Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T02:04:11.745Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Does Power Always Flow to the Executive? Interbranch Oscillations in Legislative Authority, 1976–2014

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 August 2021

Paul Chaisty*
Affiliation:
Department of Politics and International Relations, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK
Timothy Power
Affiliation:
Latin America Centre, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Is legislative power flowing to the executive branch over time? Beginning in the 1990s, comparativists began to investigate delegation to the executive under different executive formats. Hypothesized causes include collective action problems due to legislative fractionalization, the presence of a dominant pro-executive faction, preference congruence vis-à-vis the head of government, and challenges posed by economic crises. We test these four hypotheses on a data set containing 2,020 country-year observations of democracies and semi-democracies between 1976 and 2014. Using V-Dem data, we derive annualized measures of shifts in executive–legislative relationships. Contrary to stereotypes of executive dominance, relative gains by legislatures are no less frequent than gains by executives, and economic crises do not advantage political executives in consistent ways. Surprisingly, some of the factors expected to benefit executives seem to enhance assembly authority as well. Robust democracy maintains interbranch power relations in equilibrium, while lower levels of polyarchy are associated with greater ‘noise’ in the relationship.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Government and Opposition Limited

What explains shifts in the balance of power between the executive and legislative branches in modern democracy? To the extent that political scientists have predicted change, they have usually put their money on the executive branch. In fact, this expectation of a ‘ratchet effect’ – that is, unidirectional empowerment of the executive – is now more than a century old. In ‘Parties and Parliament in a Reconstructed Germany’ (originating in 1917 as a series of newspaper articles), Max Weber predicted a shift in authority from the legislative to the executive branch that would grow more pronounced throughout the 20th century. He claimed that parliaments would gradually become agents of oversight and of budgetary control, rather than the initiators of legislation (Weber Reference Weber1978: 1407–1419). Decades later, students of the Third Wave of democratization would frequently echo Weber, displaying concern at perceived overreach by the executive branch – for example, ‘majoritarianism’, ‘super-presidentialism’, ‘delegative democracy’ and the like.

Much of the literature evincing this disquiet was based on case studies or at best limited to a single region of the world. Yet with the global expansion of competitive regimes since the 1970s, and with vast improvements in the availability of comparative data, we are now in a better position than ever before to observe variations in the relative shares of influence over statutory authority, both across space and across time (Chernykh et al. Reference Chernykh, Doyle and Power2017; Fish and Kroenig Reference Fish and Kroenig2009; Wilson and Woldense Reference Wilson and Woldense2019). In this observational study, we document instances of interbranch oscillations in legislative authority – both oversight and lawmaking – since the dawn of the Third Wave. Our dependent variable, as explained below, is not the quantity or stock of power (i.e. shares or levels of legislative influence), but rather any recorded change to the existing balance of power. These changes, in theory, could advantage either the executive or the assembly.

We begin by documenting these shifting empowerments in democratic or semi-democratic political systems over four decades of the Third Wave. We draw on two theoretical traditions strongly associated with the study of democratization – delegation theory and the politics of institutional foundings – to derive a set of simple, intuitive hypotheses about what might alter the relative balance of power between the executive and the assembly. As readers will observe, much of the thinking behind these hypotheses is driven by century-old expectations of executive aggrandizement. We then test these hypotheses on 2,020 observed country-years of competitive politics in the Third Wave, while controlling for socioeconomic modernization, the robustness of democracy, executive format, incentives to cultivate a personal vote, and the electoral cycle. While these are not definitive tests, they do allow for some ‘plausibility assessments’ of some prominent theoretical arguments.

Our principal findings are: (1) while perceptible power shifts are relatively rare in practice, gains by the legislature are no less frequent than gains by the executive; (2) robust democracy seems to maintain interbranch power relations in equilibrium, while lower levels of polyarchy are associated with greater ‘noise’ in the relationship; (3) economic crisis, contrary to conventional wisdom, does not appear to advantage political executives; and surprisingly, (4) some of the factors expected to benefit executives also seem to enhance assembly authority as well.

What causes power shifts in executive–legislative relations? Looking for theoretical clues

The extant literature on executive–legislative relations broadly accepts that the interbranch balance of power is not static. Some scholars believe that there is a secular trend towards greater concentration of power in the executive over time (e.g. Weber Reference Weber1978 [1918]); others claim that executive-legislative relations are periodically reshaped by institutional foundings and constitutional amendments (e.g. Lijphart Reference Lijphart2012; Sartori Reference Sartori1994); others argue that the balance of power can be altered by paraconstitutional practices that take shape over time, exogenously from the constitutional text (Riggs Reference Riggs1988); others accept the role of parchment constraints while asserting that the balance of power can still undergo short-term shifts based on electoral dynamics and outcomes (e.g. Shugart and Carey Reference Shugart and Carey1992). At the same time, while some scholars of presidentialism imply that executive power is already so high everywhere that it is unlikely to rise much further under conditions of democracy (Morgenstern et al. Reference Morgenstern, Polga-Hecimovich and Shair-Rosenfield2013), other analysts insist on the ability of legislative reformers to make relative institutional gains against even the most entrenched executives (Barkan Reference Barkan2009; Fish Reference Fish2006).

Dissensus in the literature may be a predictable consequence of differing regional experiences. However, a more serious problem is that changes in the interbranch balance of power can result from two very different sources: institutional design (that is, formal changes to the rules of the game) and political process (changes in relative de facto influence over legislation occurring in the absence of any alterations to the formal rules). Using presidential systems as an illustration, an example of the former phenomenon might be a constitutional amendment awarding the president the right to exclusive initiative of budgetary laws, or a reform empowering the power of standing committees to scrutinize the activities of government departments. An example of the latter phenomenon might be the emergence of a legislative supermajority that approves 90% of the president's proposals for eight years running, or conversely, an assembly that amends or rejects 90% of the proposals of a weak minority president. In both cases, observers would conclude that legislative influence was shifting from one branch of government to another, but the underlying cause would be fundamentally different.Footnote 1

Research on executive–legislative relations is of course cognizant of these two fundamental sources of power shifts but has not always been explicit in distinguishing between them. An admirable exception is the work on separation of power systems by John Carey and Matthew Shugart (Reference Carey, Shugart, Carey and Shugart1998). They make a clear distinction between two types of decree power: constitutional decree authority, in which this presidential prerogative is clearly and permanently specified in the constitutional text, and delegated decree authority, in which a legislature makes a temporary, reversible transfer of lawmaking power to the executive for limited policy objectives. The former is an institutional power, the latter a political gesture – although they may be observationally equivalent when we examine legislative outcomes post hoc.

This contrast helps us to identify the two subliteratures that can help us derive hypotheses about relative empowerments: the first on the politics of institutional foundings (e.g. Kitschelt Reference Kitschelt1992; Sartori Reference Sartori1994; Shugart Reference Shugart1998; Shugart and Carey Reference Shugart and Carey1992), the second on delegation theory (e.g. Bendor et al. Reference Bendor, Glazer and Hammond2001; Carey and Shugart Reference Carey, Shugart, Carey and Shugart1998; Elgie Reference Elgie2006; Huber and Lupia Reference Huber and Lupia2001; Strom Reference Strom2000). These correspond roughly to the key distinction between constitutional and political variables referenced above. Many of the key contributions in both literatures – especially in the first two decades of the Third Wave – focused on the variables expected to predict a concentration of power in the executive, not in the legislature. Reviewing this literature and noting its directional bias, the task of formulating hypotheses starts with a simple question: given a minimal level of democratic competition, what factors explain empowerment of, or delegation to, the executive branch? Below we focus on four dominant arguments in the comparative literature.

One hypothesis is that seat fragmentation in the legislature would induce collective action problems that would encourage a transfer of responsibilities to the executive. This argument is consistent both with accounts of institutional foundings and with observation of ongoing political dynamics. In their work on presidentialism, Shugart and Carey (Reference Shugart and Carey1992) focused on certain patterns in founding constitutional choices: wherever constitution-writers had good reasons to believe that governability would be difficult to achieve in the future (e.g. due to party fragmentation), they would opt for certain institutions designed to lubricate or streamline the policymaking process. These could include presidential agenda power, decree authority or exclusive initiative in specific policy areas. Such institutions were seen as having a pre-emptive quality: they were quite clearly intended to correct for the inherent collective action problems of fragmented legislatures. The same internal coordination problems could explain why legislatures, even long after founding institutional choices have been made, could still prefer – or at least tolerate – de facto legislative agenda-setting by the executive.

A second hypothesis identifies a political mechanism for delegation: the size of the executive party. In contrast to explanations focusing on fragmentation, which are actor-blind, this approach understands delegation in terms of the level of support commanded by the nominal party of the head of government. Famously described by Walter Bagehot (Reference Bagehot1867) as the ‘efficient secret’ of English parliamentary politics, legislators delegate their legislative and oversight powers to their partisan leaders (Cox Reference Cox1987; Mainwaring and Shugart Reference Mainwaring and Shugart1997; Rasch and Tsebelis Reference Rasch and Tsebelis2011). Thus, delegation to the executive is likely to accelerate as the number of legislators belonging to the executive party increases.

A third hypothesis is that assemblies that have close political alignment to the executive would be willing to cede authority. If the median legislator has similar preferences to the head of government, we would expect that the assembly – for reasons of expedience or velocity – would tolerate a higher level of executive control over the legislative process. This is inspired by principal–agent models of executive–legislative relations (e.g. Carey and Shugart Reference Carey, Shugart, Carey and Shugart1998; Shugart and Carey Reference Shugart and Carey1992; Strom Reference Strom2000).

A fourth hypothesis is that delegation of authority to the executive occurs mainly during major socioeconomic crises. When economic crisis is severe and problems need to be solved yesterday, chief executives should be more likely to arrogate authority into the executive branch, and legislators should be more likely to tolerate this (perhaps temporary) concentration of power. The crisis explanation is consistent with both the ‘usurpation’ interpretation (e.g. Ferreira Rubio and Goretti Reference Ferreira Rubio, Goretti, Carey and Shugart1998; Parrish Reference Parrish, Carey and Shugart1998) and the ‘delegation’ interpretation of executive agenda control; either one would predict agency loss by the assembly. This approach is also closely linked to theories of ‘delegative democracy’, which cite economic crisis as the main causal factor in explaining the shift from representative to delegative (executive-centric) forms of governance (O'Donnell Reference O'Donnell1994).

We acknowledge that these four hypotheses are not the only conceivable approaches to explaining interbranch power shifts. However, they are simple and intuitive. If they are well supported empirically, they should correctly predict a clear directional outcome: empowerment of the executive. In the next section, we operationalize these models.

Data and method

We analyse expert survey data for 2,020 years of legislative–executive relations since the dawn of the Third Wave of democratization in 1976. These data cover parliamentary, presidential and semipresidential political systems that meet a minimum standard of pluralism: we restrict our analysis to political systems with a positive score (1–10) on the Polity IV scale. This measure spans ‘open anocracies’ – countries that are neither fully democratic nor fully autocratic, but are closer to democracies on all components measured by Polity – to established democracies (Marshall and Cole Reference Marshall and Cole2014: 21). This variation allows us to explore how regime-level factors may affect the balance of power between executives and legislative assemblies.

As can be seen in Table 1, our annualized data cover country cases from most world regions. The largest share of cases (approximately 40%) can be found in Europe; almost 30% derive from Latin America; around 30% are shared between Asia and sub-Saharan Africa; and the remainder can be found in the Middle East and the former Soviet Union. These regional differences display immense variation in terms of executive format. Over 50% of the parliamentary year-cases and 60% of the semipresidential year-cases are from Europe, while most of the presidential observations (over 70%) are drawn from Latin America.

Table 1. Sample Summary of Cases by Region, Country and Executive Type, 1976–2014

To examine dynamics in legislative–executive relations over a 40-year period and cross-regionally, we deploy expert assessments of assembly lawmaking and executive oversight powers generated by the Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) project (Coppedge et al. Reference Coppedge2016). Although these data derive from the subjective interpretation of actual practice, we believe that they are superior to measures of legislative–executive relations that rely on formal rules alone. This is because shifts in legislative–executive power relations often occur independently from changes in de jure arrangements. Moreover, while such de facto measures always raise the possibility of cross-contamination by expert assessments of executive power in other areas, the variables that we use correlate significantly with formal measures of legislative power and executive oversight.Footnote 2 Thus, we are confident that the V-Dem variables are capturing substantive patterns of legislative–executive relations.

To examine relative empowerment of either the legislative or executive branches, we analyse categorical variables for oversight and lawmaking, which are formed from responses to V-Dem survey items. First, to assess oscillations in oversight power, we use the composite V-Dem index of ‘Legislative Constraints on the Executive’, which measures the capacity of the assembly to scrutinize and investigate the sitting executive.Footnote 3 Second, to assess any institutional shifts in lawmaking power, we analyse three V-Dem questions on the lawmaking power of the legislative and executive branches:

  1. 1. ‘In practice, is the approval of the lower (or unicameral) chamber of the legislature required to pass legislation?’

  2. 2. ‘Does the head of state have the capacity, in practice, to propose legislation?’

  3. 3. ‘Does the head of government have the capacity, in practice, to propose legislation?’

Following the thrust of most of the literature, we first arrange responses to each question in the direction of empowerment of the executive. We then code any within-country change in consecutive annual scores as advantaging the executive (positive values), empowering the assembly (negative values) or exhibiting no change at all (scored as zero).Footnote 4 With the data available to us at present, we are unable to say whether these shifts are due to constitutional/institutional reform or to the logic of political process; as explained above, both phenomena result in power shifts that are observationally equivalent in our data set.

Recoding the V-Dem items produces two dependent variables, one representing oversight dynamics and one capturing lawmaking dynamics. Each dependent variable consists of three simple categories: year-on-year empowerment of the assembly, year-on-year empowerment of the executive or no change.

As can be seen in Table 2, visible oscillations in either direction are atypical; the modal outcome is for legislative–executive relations to remain in a steady state. In our data, ‘no change’ occurs almost 75% of the time for the oversight questions, and an astonishing 90% of the time for the lawmaking questions. These data exhibit less dynamism than much of the extant literature would seem to suggest, perhaps because political scientists tend to focus on change rather than stasis. Moreover, these data confound some time-honoured Weberian expectations: change advantaging the executive is no more likely than the reverse pattern. In our sample of more than 2,000 country-years beginning in 1976, executive empowerment occurs just 10% of the time on the question of oversight, and less than 5% of the time on the question of lawmaking. These findings, which are robust to the deployment of alternative dependent variables, call into question some widely held stereotypes about executive aggrandizement or usurpation in Third Wave democracies (for a critique of the presidential literature, see Carey and Shugart Reference Carey, Shugart, Carey and Shugart1998).Footnote 5

Table 2. Frequencies of Change in Legislative–Executive Relations

Note: N refers to country-year observations as explained in Table 1.

Concrete examples taken from the data set, which illustrate changes to the balance of power in the areas of oversight and lawmaking, are presented in Table 3. Oscillations in the real world can take surprisingly diverse forms. These range from constitutional engineering (e.g. Paraguay 1992 or Hungary 2011); to elections that transform legislative majorities (e.g. Taiwan 2008 or Germany 2013); and to systemic shocks such as the impeachment of a president (e.g. Peru 2000), the dismissal of a prime minister (Pakistan 1990) or a state of emergency and war, which has direct consequences for the power of the executive (e.g. India 1976 or Ukraine 2014).

Table 3. Illustrative Examples of Change in the Executive–Legislative Balance of Power

Source: Compiled by authors.

Note: Examples encompass changes deriving from both institutional redesign and from political process (see text for distinction).

We now explore our four hypotheses for changes in the balance of executive–legislative relations, using a variety of lagged independent variables. These variables are listed in Table 4. First, to examine the hypothesis that legislators cede power to the executive in the face of the collective action problems generated by multipartism, we operationalize a party fractionalization variable. This measure, originated by Douglas Rae (Reference Rae1967), estimates the probability that two MPs drawn randomly from the assembly will belong to different parties.

Table 4. Independent Variables in the Analysis

Sources: Party fragmentation, calculated from data coded by Cheibub et al. (Reference Cheibub, Przeworski and Saiegh2004) and extended to 2014; ideological proximity and distance to next election, calculated from data coded by the Database of Political Institutions (Cruz et al. Reference Cruz, Keefer and Scartascini2015); Electoral Democracy Index, electoral system, candidate selection and personal vote calculated from data coded by V-Dem (Coppedge et al. Reference Coppedge2016); economic crisis from Laeven and Valencia (Reference Laeven and Valencia2012) and V-Dem; GDP PPP per capita (real GDP at chained PPP using 2011 USD) drawn from Penn World Table 8.1, available at www.rug.nl/ggdc/productivity/pwt/; parliamentary, semipresidential and presidential calculated from data coded by Cheibub et al. (Reference Cheibub, Przeworski and Saiegh2004) and Elgie (Reference Elgie2018).

Second, to consider the hypothesis that delegation is more likely to occur when the chief executive's party dominates the assembly, we simply measure the fractional share of seats held by the party of the chief executive in the lower house or single chamber of the legislature.

Third, to test the hypothesis that delegation is more likely to occur when there is preference congruence between the executive and legislature, we estimate the overall ideological proximity of the assembly to the executive, relying on annualized data on party orientations towards economic policy. We recognize that coding a single policy area in a one-dimensional space is an imperfect way of measuring this preference congruence, yet we note that left–right differences on macroeconomic management are a major feature of political life in virtually all competitive polities. First, we calculate the ideological distance between the party of the head of the executive and the weighted ideological average of all the parties for which ideological coding was available in the Database of Political Institutions: these data cover up to three government parties and one opposition party.Footnote 6 To capture ideological proximity, the variable was recoded so that higher values represent greater alignment.

Finally, we inspect the argument that severe economic crises tend to loosen constraints on executives and expand their statutory influence. Our economic crisis variable is constructed from International Monetary Fund data on incidents of financial, banking and debt crises (Laeven and Valencia Reference Laeven and Valencia2012), and from data that record annualized, negative gross domestic product (GDP) (Coppedge et al. Reference Coppedge2016).

Moving beyond our leading explanatory variables, we also control for other factors that are likely to affect the likelihood that executive and legislative actors will seek to maximize power. First, we control for the level of electoral democracy, on the assumption that more polyarchic regimes will exhibit greater stability of interbranch relations than semi-competitive systems.Footnote 7 In this article, we do not examine the effects of judicial independence on delegation, but we note that it is highly correlated with the level of electoral democracy and produces similar results.Footnote 8 Second, we estimate the level of socioeconomic modernization using GDP per capita at purchasing power parity. This controls for the possibility that economic crisis will generate comparatively greater institutional instability in poorer societies. Third, we control for executive format, whether presidential, semipresidential or parliamentary. We expect oscillation in legislative authority to be more frequent in separation of powers and dual executive systems, given that both the executive and assembly have a constitutional right to shape legislation. Fourth, we control for systemic incentives that lead legislators to ‘cultivate a personal vote’ (Carey and Shugart Reference Carey and Shugart1995) – that is, to rely on candidate-centred rather than party-centred appeals to the electorate. Where these incentives are strong, legislators are more likely to engage in particularistic exchanges and leave national policymaking to the executive branch (Shugart Reference Shugart1998; Shugart and Carey Reference Shugart and Carey1992). The personal vote variable we use here is an interaction term incorporating the degree of majoritarianism and the centralization of candidate selection procedures.Footnote 9 Fifth, given the known effects of ‘honeymoon’ and ‘lame duck’ periods on assembly–executive relations (Howell and Mayer Reference Howell and Mayer2005; Shull Reference Shull1997), we include a variable measuring the length of time (in years) to the next parliamentary election. Distance from the next election should boost de facto alignment between the executive and assembly, even if the size or ideology of the parties remain unchanged over the course of a chief executive's term in office. All of our control variables are lagged by one year in the analyses.

Analysis and findings

In presenting our empirical results, we remind the reader once again that our goal is not to explore the power of executives or assemblies in absolute terms, but rather in relative terms, using the year-on-year (YOY) change variables described in the preceding section. Using multinomial regression, we assess the plausibility of the different explanations in separate models that test the lawmaking and oversight dependent variables. These models explore the extent to which each predictor is likely to explain empowerment of the legislature or of the executive relative to the baseline. The reference category is ‘no observed change’ in the balance of power, which is the modal YOY observation in our data set.

Table 5 summarizes the estimated effects of each explanatory variable on the likely increase or decrease in the capacity of legislatures to oversee the executive branch. (As the variables for party fragmentation and the size of the chief executive's party are highly correlated, we analyse them in separate models.) The general pattern here is that our explanatory variables, which are largely derived from theories of executive dominance, actually perform better at predicting empowerments of the legislative assembly. Interestingly, our analysis finds no evidence to support the view that the probability of delegation to the executive is determined by the size of the chief executive's party. In fact, we find that assemblies dominated by the party of the chief executive are significantly less likely to change the status quo. This equilibrium may reflect the interest of large legislative majorities that do not face significant veto players.

Table 5. Predictors of Power Shifts in Executive Oversight Patterns (Multinomial Regression Coefficients and Standard Errors)

Notes: The excluded category on the dependent variable is no annual change. The reference category for executive format is parliamentary. Significance levels: * p < 0.05; ** p < 0.01; *** p < 0.001.

The only explanatory variable that is significantly correlated with the empowerment of the executive – party fragmentation – also seems to contribute to the empowerment of the assembly. Holding all the other variables at their means, fragmentation values increase the probability of executive empowerment by 12 percentage points (as fragmentation increases from its minimum to maximum value), but also increase the probability of assembly empowerment by 15 percentage points. In other words, partisan fractionalization – which we interpret here as a measure of collective action problems in the interbranch bargaining environment – sharply raises the probability of departures from the status quo. Low levels of political fragmentation seem to hold the executive–legislative relationship in place, while high levels of fragmentation are associated with a breakdown of this equilibrium.

The other explanatory variables that have a significant impact on change in oversight powers – ideological affinity and economic crisis – advantage only the legislative branch. Holding all the other variables at their means, the probability of assembly empowerment increases from 6 to 18 percentage points (Model 1) as the ideological gap between the executive's party and the assembly's weighted average narrows to zero (with a one-year lag). In other words, relative ideological congruence between the executive and legislature seems to open up space for potential (rather than observed) legislative oversight of the executive, which is what our V-Dem variable captures. One possible explanation for this could be that when interbranch preference congruence is known to be high, executives may have less to fear from legislative scrutiny. However, deployment (as opposed to availability) of oversight mechanisms is not directly observable in our data set, and more research would be necessary to confirm this interpretation.

Crisis is also more likely to strengthen the legislature's oversight power, despite strong theoretical and empirical reasons to expect that economic crisis would advantage the executive. Holding all the other variables at their means (Model 1), economic crisis (lagged by one year) increased the probability of legislative oversight empowerment from 13 (no crisis) to 18 (crisis) percentage points. Conversely, economic crisis had a negative impact on executive empowerment. Although the crisis variable is almost significant at the 0.05 level (p = 0.06), its effect is to produce change that strengthens legislative oversight of the executive branch. This negative effect, which is statistically significant in Model 2, holds when the crisis variable is lagged by more than two years.Footnote 10 One interpretation of these results could be that crises actually do confer various first-mover advantages upon incumbent executives – as predicted by the delegation and crisis literatures – but assemblies then counter this effect by upgrading horizontal accountability after the fact. This causal mechanism would require confirmation in case studies, focusing on instances of institutional reform in post-crisis scenarios.

The lagged control variables were significant for all or most models, but their effects both suppress and magnify the empowerment of both branches on the oversight dimension. Consistent with our expectations, the level of electoral democracy significantly depresses the likelihood that change in oversight politics will occur. Recall that we first selected country-years with Polity scores of above 1, and then within this set of cases, we used the V-Dem Electoral Democracy Index (EDI) to discriminate among them. The EDI variable has the largest impact of any of our predictors. As electoral democracy becomes more robust, change becomes less likely in either direction: existing oversight patterns remain in a steady state. As electoral democracy increases from its minimum to maximum values in Model 1, the likelihood of change empowering the legislature and executive falls by 15 and 19 percentage points, while the likelihood of no change increases by 34 percentage points.

The effect of democracy does not appear to be conditional on the institutional format of the executive. Figures 1a and 1b summarize the results of logistic regressions estimating the predicted probabilities of lagged electoral democracy on empowerment of both the legislature and executive branches, while holding all the lagged regime-type categories at their means. As electoral democracy increases, the probability of any shift in oversight patterns declines. This bracing effect holds across presidential, semipresidential and parliamentary systems.

Figure 1a. Probability that Democratization Will Empower the Assembly in Oversight, by Executive Format (predicted probabilities with 95% confidence intervals)

Note: Predicted probabilities in Figures 1a, 1b, 2a, 2b are estimated from binary logistic regression of the effects of levels of electoral democracy on change (either to the assembly or the executive) for each executive format.

Figure 1b. Probability that Democratization Will Empower the Executive in Oversight, by Executive Format (predicted probabilities with 95% confidence intervals)

However, these results also show that the probability of oversight change remains consistently higher in separation of powers systems. This is evident in the full regression model. As can been seen in Table 5, both presidential and semipresidential systems are significantly more likely than the reference category (parliamentarism) to experience change that strengthens either the oversight power of legislatures or the capacity of executives to reduce these constraints. This is consistent with our theoretical expectations.

The observed effects of the other control variables are the opposite of what we expected. Interestingly, the likelihood of change falls significantly at the start of an executive's term in office. There is no evidence to suggest that temporal distance to the next election (the honeymoon effect) empowers either the executive or the assembly. Yet change in oversight patterns – in either direction – is far more likely towards the end of a government's term in office. When the legislature gains in oversight capacity, it could be because of the anticipated political weakness of tired or term-limited governments (the lame duck effect), but it could also simply reflect the political life cycle of incumbents: incoming governments have less of a record to be investigated than do outgoing governments. When the oversight capacity of the assembly to hold the executive to account atrophies towards the end of a parliament, it could be because members are more concerned with electoral prospects in the final year of the legislature.

Also contrary to our expectations, the strengthening of the personal vote can advantage the assembly as well as the executive. Holding all the other variables at their means, the probability of change in political systems with the highest personal vote value was 28 percentage points greater than in political systems with the lowest personal vote value (at a one-year lag in Model 1). This finding is not an artefact of the way we code individual-level incentives to cultivate a personal vote. When we repeat the analysis with a V-Dem variable that codes party systems along a dimension from programmatic to clientelistic, the result is the same: more particularistic political systems increase the probability of both legislative and executive empowerments.Footnote 11

This finding may sound counterintuitive, but we remind the reader that we are not observing ‘legislative strengthening’ in the sense of professionalization, but simply a perceptible shift in the balance of oversight authority in interbranch politics. Why would institutional incentives to cultivate a personal vote advantage the assembly? The shift we observe may be a consequence of extreme forms of clientelism, which require chief executives to negotiate each piece of legislation ad hoc with individual legislators, thus inflating drastically the number of veto players. This scenario resembles Gary Cox and Scott Morgenstern's (Reference Cox and Morgenstern2001) model of the ‘venal-parochial’ assembly. Under these conditions, as work on Italy (e.g. Di Palma Reference Di Palma1977) or Brazil has shown (e.g. Ames Reference Ames2001), rampant clientelism can make the executive a ‘hostage’ to the legislature, with legislators exerting great influence over the government's statutory proposals.

In a second analysis, we now consider the impact of our four explanatory variables on the balance of lawmaking powers between assemblies and executives. These results are summarized in Table 6. As can be seen, they are less significant statistically, although the findings for the effects of party fragmentation, the size of the chief executive's party and electoral democracy power remain similar in terms of empowerment of the assembly. When the fragmentation of parties is at its maximum level, for example, the probability of any increase in the lawmaking power of assemblies is 8 percentage points greater than when fragmentation is at its minimum level.

Table 6. Predictors of Power Shifts in Lawmaking Patterns (Multinomial Regression Coefficients and Standard Errors)

Notes: The excluded category on the dependent variable is no annual change. The reference category for executive format is parliamentary. Significance levels: * p < 0.05; ** p < 0.01; *** p < 0.001.

As in the previous models, the likelihood of change empowering both the legislature and executive declines as the level of democracy rises. Holding all the other variables at their means (Model 1), the probability that democracy will empower the lawmaking capability of legislators falls by 22 percentage points as political systems move from the lowest to the highest levels of electoral democracy, and by 17 for executives. Thus, as in our oversight analysis, the main effect of democratization seems to be the cementing of stable equilibria in interbranch relations.

This evidence seems to bolster the conventional wisdom about the Third Wave: change empowering the executive is more likely to occur in semi-competitive systems and in unconsolidated democracies of all stripes. This is a recurring theme in the vast literatures on ‘delegative democracy’ (e.g. González Reference González, Brinks, Leiras and Mainwaring2014; O'Donnell Reference O'Donnell1994; Peruzzotti Reference Peruzzotti, Brinks, Leiras and Mainwaring2014) and on ‘hybrid regimes’ (e.g. Levitsky and Way Reference Levitsky and Way2011; Schedler Reference Schedler2013). However, it also shows that change empowering the executive is not the only outcome in these regimes: legislative gains in oversight and statutory authority are also commonplace. The clearest implication of the analyses is that if and when hybrid regimes democratize further, fluctuations in the interbranch balance of power are likely to slow or cease. Although our data do not measure formal institutions, here we can offer an interpretation inspired by historical institutionalism, identifying a window of opportunity for change in the interbranch balance of power. This window is open mainly at modest levels of polyarchy.

Moreover, we find that the effect of democratization on the balance of lawmaking power between executives and assemblies is once again unmediated by executive format. As Figures 2a and 2b show, the probability of change in the balance of lawmaking power between the executive and assembly falls consistently across all regime types as the level of electoral democracy rises.

Figure 2a. Probability that Democratization Will Empower the Assembly in Lawmaking Authority, by Executive Format (predicted probabilities with 95% confidence intervals)

Figure 2b. Probability that Democratization Will Empower the Executive in Lawmaking Authority, by Executive Format (predicted probabilities with 95% confidence intervals)

The same visual analysis also shows that the likelihood of any change is greatest in semipresidential systems. This gives further support to Maurice Duverger's classic (Reference Duverger1980) contention that the balance of power swings more dramatically under semipresidentialism due to the existence of a dual executive. This institutional arrangement incentivizes the legislature and the executive to make competing claims on lawmaking and oversight power, thereby increasing the probability of power shifts whenever changes in legislative support for the president lead to a more united or divided executive. While Duverger described semipresidentialism as a form of ‘alternation’ between presidential and parliamentary patterns, Giovanni Sartori (Reference Sartori1994: 24) preferred the term ‘oscillation’, which we have adopted here. Both authors correctly predicted the patterns we illustrate in Figures 2a and 2b.

The most striking regional effect that we also observe in these results – the probability of change in either direction was highest in those countries that were formerly part of the Soviet UnionFootnote 12 – highlights the effects of the combination of political system hybridity with semipresidentialism, an admixture that predominates in the region. Although our concern in this article has been with latent cross-national trends, this finding will be of interest to scholars of post-Soviet politics.

Conclusions

Shifting empowerments between the executive and legislature are relatively rare in modern political systems. When we examine the interbranch balance of power on oversight and lawmaking, the vast majority of country-years exhibit no change at all. But this aggregate finding obscures substantial variation across cases when we control for the level of political democracy. Country-years with high Polity IV scores display lower variation in the relative balance of power between the executive and assembly – the probability of change empowering either the executive or assembly in a given year is around 4% in terms of lawmaking and between 11 and 14% for oversight – while semi-competitive political systems exhibit far more dynamism in the relationship. At our lowest observed levels of political pluralism (countries with a Polity score of 1), the probability of a fluctuation in the lawmaking authority of the assembly or executive in a given year is between approximately 13 and 16 percentage points, and between 14 and 27 percentage points for oversight.Footnote 13

Democracy matters. While robust polyarchy does not freeze interbranch relationships in place forever, it is far more likely to exhibit a stable equilibrium between the executive and assembly. A reasonable interpretation of the robust-democracy equilibrium is that actors’ expectations concerning executive oversight and the origins, amendment and enactment of legislation have largely converged. This finding holds across different regime types – presidential, semipresidential and parliamentary – and can be viewed as both cause and consequence of the ‘only game in town’ (Linz and Stepan Reference Linz and Stepan1996).

Yet even when we control for the (stabilizing) effects of democracy on the interbranch balance of power, and the greater likelihood of change in lawmaking patterns in semipresidential systems, we still find that fractionalization of the party system is associated with change in either direction. Both the executive and the assembly are in a position to exploit fragmentation for procedural gains. An intuitive reading of this finding would be that extremely fragmented party systems are associated with minority executives, the lack of a hegemonic force in the legislature, and continual political conflicts. This argument resonates in the presidentialism literature, wherein these features were famously identified as ‘perils’ by Juan Linz (Reference Linz1990); it is possible that ‘Linzian conflicts’ could be responsible for the see-saw pattern that we observed in the results for fragmentation. Such an interpretation would be consistent with the early revisions to Linz (Reference Linz1990) proposed by Scott Mainwaring (Reference Mainwaring1993) and Mark Jones (Reference Jones1995); fragmentation may not always cause regime breakdown, but is associated with protracted struggles for policymaking authority.

We also find that ideological affinity of both branches is more likely to empower assemblies over executives. When there is reasonable ideological congruence among the main parties in the legislature, we observe a much greater likelihood that executive oversight power will gravitate towards the assembly. One reading of this scenario is that the executive, not feeling threatened by an ideologically distant parliament, is content to let the assembly drive a greater share of the policy agenda. However, we observe that this effect is independent of the electoral timetable. We find no evidence to suggest that the more cooperative relations that we associate with electoral honeymoons has any impact on the balance of power. On the contrary, as elections approach, the oversight powers of the assembly and the executive's power to withstand oversight appear to be strengthened.

We also find some mixed evidence that electoral systems encouraging legislators to cultivate a personal vote may actually advantage legislative assemblies vis-à-vis the executive. We concede that our personal vote variable captures only institutional incentives towards particularism in legislative careers, and is in no way a behavioural measure of observed clientelistic interactions between the executive and the assembly. Yet our findings are congruent with bargaining models suggesting that pervasive clientelism inflates the number of effective veto players (even net of party fragmentation) and dilutes the executive's agenda.

Most surprisingly, we find little evidence to support the contention that economic crisis empowers executives. We observe that (lagged) economic crisis is significant only in predicting greater legislative oversight of the executive branch. The utter failure of crisis models to predict shifts in interbranch authority in the direction of the executive calls into question some long-standing arguments about executive dominance, such as theories of presidential decree deployment (e.g. Ferreira Rubio and Goretti Reference Ferreira Rubio, Goretti, Carey and Shugart1998), and also claims about an economic origin of so-called ‘delegative democracy’ (e.g. Kubicek Reference Kubicek1994; O'Donnell Reference O'Donnell1994).Footnote 14

Overall, we have found that some mainstream explanations of delegation – devised almost exclusively to explain delegation from the assembly to the executive – also work passably well in explaining delegation to the opposite direction, i.e. to the legislature. This finding is at odds with many of the principal–agent models that have shaped the study of executive–legislative relations in the Third Wave, particularly in the study of comparative presidentialism. Some readers may interpret the surprising infrequency of gains by the executive to be indicative of the already high levels of executive authority in modern political systems – in this view, some sort of ‘Weberian ceiling’ may have already been reached. This would echo the recent analysis by Morgenstern et al. (Reference Morgenstern, Polga-Hecimovich and Shair-Rosenfield2013), who claim that presidential power in the US and Latin America is either high or very high. However, a proper test of the ceiling hypothesis will only be possible when we have comparable measures of legislative power that are valid across space, time, and executive format.Footnote 15

In conclusion, while many case studies on post-Third Wave politics have documented executive usurpation or encroachment upon legislative authority, a cross-national analysis suggests the need to rethink some of these arguments. Change in executive–legislative relationships is relatively infrequent; concrete gains by the executive are rare; and moreover, even when such gains do occur, the proposed explanatory factors perform inconsistently at best.

Acknowledgements

We thank Christopher Gerry and the ECPR Presidential Politics Standing Group for advice and helpful comments.

Footnotes

1 We could then go on to hypothesize that empowerments resulting from institutional design would be more ‘sticky’ while empowerments due to temporary political majorities would be more easily reversible. This is an empirical question that will not be addressed in this article.

2 Although using different phrasing, the V-Dem indicators of de facto institutional power correlate significantly with (formalist) cognate variables provided by the Comparative Constitutions Project (http://comparativeconstitutionsproject.org/ccp-data-downloads/). For example, the CCP coding of which actor can initiate general legislation in presidential systems correlates at 0.496 with the V-Dem measure of the president's effective power to legislate.

3 The index is formed by taking the point estimates from a Bayesian factor analysis model of four other V-Dem indicators: legislature questions officials in practice (v2lgqstexp), the extent of executive oversight (v2lgotovst), legislature investigates in practice (v2lginvstp), and legislature opposition parties (v2lgoppart).

4 For the three lawmaking questions, it is possible for change to be driven by just one V-Dem question, to take place within the executive branch only (as is more typical in semipresidential systems), and to occur in different directions (e.g. the legislature and executive can be empowered simultaneously). To convert this information to a single annualized observation, we deploy the following coding rules across all three questions: (1) when only one question captures change, any gain is coded as a gain overall for that particular branch, and a loss is coded as a gain for the other branch; (2) when a change occurs within the executive from the head of state to the head of government, this is interpreted as a gain for the legislature in semipresidential systems (and vice versa if power moves from the premier to the president), and as no change in either presidential or parliamentary systems; (3) if questions indicate that both branches gain or lose power in the same direction, this is coded as no change. When we exclude cases of no change from the analysis, this makes no difference to the results.

5 Analysis of combined V-Dem questions on the capacity of either the head of state or the head of government to veto legislation in practice finds that for over 90% of the cases, there was ‘no change’ in the capacity of the executive to veto legislation, and that when change did occur it did so equally in both directions.

6 See Cruz et al. (Reference Cruz, Keefer and Scartascini2015). The ideological position of each party on economic issues is classified as left (3), centre (2) or right (1). We have recoded their category of 0 (no clear position on the economic policy dimension) as 2.

7 We use V-Dem's Electoral Democracy Index, which is formed by the weighted average of the indices measuring freedom of association, suffrage, clean elections, elected executive and freedom of expression.

8 Analysis of V-Dem's Judicial Constraints on the Executive Index produces results similar to those generated by the Electoral Democracy Index. This analysis is available from the authors on request.

9 Due to missingness, we could not employ the personal vote index (PVI) created by Carey and Shugart (Reference Carey and Shugart1995) and updated by Johnson and Wallack (Reference Johnson and Wallack2010). We create an imperfect substitute by first drawing on V-Dem's variable for the electoral system used for the lower or unicameral chamber (v2elparlel), recoding it so that proportional systems are scored 1, mixed systems 2 and majoritarian systems 3. We then deploy the V-Dem variable on candidate selection rules (v2pscnslnl), recoding it so that the most centralized system (‘national legislative candidates are selected exclusively by national party leaders’) is scored 1 and the most decentralized system (‘national legislative candidates are chosen by constituency groups or direct primaries’) is scored 6. These two indicators are then multiplied together to create our ‘personal vote’ variable with a possible range from 1 to 18. This variable correlates at 0.553 with the Johnson and Wallack PVI.

10 Moreover, in separate analyses we found that alternative variables capturing other forms of major national crises – e.g. violent conflict at home (intra-state war with at least 1,000 battle deaths for each country-year) and violent conflict in the international area (did the country participate in an international armed conflict?) – are insignificant. Our sources for the conflict variables were the Haber and Menaldo (Reference Haber and Menaldo2011) ‘civil war’ variable and the ‘armed conflict, international’ variables, both included in ‘V-Dem Codebook v6’ (Coppedge et al. 2016). Results available upon request.

11 The specific V-Dem question asked was: ‘Among the major parties, what is the main or most common form of linkage to their constituents?’ We reversed the order of categories from: 0 = policy/programmatic; 1 = mixed local collective and policy/programmatic; 2 = local collective; 3 = mixed clientelistic/local collective; 4 = clientelistic. We used our ‘personal vote’ rather than this variable because this V-Dem indicator correlates too highly with the separate V-Dem Electoral Democracy Index.

12 This analysis is available from the authors on request.

13 Predicted probabilities are calculated from a simple bivariate analysis of the effect of a country's level of democracy (as measured by Polity IV) on the likelihood of change empowering either the assembly or the executive. This analysis is available on request.

14 O'Donnell (Reference O'Donnell1994: 160) acknowledges that delegative democracies result from the interaction effect of two factors: (1) social and economic crises inherited from authoritarian regimes, and (2) cultural patterns pertaining to the exercise of authority. However, in his analysis he gives overwhelming attention to the first factor (crisis) and very little to the second.

15 The parliamentary powers index (PPI) based on expert assessments (Chernykh et al. Reference Chernykh, Doyle and Power2017; Fish and Kroenig Reference Fish and Kroenig2009; Wilson and Woldense Reference Wilson and Woldense2019) provides an indication of first-level differences, but it is not robust enough to use as an explanatory variable in this statistical analysis. Of the PPI items appropriate for our analysis, the seven that are available in VDEM – v2lgintblo, v2lgfunds, v2lgwarlaw, v2exdfdshs, v2exdfvths, v2exremhsp, v2lgcomslo – do not scale reliably, with a Cronbach Alpha of 0.403 only.

References

Ames, B (2001) The Deadlock of Democracy in Brazil. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bagehot, W (1867) The English Constitution. London: Chapman and Hall.Google Scholar
Barkan, JD (ed.) (2009) Legislative Power in Emerging African Democracies. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bendor, J, Glazer, A and Hammond, T (2001) Theories of Delegation. Annual Review of Political Science 4, 235269. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.polisci.4.1.235.Google Scholar
Carey, JM and Shugart, MS (1995) Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: A Rank Ordering of Electoral Formulas. Electoral Studies 14(4), 417439. https://doi.org/10.1016/0261-3794(94)00035-2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carey, JM and Shugart, MS (1998) Calling Out the Tanks or Filling Out the Forms?. In Carey, JM and Shugart, MS (eds), Executive Decree Authority. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheibub, JA, Przeworski, A and Saiegh, SM (2004) Government Coalitions and Legislative Success Under Presidentialism and Parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science 34, 565587. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123404000195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chernykh, S, Doyle, D and Power, TJ (2017) Measuring Legislative Power: An Expert Reweighting of the Fish–Kroenig Parliamentary Powers Index. Legislative Studies Quarterly 42(2), 295320. https://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coppedge, M et al. (2016) V-Dem Codebook v6. Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) Project.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, GW (1987) The Efficient Secret: The Cabinet and the Development of Political Parties in Victorian England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, GW and Morgenstern, S (2001) Latin America's Reactive Assemblies and Proactive Presidents. Comparative Politics 33(2), 171190. https://doi.org/10.2307/422377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cruz, C, Keefer, P and Scartascini, C (2015) Database of Political Institutions. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://publications.iadb.org/handle/11319/7408.Google Scholar
Di Palma, G. (1977) Surviving Without Governing: The Italian Parties in Parliament. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duverger, M (1980) A New Political System Model: Semi-Presidential Government. European Journal of Political Research 8, 165187. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.1980.tb00569.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elgie, R (2006) Why Do Governments Delegate Authority to Quasi-Autonomous Agencies? The Case of Independent Administrative Authorities in France. Governance 19(2), 207227. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0491.2006.00312.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elgie, R (2018) Semipresidentialism, Premier-Presidentialism and President-Parliamentarism: A New Country-Year Dataset. Blog post, presidential-power.com, 3 April. http://presidential-power.com/?p=7869.Google Scholar
Ferreira Rubio, D and Goretti, M (1998) When the President Governs Alone: The Decretazo in Argentina, 1989–1993. In Carey, JM and Shugart, MS (eds), Executive Decree Authority. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1361.Google Scholar
Fish, MS (2006) Stronger Legislatures, Stronger Democracies. Journal of Democracy 17(1), 520. https://doi.org/10.1353/jod.2006.0008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fish, SM and Kroenig, M (2009) The Handbook of National Legislatures: A Global Survey. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
González, L (2014) Unpacking Delegative Democracy: Digging into the Empirical Content of a Rich Theoretical Concept. In Brinks, D, Leiras, M and Mainwaring, S (eds), Reflections on Uneven Democracies: The Legacy of Guillermo O'Donnell. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 240268.Google Scholar
Haber, S and Menaldo, V (2011) Do Natural Resources Fuel Authoritarianism? A Reappraisal of the Resource Curse. American Political Science Review 105(1), 126. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055410000584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howell, WG and Mayer, KR (2005) The Last One Hundred Days. Presidential Studies Quarterly 35, 533553. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055410000584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, JD and Lupia, A (2001) Cabinet Instability and Delegation in Parliamentary Democracies. American Journal of Political Science 45, 1832. https://doi.org/10.2307/2669357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, JW and Wallack, JS (2010) Electoral Systems and the Personal Vote. Data set and codebook, 25 September. http://hdl.handle.net/1902.1/17901.Google Scholar
Jones, MP (1995) Electoral Laws and the Survival of Presidential Democracies. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Kitschelt, H (1992) The Formation of Party Systems in East Central Europe. Politics and Society 20, 750. https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329292020001003.Google Scholar
Kubicek, P (1994) Delegative Democracy in Russia and Ukraine. Communist and Post-Communist Studies 27(4), 423441.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laeven, L and Valencia, F (2012) Systemic Banking Crises Database: An Update. IMF Working Paper WP/12/163. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Levitsky, S and Way, L (2011) Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid Regimes After the Cold War. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A (2012) Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries, 2nd edn. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Linz, JJ (1990) The Perils of Presidentialism. Journal of Democracy 1(1), 5169. https://doi.org/10.1353/jod.1990.0011.Google Scholar
Linz, JJ and Stepan, A (1996) Problems of Democratic Transition and Consolidation: Southern Europe, South America, and Post-Communist Europe. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Mainwaring, S (1993) Presidentialism, Multipartism, and Democracy: The Difficult Combination. Comparative Political Studies 26(2), 198228. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414093026002003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mainwaring, S and Shugart, MS (1997) Presidentialism and Democracy in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, MG and Cole, BR (2014) Global Report 2014: Conflict, Governance and State Fragility. Vienna: Centre for Systemic Peace. www.systemicpeace.org/vlibrary/GlobalReport2014.pdf.Google Scholar
Morgenstern, S, Polga-Hecimovich, J and Shair-Rosenfield, S (2013) Tall, Grande, or Venti: Presidential Powers in the United States and Latin America. Journal of Politics in Latin America 2, 3770. https://doi.org/10.1177/1866802X1300500202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Donnell, G (1994) Delegative Democracy. Journal of Democracy 5(1), 5569. https://doi.org/10.1353/jod.1994.0010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parrish, S (1998) Presidential Decree Authority in Russia. In Carey, JM and Shugart, MS (eds), Executive Decree Authority. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 62103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peruzzotti, E (2014) Accountability Deficits of Delegative Democracy. In Brinks, D, Leiras, M and Mainwaring, S (eds), Reflections on Uneven Democracies: The Legacy of Guillermo O'Donnell. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 269286.Google Scholar
Rae, D (1967) The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Rasch, BE and Tsebelis, G (2011) The Role of Governments in Legislative Agenda Setting. Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Riggs, FW (1988) The Survival of Presidentialism in America: Para-Constitutional Practices. International Political Science Review 9(4), 247278. https://doi.org/10.1177/019251218800900401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sartori, G (1994) Comparative Constitutional Engineering: An Inquiry into Structures, Incentives and Outcomes. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Schedler, A (2013) The Politics of Uncertainty: Sustaining and Subverting Electoral Authoritarianism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shugart, MS (1998) The Inverse Relationship between Party Strength and Executive Strength: A Theory of Politicians Constitutional Choices. British Journal of Political Science 28(1), 129. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123498000088.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shugart, MS and Carey, JM (1992) Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shull, SA (1997) PresidentialCongressional Relations: Policy and Time Approaches. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strom, K (2000) Delegation and Accountability in Parliamentary Democracies. European Journal of Political Research 37, 261289. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.00513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, M (1978 [1918]) Parties and Parliament in a Reconstructed Germany. In Economy and Society, 2 vols. Berkeley: University of California Press, vol. 2, Appendix II.Google Scholar
Wilson, MC and Woldense, J (2019) Contested or Established? A Comparison of Legislative Powers across Regimes. Democratization 26(4), 585605. https://doi.org/10.1080/13510347.2018.1564282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Sample Summary of Cases by Region, Country and Executive Type, 1976–2014

Figure 1

Table 2. Frequencies of Change in Legislative–Executive Relations

Figure 2

Table 3. Illustrative Examples of Change in the Executive–Legislative Balance of Power

Figure 3

Table 4. Independent Variables in the Analysis

Figure 4

Table 5. Predictors of Power Shifts in Executive Oversight Patterns (Multinomial Regression Coefficients and Standard Errors)

Figure 5

Figure 1a. Probability that Democratization Will Empower the Assembly in Oversight, by Executive Format (predicted probabilities with 95% confidence intervals)Note: Predicted probabilities in Figures 1a, 1b, 2a, 2b are estimated from binary logistic regression of the effects of levels of electoral democracy on change (either to the assembly or the executive) for each executive format.

Figure 6

Figure 1b. Probability that Democratization Will Empower the Executive in Oversight, by Executive Format (predicted probabilities with 95% confidence intervals)

Figure 7

Table 6. Predictors of Power Shifts in Lawmaking Patterns (Multinomial Regression Coefficients and Standard Errors)

Figure 8

Figure 2a. Probability that Democratization Will Empower the Assembly in Lawmaking Authority, by Executive Format (predicted probabilities with 95% confidence intervals)

Figure 9

Figure 2b. Probability that Democratization Will Empower the Executive in Lawmaking Authority, by Executive Format (predicted probabilities with 95% confidence intervals)