) The Mobilizing Effect of Political Choice. European Journal of Political Research 59(2), 229247. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hooghe, L and Marks, G (2018) Cleavage Theory Meets Europe's Crises: Lipset, Rokkan, and the Transnational Cleavage. Journal of European Public Policy 25(1), 109135. https://doi.org/10.1080/13501763.2017.1310279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, JD (1989) Values and Partisanship in Left–Right Orientations: Measuring Ideology. European Journal of Political Research 17, 599621. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.1989.tb00209.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, RA and Ruth, SP (2017) Mind the Gap! Populism, Participation and Representation in Europe. Swiss Political Science Review 23(4), 462484. https://doi.org/10.1111/spsr.12280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hunter, JD (1991) Culture Wars: The Struggle to Define America. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Immerzeel, T and Pickup, M (2015) Populist Radical Right Parties Mobilizing ‘the People’? The Role of Populist Radical Right Success in Voter Turnout. Electoral Studies 40, 347360. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.electstud.2015.10.007.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Inglehart, R (1990) Culture Shift in Advanced Industrial Society. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9780691186740CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacoby, WG (2014) Is There a Culture War? Conflicting Value Structures in American Public Opinion. American Political Science Review 108(4), 754771. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055414000380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kenyon, T (2014) False Polarization: Debiasing as Applied Social Epistemology. Synthese 191(11), 25292547. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11229-014-0438-x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Key, VO (1966) The Responsible Electorate: Rationality in Presidential Voting, 1936–1960. New Haven: Belknap Press.10.4159/harvard.9780674497764CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleiner, T-M (2016) Führt Polarisierung zu politischen Engagement? Swiss Political Science Review 22(3), 353384. https://doi.org/10.1111/spsr.12215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleiner, T-M (2018) Public Opinion and Protest Behavior. European Journal of Political Research 57(4), 941962. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knutsen, O (1995) Value Orientations, Political Conflicts and Left–Right Identification: A Comparative Study. European Journal of Political Research 28, 6393. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.1995.tb00487.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kriesi, H, Grande, E, Lachat, R, Dolezal, M, Bornschier, S and Frey, T (2006) Globalization and the Transformation of the National Political Space: Six European Countries Compared. European Journal of Political Research 45(6), 921956. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.2006.00644.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lachat, R (2008) The Impact of Party Polarization on Ideological Voting. Electoral Studies 27, 687698. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.electstud.2008.06.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M and Hunt, B (1992) Party and Policy Competition. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Layman, GC and Carsey, TM (2002) Party Polarization and ‘Conflict Extension’ in the American Electorate. American Journal of Political Science 46(4), 786802. https://doi.org/10.2307/3088434.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leighley, JE and Nagler, J (2014) Who Votes How? Demographics, Issues, Inequality, and Turnout. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Leininger, A and Meijers, MJ (2021) Do Populist Parties Increase Voter Turnout? Evidence from over 40 Years of Electoral History in 31 European Democracies. Political Studies 69(3), 665685. https://doi.org/10.1177/0032321720923257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levendusky, MS (2010) Clearer Cues, More Consistent Voters: A Benefit of Elite Polarization. Political Behavior 32, 111131. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-009-9094-0.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levendusky, MS and Malhotra, N (2016) (Mis)Perceptions of Partisan Polarization in the American Public. Public Opinion Quarterly 80(Special Issue), 378391. https://doi.org/10.1093/poq/nfv045.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, A (1997) Unequal Participation: Democracy's Unresolved Dilemma. American Political Science Review 91(1), 114. https://doi.org/10.2307/2952255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipset, SM, Lazarsfeld, PF, Barton, AH and Linz, J (1954) The Psychology of Voting: An Analysis of Political Behaviour. In Lindzey, G (ed.), Handbook of Social Psychology. Cambridge: Addison-Wesley, pp. 2645.Google Scholar
Lupu, N (2015) Party Polarization and Mass Partisanship: A Comparative Perspective. Political Behavior 37, 331356. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-014-9279-z.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mason, L (2015) Party Polarization Is Making Us More Prejudiced. In Hopkins, DJ and Sides, J (eds), Political Polarization in American Politics. New York: Bloomsbury, pp. 5560.Google Scholar
McCarty, N (2015) What We Know and Do Not Know about Our Polarized Politics. In Hopkins, DJ and Sides, J (eds), Political Polarization in American Politics. New York: Bloomsbury, pp. 18.Google Scholar
Moral, M (2017) The Bipolar Voter: On the Effects of Actual and Perceived Party Polarization on Voter Turnout in European Multiparty Democracies. Political Behavior 39, 935965. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-016-9386-0.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mudde, C and Rovira Kaltwasser, C (2012) Populism and (Liberal) Democracy: A Framework for Analysis. In Mudde, C and Kaltwasser, CR (eds), Populism in Europe and the Americas: Threat or Corrective for Democracy? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 126.10.1017/CBO9781139152365CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Munzert, S and Bauer, PC (2013) Political Depolarization in German Public Opinion 1980–2010. Political Science Research and Methods 1(1), 6789. https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2013.7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, R (2000) Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Rapp, C (2016) Moral Opinion Polarization and the Erosion of Trust. Social Science Research 58, 3445. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2016.02.008.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rogowski, JC (2014) Electoral Choice, Ideological Conflict, and Political Participation. American Journal of Political Science 58(2), 479494. https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12059.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roßteutscher, S and Scherer, P (2013) Links und Rechts im politischen Raum: Eine vergleichende Analyse der ideologischen Entwicklung in Ost- und Westdeutschland. In Weßels, B, Schoen, H and Gabriel, OW (eds), Wahlen und Wähler: Analysen aus Anlass der Bundestagswahl 2009. Wiesbaden: Springer VS, pp. 380406.10.1007/978-3-658-01328-8_17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sani, G and Sartori, G (1983) Polarization, Fragmentation and Competition in Western Democracies. In Daalder, H and Mair, P (eds), Western European Party Systems: Continuity and Change. Beverly Hills: Sage, pp. 95133.Google Scholar
Schäfer, C and Debus, M (2018) No Participation without Representation: Policy Distances and Abstention in European Parliament Elections. Journal of European Public Policy 25(12), 18351854. https://doi.org/10.1080/13501763.2017.1363806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schäfer, A, Roßteutscher, S and Abendschön, S (2020) Rising Start-up Costs of Voting: Political Inequality among First-Time Voters. West European Politics 43(4), 819844. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2019.1638141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt-Catran, AW and Fairbrother, M (2016) The Random Effects in Multilevel Models: Getting Them Wrong and Getting Them Right. European Sociological Review 32(1), 2338. https://doi.org/10.1093/esr/jcv090.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitt, J and Franzmann, ST (2017) Measuring Ideological Polarization in Party Systems: An Evaluation of the Concept and the Indicators. Paper prepared for the EPSA Annual Conference.Google Scholar
Schmitt, H and Freire, A (2012) Ideological Polarization: Different Worlds in East and West. In Sanders, D, Magalhaes, PC and Tóka, G (eds), Citizens and the European Polity: Mass Attitudes towards the European and National Polities. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 6587.10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199602339.003.0004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwander, H, Gohla, D and Schäfer, A (2020) Fighting Fire with Fire? Inequality, Populism and Voter Turnout. Politische Vierteljahresschrift 61, 261283. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11615-020-00247-1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sciarini, P and Goldberg, A (2016) Turnout Bias in Postelection Surveys: Political Involvement, Survey Participation, and Vote Overreporting. Journal of Survey Statistics and Methodology 4(1), 110137. https://doi.org/10.1093/jssam/smv039.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siaroff, A and Merer, JWA (2002) Parliamentary Election Turnout in Europe since 1990. Political Studies 50, 916927. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9248.00400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steiner, ND and Martin, CW (2012) Economic Integration, Party Polarization and Electoral Turnout. West European Politics 35(2), 238265. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2011.648005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stonecash, J (2015) The Two Key Factors Behind Our Polarized Politics. In Hopkins, DJ and Sides, J (eds), Political Polarization in American Politics. New York: Bloomsbury, pp. 6975.Google Scholar
Taagepera, R (1997) Effective Number of Parties for Incomplete Data. Electoral Studies 16(2), 145151. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0261-3794(97)00003-6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavits, M (2006) Party System Change: Testing a Model of New Party Entry. Party Politics 12(1), 99119. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068806059346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Theriault, S (2015) Partisan Warfare is the Problem. In Hopkins, DJ and Sides, J (eds), Political Polarization in American Politics. New York: Bloomsbury, pp. 1115.Google Scholar
Van der Meer, TWG, van Deth, JW and Scheepers, PLH (2009) The Politicized Participant: Ideology and Political Action in 20 Democracies. Comparative Political Studies 42(1), 14261457. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414009332136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weßels, B and Schmitt, H (2008) Meaningful Choices, Political Supply, and Institutional Effectiveness. Electoral Studies 27, 1930. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.electstud.2007.11.010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Westfall, J, van Boven, Leaf, Chambers, JR and Judd, CM (2015) Perceiving Political Polarization in the United States: Party Identity Strength and Attitude Extremity Exacerbate the Perceived Partisan Divide. Perspectives on Psychological Science 10(2), 145158. https://doi.org/10.1177/1745691615569849.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wolf, C and Roßteutscher, S (2013) Religiosität und politische Orientierung? Radikalisierung, Traditionalisierung oder Entkopplung? Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie 65(Supplement 1), 149181. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11577-013-0222-9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Direct Turnout Effect of Party System Polarization (Left) and Individuals' Perceptions of Party Differences (Right) with 95% Confidence IntervalsNote: x-axis scale units denote changes in standard deviation from mean.

Figure 1

Figure 2. The Effect of Perceived Party Differences by Moderate/Extreme Position (Left) and Different Levels of Partisanship (Right) with 95% Confidence IntervalsNote: x-axis scale units denote changes in standard deviation from mean.

Figure 2

Figure 3. The Effect of Party System Polarization by Moderate/Extreme Position (Left) and Levels of Partisanship (Right) with 95% Confidence IntervalsNote: x-axis scale units denote changes in standard deviation from mean.

Figure 3

Table 1. Robustness Checks

Supplementary material: File

Rossteutscher and Stövsand supplementary material

Rossteutscher and Stövsand supplementary material
Download Rossteutscher and Stövsand supplementary material(File)
File 1.2 MB