A. Introduction
There is no unified definition of the term “state capitalism,” despite its wide use in the economics, finance, management, international business, and legal literature. Scholars have deployed the concept to refer to an extremely wide array of practices, policy instruments and vehicles, institutional forms, relations, and networks that involve the state to different degrees and at a variety of levels, time frames, and scales.Footnote 1 In this Article, state capitalism is seen as a particular organizational and governance form in emerging and transition economies. It refers to an economic system in which the state uses various tools for proactive intervention in economic production and the functioning of markets.Footnote 2
State capitalism is not new. It has been around for almost as long as capitalism itself. Every rising power has relied on the state to kickstart growth or at least to protect fragile industries.Footnote 3 State capitalism had a gradual global expansion between the late nineteenth century and the 1970s, during which state-owned enterprises (SOEs) were considered as necessary solutions for coordination problems and market failures and as an important tool to overcome the difficulties of regulating certain natural monopolies.Footnote 4 However, as a consequence of the oil shocks of the 1970s and the global liquidity crisis of the early 1980s, governments began to rethink the role of SOEs in the state apparatus and a major overhaul of systems of state capitalism through massive privatization programs started in the 1980s and 1990s.Footnote 5 Yet the privatization itself was not as sweeping as what was portrayed in the literature. Governments around the world kept large SOEs, either because they were in politically sensitive industries or simply because it was difficult to privatize them.Footnote 6
Since the early 2000s, state capitalism has re-emerged as a genuine challenge to free-market capitalism. Two main reasons account for the recent comeback of state capitalism. For one, the height of the post-Cold War global wave of democratization in the developing world has stalled and gone into reverse.Footnote 7 State capitalism can be an effect of the rollback of political reform combined with extensive state involvement in the economy being an entrenched characteristic with long historical roots in the emerging markets and in the post-socialist countries.Footnote 8 The second reason is the failing of the Washington Consensus which captured the imaginations of developing countries in pursuing economic development in the 1990s.Footnote 9 The financial crisis has further enhanced the appeal of state capitalism. Around the world, economists, policymakers, and ordinary citizens have increasingly come to see neoliberalism has reached its limits.Footnote 10
The rise of state capitalism has brought about a wide range of concerns. Some of these concerns are that state capitalism will foster democratic regression, which will further undermine political stability in some strategically important developing countries; that state capitalism fails in the long run so badly that it may be a cause of major economic collapses in developing nations, taking down the rest of their regions and seriously undermining the world economy; and that, if state capitalism succeeds in the long term, it could help China and other authoritarian but efficient state capitalists to remake the liberal international economic system, amass strategic power, and potentially use SOEs as weapons of trade and investment policy.Footnote 11 It is now widely acknowledged that the competition of liberal capitalism and the state capitalism, with the United States and China as their leading example respectively, will shape the future of the global economy.Footnote 12
State capitalism has come in different varieties.Footnote 13 China is by far the biggest and most influential torch bearer of state capitalism. For example, even if market-oriented reforms have led to a rapid expansion of the private sector in China, SOEs continue to dominate commanding heights of the Chinese economy.Footnote 14 There are more than 150,000 SOEs in China today and their share in employment was between 5 percent and 16 percent in 2017.Footnote 15 The evidence confirms that China’s economy has in some respects become more state-controlled since the 1990s and early 2000s. In the mid-1990s, China’s SOEs contributed to only about 10 percent of China’s annual gross domestic product (GDP), but by 2017, SOEs had grown so much that they contributed to 23 to 28 percent of China’s GDP, even though the total number of SOEs has reduced.Footnote 16 More than one thousand SOEs are listed on China’s stock markets, accounting for 44 percent of total market capitalization and 50 percent of revenues of publicly listed companies.Footnote 17 In 2021, 143 Chinese firms appeared on the list of Fortune Global 500, among which 82 were SOEs.Footnote 18 It has been widely accepted that SOEs are, and will be, a hallmark of China’s state capitalism model, rather than a transitional phenomenon leading to liberal capitalism as many critics of SOEs had expected.Footnote 19
Not only do Chinese SOEs play a key role in China’s domestic economy, they are also an important player in international trade as well as a major force in implementing the Government of China (GOC)’s ambitious “Go Out” strategy and more recently the Belt and Road Initiative (BRI), the Chinese paramount leader Xi Jinping’s signature foreign policy undertaking.Footnote 20 Earlier statistics showed that at least 80 percent of all China’s outbound foreign direct investment was funded by SOEs. With the growing strength of privately-owned enterprises (POEs) in China, a smaller proportion of China’s outbound investment is coming from SOEs. Still, the evidence shows that of 650 Chinese investments in Europe from 2010 to 2020, roughly 40 percent have moderate to high involvement by state-owned or state-controlled companies.Footnote 21 As of October 2018, Chinese SOEs contracted about half of BRI projects by number and more than 70 percent by project value.Footnote 22 Indeed, Chinese SOEs lie at the center of China’s top-down, state-driven trade strategy to push for indigenous innovation, driving self-sufficiency, and enhancing national security.Footnote 23
The expansion of Chinese SOEs’ global footprint has caused widespread concerns about their implications for national security, fair competition, reciprocity, transparency, corruption, the function of free market at home and the future of the rule-based liberal international economic order.Footnote 24 Concomitant to the rise of China’s state capitalism, there is a growing perception that the current WTO rules are neither conceptually coherent nor practically effective in tackling heterodox institutional forms such as China’s state capitalism because the multilateral trade regime that took shape in the post-war period simply did not anticipate many of the special features of China’s state capitalism.Footnote 25 Consequently, states such as the United States have resorted to unilateral trade measure to counteract Chinese SOEs’ competitive advantages in international economy.Footnote 26 On the international front, states have adopted new trade rules in regulating SOEs’ behavior through bilateral and regional free trade agreements (FTAs). Different from earlier FTAs, a separate and extensive SOE chapter features in almost all new-generation mega-regional FTAs, such as the Comprehensive and Progressive Trans-Pacific Partnership (CPTPP), the United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA), and the EU-Canada Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA) and the EU-China Comprehensive Investment Agreement (CAI)Footnote 27 Significantly, China formally submitted a request to accede to the CPTPP in September 2021.Footnote 28 China’s accession request is a clear indication that China is prepared to accept the SOE rules embodied in the CPTPP. Yet there are serious doubts about the effectiveness of the new trade norms on SOEs, arguing that they add little beyond the WTO rules and the rules contained in China’s WTO Accession Protocol.Footnote 29
This Article is premised on the assumption that diagnosis should precede prescription. Although public debates have demonstrated deep anxiety over the resurgence of China’s state capitalism in global economy, the features, institutional mechanisms, and global trade implications of China’s state capitalism remain poorly understood. This Article contributes to the debate of what trade rules may be needed to counteract China’s state capitalism by unpacking the black box of China’s state capitalism: how is this model embedded in China’s political and economic context? What are the pros and cons of China’s state capitalism model? How has the model evolved in the Xi Jinping era in light of new waves of SOE reforms? Armed with an exploration of the nature of China’s state capitalism, this Article will proceed to an evaluation of new trade rules in FTAs designed to counteract China’s state capitalism. Although the new rules on subsidies and SOEs in FTAs represent an important improvement over the WTO disciplines,Footnote 30 this Article seeks to explain why they are unlikely to be successful when applying to Chinese SOEs.
The Article proceeds as follows. Part B introduces the debate on the pros and cons of China’s state capitalism model. Part C provides an overview of China’s SOE reforms in the past four decades, highlighting the close relationship between Chinese SOEs and the Chinese Party-state and the blurred boundary between SOEs and large successful POEs in China. Part D explores whether the new SOE rules in mega-regional FTAs, in particular the CPTPP, are fit for purpose when applying to Chinese SOEs. It argues that although the new SOE norms in the CPTPP are promising, it is far from clear that they will be effective in constraining Chinese SOEs. This Article ends with a short conclusion that reflects on the tenacious challenges of Chinese SOEs to the liberal international trade order and urges the GOC to utilize external pressure as incentive to push forward market-oriented SOE reforms.
B. The Debate on China’s State Capitalism
For a long time, leading Western economists have been questioning whether China’s state capitalism is a sustainable development model that could succeed in the long term. For example, China collapse theorists have been touting China’s coming financial and economic meltdown caused by the failure of state economic policies for over two decades.Footnote 31 However, there is mounting evidence that China’s state capitalism is far more resilient than was conventionally assumed. Given the right conditions, China’s state capitalism may work as a long-term economic strategy, and it could be a serious competitor for the free market model in the twenty-first century.Footnote 32
Indeed, China’s meteoric economic rise has challenged some fundamental assumptions of the superiority of free market capitalism. As Xi Jinping has highlighted, one key advantage of China’s state capitalism is to enable the Chinese government to make decisions efficiently, to coordinate the efforts and to mobilize the resources across the whole country to accomplish large undertakings.Footnote 33 That is true to some extent. For example, China’s state capitalism has enjoyed some tremendous success in building infrastructure projects. At the beginning of the 21st century, China had no high-speed railways. Today China has by far the world’s largest network of high-speed railways. No fewer than 37,900 kilometers (approximately 23,500 miles) of lines crisscross the country, linking all of its major mega-city clusters, and all have been completed since 2008.Footnote 34 China’s mobile-phone network is the world’s largest, and China boasts the world’s biggest number of internet users, nearly 1 billion by the end of 2020.Footnote 35
Nevertheless, it has long been argued that although China’s state capitalism system is good at infrastructure projects, it is not so good at innovation. Josh Lerner famously described state-sponsored innovation as a “boulevard of broken dreams.”Footnote 36 Relying on a seemingly limitless supply of cheap labor, China devoted itself to the production of other countries’ innovations and earned a reputation as a global copycat. With its pool of younger workers shrinking, China will have to rely on innovation instead. But China is not innovation-friendly because the political world in which the business needs to operate is very much bounded.Footnote 37 That view was recently challenged by an alternative proposition that one should recognize that state capitalists are copying and innovating at the same time, and that the state’s role in promoting innovation cannot be simply ignored. For instance, one feature of China’s innovation ecosystem is that hundreds of millions of Chinese consumers have developed an astonishing propensity for adopting and adapting to innovations. That gives China a huge innovation advantage because innovations must be judged by people’s willingness to use them.Footnote 38
Another example is the efficiency of Chinese SOEs. The majority of the empirical literature found that Chinese SOEs performed poorly compared to POEs both for financial performance and innovation.Footnote 39 As mighty leviathans of the Chinese planned economy, Chinese SOEs were long depicted as “muscle-bound goons” or the “relics of a failed economic experiment,” characterized as possessing a lack of managerial flair, little concern for profit, low employee motivation and mobility, and a tendency to maximize corporate size.Footnote 40 A variety of reasons account for the relatively poor performance of SOEs. To begin with, the classic agency theory suggests that the separation of ownership and control in large firms gives rise to a misalignment of incentives between shareholders and managers. Managers may pursue a personal agenda for their own interests rather than work for the interest of shareholders.Footnote 41 The agency problem is exacerbated in SOEs due to the weak monitoring of state assets caused by high costs of monitoring, as well as the lack of incentives on the part of supervisory government officials who represent the state.Footnote 42 Another cause of inefficiency of state ownership is the so-called “soft budget constraint” problem. When SOEs face financial distress, the government often bails them out because the state is ultimately accountable for the losses of SOEs. SOEs could count on surviving even after chronic losses.Footnote 43 Finally, during the process of China’s economic development, SOEs are not only expected to be profit-oriented, but also to fulfill various government policy objectives, such as maintaining the employment of redundant workers which contributed to social stability, developing national strategic industries, leading sectoral and regional restructuring, maintaining macroeconomic stability by increasing investment when growth slows, and even contributing to natural disaster management.Footnote 44 The policy burdens negatively affect Chinese SOEs’ investment decisions and corporate performance.Footnote 45
However, it is not always the case that SOEs perform poorly compared to POEs. The relationship between state ownership and the financial performance of firms varies greatly across national contexts. For example, Singapore’s government-owned companies are comparable to the most profitable POEs in efficiency.Footnote 46 One recent IMF research study suggests that SOEs perform as well as POEs in core sectors (mining, electricity and gas, water, and transport) when corruption is low.Footnote 47 Others found that the political ideology of the government (e.g., economic liberals or economic socialists), both independently and in conjunction with political institutions (state capacity and political constraint) affects the financial performance of SOEs.Footnote 48 It is also argued that China’s SOEs have a positive impact on China’s long-term economic growth by undertaking policy burdens because SOEs stabilize growth in economic downturns by carrying out massive investments; promote technical progress by investing in riskier areas of technology; and follow a high-road approach to compensation and benefits which is favorable for China to move toward a more sustainable growth model in the future.Footnote 49
As will be examined closely in Part C below, it is unrealistic today to uphold the simplistic and pessimistic view of Chinese SOEs as industrial dinosaurs fit only for dismemberment or bankruptcy after extensive reforms over the past four decades. Chinese SOEs have vastly improved their corporate governance and financial performance, some of which can rival the best private-sector multinational corporations in the world.Footnote 50 They have become competitive by leading on new technologies, finding niches, exploiting economies of scale, using cheaper labor, working harder, and making investments that pay off, other than relying on domestic monopolies and state supports.Footnote 51 Significantly, Chinese SOEs are no longer content to dominate China’s domestic market. They have proactively engaged in global partnerships and acquisitions, aiming to become global champions.Footnote 52
My argument is not that China’ SOEs are as efficient as or even better than POEs. The point is simply that Chinese SOEs have drastically improved their performance and that they are serious competitors to private multinationals in global markets. More importantly, even if China’s SOEs are not so efficient economically, they will continue to exist for the foreseeable future for political reasons.Footnote 53 In the Chinese context, as an authoritarian Party-state, the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) cannot base its political legitimacy on free democratic elections. To cling on to power, the CCP has to ensure that it controls sufficient economic, political, and social resources.Footnote 54 Given the economic might of Chinese SOEs, they are in essence the economic foundation of the CCP’s power base. As Xi Jinping unequivocally stated, SOEs are “an important material and political basis for socialism with Chinese characteristics, serving as a key pillar and supporting force for the Party to govern and prop up the country.”Footnote 55 Ideologically, still upholding Marxism-Leninism and Mao Thought as guiding ideology, at least rhetorically, the primary goal of China’s economic reforms is to build a socialist market economy with the state-owned sector as a leading sector.Footnote 56 The political connections that SOEs have with the CCP as the sole ruling party in China and the strong ideological preference in favor of SOEs allow them to capture the political decision that SOEs must be kept and improved, rather than fully privatized.Footnote 57 Therefore, the issue of giving autonomy to SOEs and making them truly independent market entities on the one hand and strengthening monitoring of SOEs and making more and more demands on SOEs on the other hand, has been a recurrent issue in Chinese SOE reforms. It is precisely within this complex institutional environment that Chinese SOEs have evolved and transformed over the past four decades.
Nor do I argue that China’s state capitalism model is more advantageous than free market capitalism or that it is the best development strategy that other developing countries should consider following. It may be the case that state capitalism may work well in some areas but not so well in others. It is also possible for state capitalism to boost growth at one stage of development and impede it at another.Footnote 58 Nevertheless, it is submitted that there is strong evidence that China’s state capitalism has been successful enough by the standards of developing countries at any time in history to allow for growth, that it can be maintained for a long time, and that it has created a degree of legitimacy and stability for the government.Footnote 59 It is now clear that the Chinese government no longer sees state capitalism as a way-station on the road to liberal capitalism; rather, it is seen as a sustainable model in its own right.Footnote 60
C. The Transformation of China’s SOEs
SOEs have existed in China for many years, but their form, function, and implications for the global economy have changed dramatically over the past decade. To grasp the nature of Chinese SOEs, it is essential to understand China’s economic and institutional transformation from a socialist planned economy to a socialist market economy with the state-owned sector as a leading sector. The reform of Chinese SOEs lies at the center of this grand economic transformation.Footnote 61 When SOE reform started in the early 1980s, SOE reforms were deemed to be necessary in order to reduce economic losses, increase economic growth and raise living standards, from which the Chinese Communist Party (CPP) derives its governing legitimacy.Footnote 62 Fast forward now to the twenty-first century. Not only have Chinese SOEs survived in the ecology of business organizations, but they also evolved into major players in both the domestic and the global economy.Footnote 63
I. An Overview of China’s SOE Reforms (1978–2021)
1. China’s SOE Reforms before 2012
After the CCP defeated the Nationalist Party and founded the People’s Republic of China in 1949, the communist regime discarded the previous market economic order and, emulating the Soviet Union, created a socialist planned economy.Footnote 64 The new economic structure was, by and large, a replica of the Leninist model of a “state syndicate,” in which state ownership was the sole basis of almost all economic activities.Footnote 65 In the socialist planned economy era, SOEs were basically production units rather than autonomous profit-seeking corporations. The absence of autonomy and incentives were widely recognized as the central problems facing SOEs in the period prior to SOE reform.Footnote 66 Since the historic decision in 1978 to reform and open up the economy, the GOC has taken a gradual, experimental and pragmatic approach—known as “crossing the river by touching the stone”—to bring about the reform of Chinese SOEs.Footnote 67
China’s SOE reforms had gone through three distinct phases before Xi Jinping came to power in 2012. The first phase ran from the early 1980s until the early 1990s. Due to strong ideological and political perceptions of the need for the state to control all critical means of production, state ownership of SOEs remained intact in the first phase. Inspired by the success of the household responsibility system in the rural reforms in the early 1980s, reform measures in the first phase focused on increasing SOE autonomy and introducing a market mechanism to improve the performance of SOEs.Footnote 68 The contract responsibility system was introduced in 1985 to create a formalized relationship between most small and mediumsized SOEs and the government. Under the contract responsibility system, SOE managers signed contracts with the government giving them the right to run day-to-day operation and greater emphasis on SOEs’ responsibilities for profits and losses. Nevertheless, the firm remained a state asset. Profits were shared between the SOEs and the state in accordance with the terms of the contract.Footnote 69
The contract responsibility system entailed the emergence of industrial product markets and competition among SOEs. There was evidence that SOEs made some productivity gains as a result of these firm-level reforms.Footnote 70 However, it was soon viewed as inherently flawed because it did not solve the short-termism of management behavior. Managers were rewarded for their successes but not punished for their failures. This enabled managers to exploit their effective control over SOE assets for personal benefit at the expense of the state, damaging firms’ long-term development. The lack of adequate monitoring after SOEs were given managerial autonomy further contributed to SOEs’ poor performance.Footnote 71
The development of township and village enterprises (TVEs) and foreign-invested enterprises (FIEs) during this period deepened the woes of SOEs. Due to increasing competition from the private sector, SOEs stacked up huge losses.Footnote 72 In aggregate, China’s industrial SOEs no longer provided net revenues for the government and absorbed fiscal and quasi-fiscal resources that were estimated to be as large as 5 percent of the national GDP in the early 1990s.Footnote 73 The mounting losses put substantial pressure on government revenue, its fiscal burdens and banking stability and were a key factor leading to further reforms.Footnote 74
The second phase of China’s SOE reforms commenced after the historic Southern tour of Deng Xiaoping in 1992. This period was characterized by drastic ownership restructuring, with a focus on reducing the government’s holdings of SOE assets through partial or full privatization. In practice, corporatization was seen as a means of achieving ownership restructuring. The first general Chinese Company Law was enacted in order to provide for the incorporation of SOEs in 1994. Thereafter, newly corporatized SOEs proliferated all over the country.Footnote 75 Along with corporatization, central to SOE reforms in the 1990s was the policy of “nurturing the large and letting go of the small” adopted in 1995, a reference to the policy of concentrating the government’s resources and control on the larger SOEs in strategic and profitable sectors, while relaxing state control over smaller SOEs and retreating from labor-intensive competitive sectors.Footnote 76 The economic logic behind this policy was that the large firms performed much better than the smaller firms and had greater importance in the economy. Many small and medium-sized SOEs were assessed for reorganization, bankruptcy, debt write-offs, merger into partnerships, leasing, contractual operation, or sales.Footnote 77
It is vital to understand that the corporatization of Chinese SOEs did not initially and to this day does not implicate privatization of the Chinese economy or its traditional SOEs, much less any withdrawal of the Party State from the corporatized SOEs. This is because even if the incumbent Party state no longer wholly owns 100 percent of equity interest in most newly corporatized SOEs, it retains a controlling equity interest in many of them. Thus, the corporatization of SOEs leaves the control of the Party state over SOEs largely undisturbed.Footnote 78 China’s “corporatization without privatization” SOE reform has the dual effects of reducing the government’s cost burden from inefficient SOEs and creating opportunities for POEs to expand.Footnote 79 After this round of reform, the state sector shrank dramatically in absolute terms and their productivity and profitability improved.Footnote 80 Nevertheless, Chinese SOEs still lagged behind POEs and serious efficiency problems persisted.Footnote 81
The third phase of SOE reforms started in 2003 and focused on restructuring large SOEs and improving their corporate governance.Footnote 82 One key reform was the establishment of the State Assets Supervision and Administration Commission (SASAC), a quasi-governmental, ministerial level agency operating directly under the State Council. Prior to the creation of the SASAC, no single entity was ultimately responsible for an SOE’s performance, a problem known as the absence of an ultimate principal.Footnote 83 The SASAC was primarily designed to fill this regulatory lacuna, combining the administrative functions previously carried out by various government agencies. The SASAC was legally recognized as an “investor” and as such, SOEs enjoy legal rights and duties of a shareholder, holding SOE shares on behalf of the State.Footnote 84 The SASAC also enjoys a broad mandate that includes drafting regulations on the management of SOE assets, preserving and enhancing the value of state-owned assets, appointing and removing executives of SOEs under its supervision, and pushing forward further reforms of SOEs.Footnote 85 However, the SASAC does not intervene directly in SOEs’ business operations, so that the SASAC’s ownership rights are separated from those of management.Footnote 86
The GOC has consistently emphasized the control of large SOEs in strategic industries. The logic behind the policy is “less is more,” for example, by controlling the most powerful and profitable SOEs in strategic industries, the state can maintain disproportionate control over profits, investments, and the national economy.Footnote 87 Accordingly, the State-owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission of the State Council (SASAC) serves as a unitary holding company for non-financial “central SOEs”. When the SASAC was established in 2003, 196 central SOEs were under its direct supervision. Under the oversight of SASAC, that number was reduced to 96 by May 2022, as the smaller and less competitive firms were absorbed by the larger ones.Footnote 88 Although not large in number, the size and importance of Central SOEs to the national economy in many respects surpass that of all the other SOEs combined.Footnote 89 Out of 96 central SOEs, 49 were ranked in the Fortune Global 500 in 2021.Footnote 90 Chinese central SOEs are the most powerful economic force in Chinese economy, representing the core of state capitalism in China.
2. SOE Reforms in the Xi Jinping Era (2013–Present)
The fourth and the most recent phase of SOE reforms has started from the third plenum of the 18th CCP Congress held in November 2013 until now. In this “Xi Jinping era,” the Chinese central authorities laid out important directions for reforming SOE governance and operation structure, including: 1) defining the functions of SOEs to determine levels of state ownership and control; 2) promoting mixed ownership with cross holding between state-owned capital and private capital; 3) shifting from state-owned asset management to state-owned capital management; and 4) improving corporate governance of SOEs.Footnote 91 The core document guiding the overhaul of SOEs issued in 2015, Guiding Opinions of the CPC Central Committee and the State Council on Deepening the Reform of SOEs (the “One”) is supplemented by a wide range of supporting policies (the “N”). The comprehensive and thorough Chinese SOE reform in the fourth phase of Chinese SOE reforms has been guided by the “One Plus N” policy framework.Footnote 92
First, Chinese SOEs were classified as commercial SOEs and public service SOEs. Commercial SOEs are further divided into SOEs in fully competitive sectors and SOEs in strategic sectors (i.e., key industries related to national security and national economic lifelines). Commercial SOEs should stick to commercial operations and aim to increase state-owned assets, while public service SOEs exist to improve people’s quality of life and provide public goods and services. Accordingly, different levels of state ownership and control, growth strategies, regulations, and evaluations are outlined based on the classification of SOEs. For instance, commercial SOEs in fully competitive sectors will be evaluated according to financial performance metrics whilst commercial SOEs in strategic sectors will be evaluated not only in terms of their business performance indicators, but also on their efforts to serve important national strategies, safeguard national security and the operation of the national economy.Footnote 93
Second, the purpose of the mixed ownership reform (MOR) is to bring private-sector investment and management into SOEs to improve the efficiency and governance of the state sector.Footnote 94 The MOR applied specific sectoral policies. Commercial SOEs in fully competitive sectors shall actively attract other state capital and non-state capital to diversify equity, and state capital may take only a minority position. In contrast, state capital should maintain the position as the controlling or sole shareholder in strategic and public service SOEs and encourages non-state capital to become minority shareholders.Footnote 95 A significant example of the MOR was the share sale plan for China Unicom, China’s second-largest telecom carrier. It was announced in August 2017 that it would sell US$11.7 billion in shares worth 35 percent of its Shanghai-listed subsidiary to a group of fourteen private and state investors, including tech giants Alibaba, Baidu, Tencent and JD.com. The sale saw China Unicom’s stake in the listed subsidiary drop from 63 percent to 37 percent, but still the largest shareholder.Footnote 96 By the end of 2020, more than 70 percent of central SOEs and 54 percent of local SOEs had completed the MOR.Footnote 97
Third, the role of the SASAC at the central and local levels will shift from “asset management” to “capital management.” Specifically, two types of investment holding companies, state capital investment companies and state capital operation companies, were established under the auspices of the SASAC or directly under the local governments to serve as the state shareholder in SOEs. Both state capital investment and operation companies are authorized to perform the role of the shareholder and participate in the governance of the SOEs in which they invested through nominating directors and supervisors and voting in shareholders’ meetings. However, they would not intervene in the daily operations of the SOEs.Footnote 98 The SASAC, in turn, will become the state shareholder in such state capital investment or operation companies. The rationale for creating such state capital companies is to establish a firewall between the SASAC and the SOEs so as to stop the tendency for the SASAC to become involved in the business operation of SOEs.Footnote 99
Fourth, another key point of the SOE reforms since 2013, is the call for ongoing government-directed mergers to make SOEs “stronger, better and bigger.”Footnote 100 The consolidation of SOEs is motivated by both economic and political factors. Economically, it would eliminate unprofitable SOEs, cut excess industrial capacity and overlapping investment, minimize competition among SOEs, and increase economies of scale. Moreover, the consolidation would create more competitive “national champions” abroad with increased size and market share. Politically, SOE consolidation would increase state control over the economy.Footnote 101 A significant example of SOE megamergers was the merger of China’s two state-owned railway companies, CSR Corp and CNR Corp, resulting in the creation of China Railway Rolling Stock Corporation (CRRC), now the world’s largest train builder and second-largest industrial company.Footnote 102 Other examples include a merger between Shenhua Group (China’s largest coal miner) and Guodian Group (one of China’s largest power generation companies in August 2017). The new company, China Energy Investment Corp., has become the world’s largest power company with assets totaling $271 billion.Footnote 103
Finally, one unprecedented initiative in the new round of SOE reforms was to strengthen and institutionalize the role of the CCP in SOE governance. One motivation for this initiative is plainly to counterbalance the potential loss of Party control over the state sector accompanying an increase in private-capital investment.Footnote 104 All Chinese SOEs, including those listed on stock markets, were mandated to incorporate the CCP’s leadership role into their articles of association.Footnote 105 The Constitution of the CCP was revised in October 2017, which specified that “the party committee of SOEs shall play a leadership role, set the right direction, keep in mind the big picture, ensure the implementation of party policies and principles, and discuss and decide on major issues of SOEs.”Footnote 106 The campaign to strengthen the party leadership in SOEs is further institutionalized in the Trial Regulation on the Work at Primary-Level Party Organization of SOEs issued by the CCP Central Committee in December 2019.Footnote 107 The board of directors must hear the opinions of the party committee before deciding on important issues. The chairperson of the board of directors should ordinarily be the party secretary of a SOE. A cross-appointment system was introduced to ensure that SOEs’ party committee members are appointed to key positions and hold decision-making power.Footnote 108 The formalized role of the CCP in SOE governance has closed the gap between SOE boardrooms and the CCP’s strategic goals.Footnote 109
To further implement SOE reforms discussed above, the SASAC has unveiled a “Three-year Action Plan for SOE Reforms (2020-2022),” setting out a clear roadmap as well as specific targets to meet.Footnote 110 Based on a series of performance indicators, Chinese SOEs have become stronger after the recent round of SOE reforms. They are now much less leveraged compared to the leverage level before 2016. The shrinking trend of SOEs both in numbers and the proportion of SOEs’ assets in the industrial sector has been reversed and stabilized.Footnote 111
II. Chinese SOEs and the Chinese Party-State
Through most of the history of China’s SOE reforms, the predominant concerns of Chinese policymakers were SOEs’ low efficiency and poor incentives for SOE managers. SOE reforms were therefore focused on improving their performance and profitability. Precisely for this reason, the government has been ordered to retreat from SOE governance, not to interfere with the day-to-day management at the firm level and make SOEs independent market entities.Footnote 112 However, when SOEs have become vastly more profitable, Chinese policymakers are expecting SOEs to spearhead China’s development objectives, pioneering technological advance, maintaining macroeconomic stability, and implementing major government strategies such as the BRI. At the same time, while the GOC has been retreating from interfering in SOE management and more autonomy was granted to SOEs, the CCP has institutionalized its control of SOEs.Footnote 113 Xi Jinping openly asserted that party leadership and strengthening party building are the “root and soul” of Chinese SOEs, and that SOE executives shall “bear in mind that their number one role and responsibility is to work for the party.” The tenet of Chinese SOE reforms is succinctly described as “the Party’s leadership over SOEs is a major political principle, it must be steadfastly upheld; the establishment of modern enterprise system is the direction of SOE reform, it also must be steadfastly upheld.”Footnote 114
To be sure, the overall SOE policy under Xi in many aspects exhibits a deepening of pre-existing trends rather than a decisive departure.Footnote 115 The core goal of molding SOEs that are both market competitive and following the Party line has remained consistent in the Xi Era. Still, the scale of institutionalizing, legalizing, and enhancing of the Party’s role in SOEs’ corporate governance is unprecedented, which some termed as “party-state capitalism” or the “politicization of corporate governance.”Footnote 116
While strengthening the Party’ leadership role may help limit opportunistic behavior and decrease mismanagement in the SOEs,Footnote 117 the fundamental challenge of this new approach is that there are important contradictions and tensions among the objectives of increasing Party control and giving firms more political and developmental missions, on the one hand, and improving their incentives, corporate governance, and financial flexibility on the other hand.Footnote 118 Not only must managers scramble to meet multiple inconsistent targets, they must also use the trade-off among targets to deflect demands for rigorous profit maximization.Footnote 119 In China’s institutional context, the principle of party leadership would inevitably assign much greater weight to safeguarding the Party-state’s interests rather than to the principle of corporate governance such as maximizing shareholder value in case there is a conflict.Footnote 120 To understand the behavioral logic of Chinese SOEs in both national and international markets, it is enlightening to look closely at how the Chinese Party-state exercises authority over Chinese SOEs.
One key tool for the CCP to ensure its control over SOEs is “personnel power,” authority to appoint, evaluate, rotate, and remove SOEs’ top management.Footnote 121 The leaders of SOEs are appointed in accordance with a highly institutionalized cadre management system to ensure the principle of “absolute control of the (SOE) executives by the Party.”Footnote 122 By directly managing SOE executives’ careers, the Party shapes managerial incentives and in turn influences the corporate behavior of China’s SOEs. Different from their western counterparts who stand at the top of the corporate hierarchy and rely on active external labor market for executive career opportunities, top executives in Chinese SOEs have limited opportunities outside the state apparatus.Footnote 123 However, they have ample upward potential in the political arena by being appointed to senior party leader or government official positions, which would allow them to climb the political ladder in the Party-state hierarchy, bringing them more prestige and a higher political status.Footnote 124 Consequently, when financial and state goals are in conflict, the incentives SOE executives face tend to push them to choose state interests over financial interests of the firm and other non-state shareholders.Footnote 125
Another key mechanism for the CCP to exercise its authority over SOEs is by institutionalizing Party committees’ leadership role in SOE corporate governance. Previously, there was an implicit division of labor between SOE Party committees and formal corporate governance institutions prescribed in Chinese Company Law such as the shareholder meeting, the board of directors and the supervisory board. As the “political core” of SOEs, SOE Party committees focused mainly on political, social and personnel matters, such as selecting and evaluating senior personnel, recruiting Party members, circulating political propaganda materials, and organizing study sessions. The board of directors led commercial decision-making with shareholder input and supervisory board oversight.Footnote 126 By contrast, the new round of SOE reforms specifies that the Party committee in the SOEs serves a “leadership core” function as well as a “political core” function. A SOE’s Party committee has authority to deliberate and discuss major issues concerning the reform, development, and stability of the firm, as well as major operational and managerial issues. The board of directors shall first listen to the opinions of the Party committee before deciding on major issues.Footnote 127
The strengthening of the Party’s leadership role in SOEs entails several profound implications. To begin with, there is a risk that the oversight functions of conventional internal governance mechanisms, such as the board of directors, the supervisory board, and independent directors, are being supplanted by political incentive mechanisms and Party committees that are deployed within the SOEs. With both the board of directors and the Party committee prescribed to be the decision-making bodies in the SOEs, the obvious challenge is how to divide the power between the two to ensure that the Party committee’s involvement in the decision-making process will not undermine the power of the board of directors to make independent decisions. Moreover, bolstering the Party Committee’s leadership role risks undermining the MOR of SOEs because it underscores the Party state’s willingness to subordinate commercial objectives to political imperatives.Footnote 128 It will further exacerbate POEs’ concerns about how their interests as minority shareholders would be protected as their stake in SOEs is unlikely to grant them real power.Footnote 129 Finally, the move to strengthen Party control of SOEs will exacerbate the rising perception that SOEs are simply Chinese Party state’s policy instruments to exercise governmental functions and implement government strategies.Footnote 130
III. The Porous Boundary of SOEs and Privately-owned Enterprises in China
The international trade and investment regimes frequently draw a stark distinction between SOEs and POEs. Because SOEs are controlled by the state, they are widely believed to be uniquely positioned to capture state-generated rents such as privileged market access, receipt of state subsidies, and de facto exemption from competition laws. POEs, by contrast, are often idealized as insulated from government intervention. Consequently, extra trade and investment disciplines are considered necessary to ensure competitive neutrality between SOEs and POEs.Footnote 131 However, the formalistic distinction between SOEs and large successful POEs tend to break down in the institutional environment in China.Footnote 132 With a long tradition of state dominance in the economy, underdeveloped legal institutions, relatively inchoate conceptions of property rights and omnipresent Party leadership, the party-state enjoys fairly extensive informal control rights over POEs, even in the absence of state ownership. Indeed, large POEs, similar to large SOEs, survive and prosper precisely because they have fostered connections to state power and have succeeded in obtaining state-generated rents.Footnote 133
Empirical evidence has shown the value of political connections to Chinese POEs. For example, it was difficult for even large and profitable but less politically connected firms to list shares on Chinese stock exchanges through initial public offerings. These good firms were forced to go public through reverse mergers, an unconventional and much more costly route to access public financing.Footnote 134 Likewise, politically connected POEs were more likely to win commercial lawsuits in Chinese courts and to obtain loans from state-owned banks.Footnote 135 It is also not unusual for large, successful POEs to receive state subsidies. For example, Huawei is legally an independent, privately held company. Huawei’s shares are held by its employees through an Employee Stock Ownership Plan.Footnote 136 Yet it was reported that Huawei had access to as much as $75 billion in tax breaks, financing and cheap resources from the GOC as it grew to the world’s largest telecommunications equipment company.Footnote 137 More revealingly, while the party-building amendments to corporate charters are mandatory for SOEs in the new round of SOE reform, the policy is not even directed at private firms. Nevertheless, almost 6 percent of listed POEs amended their charters to include some type of party-building provisions from 2015 through 2018 as a means of signaling fealty to the CCP.Footnote 138
Consequently, as Milhaupt and Zheng observed, functionally, “SOEs and large POEs in China share many similarities in the areas commonly thought to distinguish state-owned firms from privately owned firms: market access, receipt of state subsidies, proximity to state power, and execution of the government’s policy objectives.”Footnote 139 To be sure, the claim is not that corporate ownership is completely irrelevant in China or that Chinese POEs are identical in all respects to SOEs, but that the relationship between POEs and the GOC is complex, shifting, and variegated with respect to the level and quality of governmental intrusion, and that the boundary between SOEs and POEs is sometimes blurred in China’s weak institutional setting.
D. Is the CPTPP an Ideal Model for the Regulation of Chinese SOEs?
The increased presence of SOEs in international trade and global value chains have given rise to a range of regulatory concerns.Footnote 140 One key concern is that SOEs in China often benefit from credits extended by state banks or other forms of financing, implicit guarantees, capital injections, and preferential access to inputs. In addition, the Chinese government may provide SOEs with certain regulatory advantages or influence them to confer such advantages on other entities. That would tilt the playing field and create distortive effects on international trade.Footnote 141 Moreover, state ownership has a negative effect on transparency of multinational enterprises.Footnote 142 Chinese SOEs are particularly criticized for their lack of transparency compared to POEs.Footnote 143 The lack of transparency around SOEs has contributed to growing levels of anxieties over their national security and competitive neutrality implications. The more pronounced presence of SOEs in the global marketplace has also been marked by certain high-profile scandals and occasional evidence of susceptibility of SOEs to corruption or human rights violations.Footnote 144 In 2014, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) reported that 81 percent (by value) of the foreign bribery cases investigated between 1999 and 2013 were promised, offered or given to SOE officials.Footnote 145
The GATT recognized that, by acting as a trader, a government may influence the direction of international trade through its purchase and sales decisions. Nevertheless, international trade disciplines on SOEs in the GATT/WTO regime are limited in scope and are perceived as inadequate.Footnote 146 For example Article XVII:1 imposes on state trading enterprises (STEs) the core obligation to undertake purchases and sales on a non-discriminatory basis and solely in accordance with commercial considerations involving either imports or exports. However, the application of Article XVII.1 is flawed in at least three important aspects. First, it is unclear whether the non-discriminatory treatment in Article XVII:1 extends beyond a requirement of MFN treatment and includes a NT obligation.Footnote 147 The negotiating history suggests that Article XVII:1 was not intended to include a NT obligation and the GATT/WTO panels declined to take a position on this issue.Footnote 148 Second, the AB held that the “commercial considerations” requirement in Article XVII.1 does not impose a distinctive obligation on STEs, and that it suffices for STEs to act in in a non-discriminatory manner to comply with the provision.Footnote 149 Third, the AB clarified that the obligation to act solely in accordance with commercial considerations does not require STEs to refrain from using their exclusive or special privileges simply because such use might disadvantage competing commercial actors. The only constraint is that they should be used to make sales which are driven exclusively by commercial considerations.Footnote 150 While it is questionable whether the AB’s interpretation of acting in accordance with commercial considerations is correct as economic logic would not support this view, there is not one single deviation from this case law in the GATT/WTO history.Footnote 151
Because of the perceived inadequacy of existing WTO rules on SOEs, FTAs provide a new avenue to adopt innovative SOE disciplines.Footnote 152 A typical example is the Comprehensive and Progressive Trans-Pacific Partnership (CPTPP) concluded in 2018. Largely built upon the SOE disciplines contained in some FTAs that the U.S. had signed before, the CPTPP included a stand-alone chapter that applies “with respect to the activities of state-owned enterprises that affect trade or investment.”Footnote 153 The inclusion of the SOE chapter in the CPTPP represents the most ambitious attempt of the international community to regulate SOEs in international trade up to date.Footnote 154 It is therefore helpful to critically analyze the SOE rules in the CPTPP and interrogate how effective they may be in addressing the challenges posed by Chinese SOEs.
The SOE chapter of the CPTPP has a number of novel features, including a bright line definition of SOEs, cumulative obligations of non-discriminatory treatment and commercial considerations, prohibition of non-commercial assistance to SOE service providers, and better enforcement mechanisms. Fundamentally, the CPTPP seeks to achieve a more level playing field—regulatory and competitive neutrality—for both SOEs and POEs.Footnote 155 Nevertheless, as will be argued below, it is far from clear whether the CPTPP would provide an ideal model for the regulation of Chinese SOEs.Footnote 156
I. Is the Definition of SOE too Narrow?
One of the main issues regarding the disciplines on SOEs in international law is the lack of a clear and consistent definition of what SOEs are. Article XVII of the GATT defines STEs as “Governmental and non-governmental enterprises, including marketing boards, which have been granted exclusive or special rights or privileges, including statutory or constitutional powers, in the exercise of which they influence through their purchases or sales the level or direction of imports or exports.”Footnote 157 Although there might be some overlapping between the notion of an STE and that of an SOE, the two are not synonymous. For instance, a private enterprise without state ownership can be a STE. On the other hand, SOEs cover a wider remit than STEs because the latter is limited to SOEs with special rights or privileges.Footnote 158 Indeed, only a few Chinese SOEs having the exclusive right to import or export wheat, maize, sugar, tobacco, rice, cotton, crude and processed oil, refined coal, chemical fertilizers, tungsten and tungstate products, antimony, and silver are considered as STEs.Footnote 159 As the WTO concedes, the definition of STEs is far from being clear and the absence of a clear definition renders Article XVII ineffective.Footnote 160 Similarly, there is much controversy of whether SOEs are “public bodies,” and therefore can be a subsidy provider, in the SCM Agreement.Footnote 161
The CPTPP represents a paradigm shift away from the pre-existing definitions and for the first time, adopts a clear-cut rule based exclusively on quantifiable proxies to determine what a SOE is.Footnote 162 Article 17.1 of the CPTPP expressly defines a SOE in relation to two main criteria: governmental control and commercial activity. It provides that a SOE is an enterprise that is principally engaged in commercial activities and in which a party: (i) directly owns more than 50 percent of the share capital; (ii) controls, through ownership interests, the exercise of more than 50 percent of the voting rights; or (iii) holds the power to appoint a majority of members of the board of directors or any other equivalent management body.Footnote 163 Moreover, “commercial activities” are defined as “activities which an enterprise undertakes with an orientation toward profit-making and which result in the production of a good or supply of a service that will be sold to a customer in the relevant market in quantities and at prices determined by the enterprise.”Footnote 164 Thus entities engaged mainly in non-profit activities or public services are excluded. The limitation of the definition to those SOEs that are engaged in commercial activities reflects the competitionrelated concerns underlying SOE disciplines. The CPTPP does not seek to regulate SOEs when they engage in non-commercial activities that do not risk distorting competition. It is also a recognition that SOEs, in providing public services, fulfill policy objectives where private participation cannot solve market failures.Footnote 165 According to the SOE definition in the CPTPP, it is irrelevant whether an entity enjoys special privileges, monopoly status or exercises governmental authority or not. The government ownership or control of a commercial entity, by itself, is sufficient to identify a SOE.
Although a clear-cut definition eliminates uncertainties of what an SOE is, rigid rules may also weaken SOE disciplines. The quantitative thresholds defining ownership/control in the CPTPP fail to consider the many other, lower levels of ownership or board appointment that can actually be structured so as to retain governmental control, as well as situations of indirect control.Footnote 166 For example, how might interlocking directorates and indirect ownership structures influence the determination of a SOE?Footnote 167 What if the government holds less than the majority of the shares, but still constitutes the largest block of voting rights?Footnote 168 This is particularly an issue for Chinese SOEs after the MOR reform where the GOC no longer owns more than 50 percent of the shares, nor holds power to appoint a majority of the board of directors. Nevertheless, it is clear that the GOC still holds sway over the new firm after the MOR reform in China’s institutional context. An example is Yunan Baiyao, one of the most famous listed pharmaceutical companies in China. After two rounds of MOR, Yunnan SASAC now owns 25.14 percent of Yunnan Baiyao’s shares. However, it remains one of the two largest shareholders of Yunan Baiyao. Indeed, the bottom line of Yunan Baiyao’s MOR was that no single private investor could own more voting rights than Yunan SASAC.Footnote 169 Moreover, it is not clear whether the party committee still plays the role of “leadership core” in mixed ownership companies in which the state capital controls less than 51 percent of the voting rights.Footnote 170 Although the definition of SOEs in the CPTPP may be stretched to encapsulate de facto control, thereby requiring inquiry into inter-locking and indirect ownership structures as well as other forms of indirect control such as through building shareholder coalitions,Footnote 171 the concern remains that the SOE definition in the CPTPP may not be able to capture the scenarios where the state may be able to exert strong influence without meeting the quantitative thresholds. After all, it seems fairly easy for SOEs to reorganize their ownership or voting structure to circumvent the rule.Footnote 172
By comparison, under the U.S.-Singapore FTA, a SOE is an enterprise in which the Government of Singapore has “effective influence.” Importantly, effective influence may exist when the government owns less than fifty percent of the voting rights of an entity, as long as it can determine the outcome of strategic, financial or operating decisions or plans of an entity, or otherwise exercise substantial influence over the management or operation of an entity. There exists a rebuttable presumption of effective influence when the government ownership exceeds 20 percent and constitutes the largest block of voting rights of the entity.Footnote 173 The SOE definition in the U.S.-Singapore FTA was followed by the USMCA and the CAI.Footnote 174 Specifically, the CAI widens the SOE definition in the CPTPP, adding that SOEs also include those entities in which the government holds the power to control the decisions through minority ownership as well as enterprise in which the government has the power to legally direct the actions or otherwise exercise an equivalent level of control in accordance with its laws and regulations.Footnote 175 This definition is likely to broaden the SOE definition significantly and may even include some ostensible POEs in China.
II. Non-discriminatory Treatment and Commercial Considerations
Article 17.4 requires the SOEs of a CPTPP party to act on a commercial basis, and not to discriminate, in their purchases and sales of goods and services against suppliers, buyers, and investors of other CPTPP parties. Although the obligations of non-discrimination and commercial considerations in the CPTPP is plainly rooted in the GATT STE rules discussed above, there are several important changes.Footnote 176 First, Article 17.4 dissolves any uncertainty with respect to the NT principle. The non-discriminatory treatment of SOEs now explicitly incorporates both NT and MFN treatment.Footnote 177 Second, NT and MFN obligations are not restricted to trading activities in goods but extend to trade in services and investors from other parties. In a similar vein, the obligations cover not only imports and exports, but also SOEs’ activities in the markets of their home states.Footnote 178 Third, acting in accordance with commercial considerations is no longer considered as an illustration of non-discrimination treatment but an independent obligation. An SOE must cumulatively satisfy both requirements of non-discriminatory treatment and commercial considerations. Commercial considerations are defined as “the same factors, such as price, quality, availability, marketability, and other factors that a privately owned enterprise in the same business or industry would normally consider in the commercial decisions.”Footnote 179
Compared to the GATT rules on STEs, the circumscribing word “solely” was absent from Article 17.4 of the CPTPP. In the WTO Panel’s view, the requirement that STEs act solely in accordance with commercial considerations must imply that they should seek to purchase or sell on terms which are economically advantageous for themselves. An STE would not be acting solely in accordance with commercial considerations if it were to make purchases or sales on the basis of such considerations as the nationality of potential buyers or sellers, the policies pursued by their governments, or the national (economic or political) interest of the Member maintaining the STE.Footnote 180 Therefore, there are concerns that the absence of the word “solely” in the commercial considerations requirement would allow states to circumvent it by arguing that commercial considerations do not need to be solely market driven.Footnote 181 Whether Article 17.4 allows for such a flexibility is uncertain and will have to be clarified later.
Another difficulty with the obligation to act on a commercial basis is that there is no easy economic test to determine whether a firm’s behavior is commercially sound.Footnote 182 Central to determine whether a SOE has fulfilled this obligation is to inquire whether a POE may perform the same acts in normal business transactions. But actions such as selling at very low prices to hook customers can be practiced by commercially motivated firms and those with ulterior motives alike.Footnote 183 Further interpretative guidance would be helpful to clarify how to determine whether SOEs are not acting in accordance with commercial considerations.
III. Non-Commercial Assistance
It has long been argued that general principles of nondiscriminatory treatment and commercial considerations would not solve all of the issues and that there is a need for specific disciplines that address specific concerns with regard to SOEs.Footnote 184 One example is that many of the inherent advantages of SOEs boil down to direct and indirect subsidization by the government. In this regard, Article 17.6 prohibits the provision of non-commercial assistance (NCA) by the government (or SOEs) to SOEs if such assistance causes “adverse effects” to trade and investment interests of another party or “injury” to a domestic industry of another party.Footnote 185 Article 17.1 defines NCA as “assistance to a SOE by virtue of that SOE’s government ownership and control,” including direct transfers of funds or potential direct transfer of funds or liabilities as well as the provision of goods or services other than general infrastructure on terms more favorable than those commercially available to an enterprise.Footnote 186
In essence, Article 17.6 of the CPTPP extends and adapts WTO subsidy regulation to SOEs. The definition of NCA is reminiscent of the definition of “financial contributions” under Article 1 of the SCM Agreement. Similarly, the term “by virtue of that SOE’s government ownership or control” in the NCA definition, which means that the access to NCA favors SOEs as a distinct class, is in effect the specificity requirement in Article 2 of the SCM Agreement. Lastly, the requirements of “adverse effect” or “injury” also resemble Articles 6 and 15 of the SCM Agreement, although the CPTPP defines these two terms more narrowly, arguably making investigations of the violation easier.Footnote 187 Of particular significance of the NCA rules in the CPTPP is that they not only apply to the production and sale of goods by SOEs but also to assistance given to SOE in respect of services supply outside the providing party’s own territory. Therefore, a CPTPP Member is prohibited from causing adverse effects to the interests of another Member by providing NCA to the export of a service by any of its SOEs into the territory of another Member.Footnote 188 However, the NCA rules do not apply to a service supplied by a SOE within the territory of the subsidizing party.Footnote 189
Despite the fairly lengthy provisions, the bottom line is that the CPTPP does not generally inhibit NCA as such. Instead, the new rules aim at controlling certain negative effects that may arise from the NCA.Footnote 190 One may wonder to what extent the main concerns with the SCM Agreement, such as the high evidentiary burden in proving the existence of a subsidy in China, the failure of the notification process, and the ineffectiveness of remedies in disciplining subsidies, are adequately addressed in the CPTPP.Footnote 191 By contrast, the Japan-United States-European Union Trilateral Initiative proposed to expand the list of subsidies prohibited outright while creating a reversal of the burden of proof to establish negative impacts of the subsidies in some cases.Footnote 192 The USMCA contains an unconditional prohibition of three forms of NCA provided to an SOE primarily engaged in the production of goods other than electricity.Footnote 193
IV. Will Extensive Carve-Outs Hollow Out the SOE Rules?
The SOE disciplines in the CPTPP are considerably limited by extensive carve-outs and exceptions in recognition of the need for governments to retain some leeway to continue the pursuit of policy objectives through SOEs. Article 17.2 enumerates several areas that are not included within the scope of the SOE chapter: regulatory and supervisory measures from a central bank or a monetary authority; regulatory or supervisory measures over financial services suppliers; measures adopted for the purpose of a failing or failed financial institution; sovereign wealth fund; independent pension fund; government procurement; the provision of goods and services by a SOE to carry out a party’s governmental functions; and the establishment or the maintaining of a SOE. Article 17.9 provides the possibility for each party to list elements to which SOE disciplines shall not apply. States can list in their schedule to Annex IV non-conforming activities of SOEs.Footnote 194 Article 17.13 allows more flexibility for SOEs by excluding from the obligations smaller SOEs, the adoption of temporary measures in response to a national or global economic emergency, as well as the supply of financial services by a SOE pursuant to a government mandate.Footnote 195
While some exemptions are quite sensible, such as the exemptions of smaller SOEs, government procurement and services supplied in the exercise of governmental authority, other exemptions are more controversial, such as a sweeping exemption for SOEs that a sub-central level government owns or controls, state-owned domestic service providers and SWFs. Combined with reservations and specific exceptions contained in the annexes and side agreements, which go quite far and include a wide range of enterprises, scholars noted that there are more pages devoted to exceptions than there are to the general rules themselves.Footnote 196 Apparently, this complex legal framework resulted from political compromises as different states have different views of SOEs and some CPTPP parties continue to rely heavily on SOEs. Still, looking at the extensive carve-outs, the question arises whether the totality of all exemptions and exceptions in the CPTPP does not render the substantial provisions rather useless.Footnote 197
The challenges are even more acute when applying these exemptions to Chinese SOEs. For example, the exemption of sub-central SOEs considerably limits the scope of application of SOE rules. But sub-central SOEs are equally capable of severely distorting international investment. After extensive restructuring and reorganization of the state sector in China, there are only 96 central SOEs under the direct supervision of the SASAC. At the same time, there are hundreds of thousands of sub-central SOEs flourishing in China, accounting for almost half of the total annual revenue of all Chinese SOEs and a quarter of all Chinese enterprises listed on the Fortune Global 500 in 2021.Footnote 198 Given that Chinese sub-central SOEs are important players in a wide range of industries of commercial significance, their exemption leaves important lacunae under the SOE rules. In this respect, it is noted that the CAI applies to Chinese SOEs at all levels of government, including sub-central SOEs.Footnote 199 Another example of the exception is SWFs. China is actively exploring the potential transformation of SOEs into SWFs, and it is not too farfetched to imagine the SWFs of the next generation as being what SOEs are today.Footnote 200 This raises the issue of parties restructuring the mode of state interference rather than eliminating the problem. Lastly, some CPTPP parties, such as Mexico and Vietnam, have successfully negotiated extensive exceptions for certain SOEs in specific sectors or activities. There is no reason why China will not push hard for an extensive list of carve-outs in the accession negotiations.
V. Will China Be Able to Implement SOE Obligations in the CPTPP?
The SOE rules in the CPTPP draw heavily from the existing rules under the GATT/WTO system, including the obligations embodied in China’s Protocol of Accession to the WTO, when it comes to the substantive obligations for SOEs such as non-discrimination, commercial considerations, and transparency. Although the SOE rules in the CPTPP have added precision and expanded the scope of SOE obligations, in at least some aspects the CPTPP rules may be even less stringent than the obligations in China’s Protocol of Accession to the WTO.Footnote 201 To the extent that the existing SOE rules have not been successful in bringing about China’s compliance with the WTO rules, the effect of the SOE rules in the CPTPP may also be limited.Footnote 202 There is no guarantee that the SOE rules in the CPTPP are able to constrain China’s state capitalism effectively. In short, the current SOE rules may serve as a starting point for future negotiations of what rules are appropriate for Chinese SOEs in the 21st Century.
Take the transparency obligation in the CPTPP as an example. As SOEs compete in the global marketplace, transparency and disclosure of the SOE sector has gained importance beyond the domestic reform agenda. Transparency allows host states to be clear of how SOEs are controlled and supported by their home states and to monitor implementation of state obligations in international trade and investment agreements.Footnote 203The perception that Chinese SOEs lack transparency is particularly disconcerting because it is essential for Chinese SOEs to work extra hard to attain local legitimacy, and therefore be more transparent about their financing, structures and objectives.Footnote 204
Article 17.10 of the CPTPP contains extensive transparency requirements of SOEs that each party should provide. The requirements combine the proactive disclosure of SOE information by the home state with a request mechanism to obtain information by other parties.Footnote 205 Article 17.10.1 requires each party to provide to the other parties or otherwise make publicly available on an official website a list of its SOEs and to update this list annually. In addition, a party shall provide the following information on a written request of another party regarding a specific SOE: percentage of shares and votes under government ownership; special shares, votes, or other rights; government officials serving as officers or on the board of the SOE; the SOE’s annual revenue and total assets, exemptions and immunities accorded to the SOE under national law as well as any other publicly available information.Footnote 206 Moreover, the request mechanism allows other parties to obtain information regarding NCA provided by a state to its SOEs. The response must be sufficiently specific to enable the requesting party to evaluate the effects of the NCA on trade and investment between the parties, including the legal basis and policy objective of the measure, the amount of the assistance, its duration, as well as statistical data permitting an assessment of the effects of the NCA on trade and investment.Footnote 207
Wolfe questioned the effectiveness of the transparency requirements provided in the CPTPP. First, the record of WTO Members’ notification of industrial subsidies with respect to SOEs is consistently poor and the same disincentives exist when providing information in response to information request in the CPTPP.Footnote 208 Second, the transparency provisions are not accompanied by strong institutional support. The mandate of the Committee on SOEs does not include regular receipt, discussion and dissemination of SOE information. The information provided in response to an information request can be kept confidential if the party supplying the information requests it. As a result, the requested information cannot benefit all affected parties.Footnote 209 Lastly, given the number of Chinese SOEs, it may be unrealistic to expect China to create an online list of every SOE, given the size of the state sector in China, and even more unrealistic for any CPTPP party to try to provide written evidence of the trade effects of most SOEs on the list in order to justify a request from China for more information.Footnote 210 That said, the CPTPP has set in place a more powerful mechanism to enforce transparency obligations through dispute settlement. A panel is entitled to draw adverse inferences from instances of non-cooperation by a disputing party in the information gathering process. In addition, the panel shall not request additional information to complete the record where the information would support a party’s position and the absence of that information is the result of that party’s non-cooperation in the information-gathering process.Footnote 211 A stronger enforcement mechanism might provide additional incentives for China to comply with the daunting obligations, but that is still an open question.
E. Conclusion
Much ink has been splashed on the ideological, conceptual, and practical challenges that China’s state capitalism has posed to global trade rules. There is a growing perception that current international trade rules are neither conceptually coherent nor practically effective in tackling China’s state capitalism.Footnote 212 This perception has not only led to the emergence of new trade rules, but also culminated in the US-China trade war, only further aggravated by the Covid-19 pandemic and Russia-Ukraine war.Footnote 213
This Article contributes to the debate of what trade rules may be needed to regulate SOEs by unpacking the black box of China’s state capitalism. Tracing the reform of Chinese SOEs over the past 40 years, this Article shows that the CCP possesses both formal and informal tools to control SOEs, in particular Central SOEs in strategic sectors and that the boundary of SOEs and POEs is very blurred in contemporary China. Based on an understanding of the dual political and economic nature of China’s state capitalism, this Article casts serious doubts on the effectiveness of the new SOE rules in the CPTPP, including the narrow definition of SOEs, wide carve-outs and exceptions, and the likelihood of China’s inability to implement the SOE rules.
It must be stressed that China was not a negotiating party when the SOE rules in the CPTPP were written and that there is no guarantee that China will ever be able to join the CPTPP. Therefore, it would be unrealistic to expect the CPTPP negotiators to focus on how to regulate Chinese SOEs, a possibility in the future, as opposed to what are acceptable SOE rules to current CPTPP parties. Given that China formally submitted a request to accede to the CPTPP, it is reasonable to assume that China is comfortable with the new SOE disciplines embodied in the CPTPP. However, even if China might be accepted into the CPTPP in the future, it remains possible that the current CPTPP Members may push for “CPTPP-plus” obligations in China’s protocol of accession, in the same manner as China negotiated for its WTO entry two decades ago.Footnote 214 Despite the uncertain outcome of China’s CPTPP accession, it is hoped that the recent spotlight on Chinese SOEs may serve as an external incentive for the GOC to push forward market-oriented SOE reforms. These reforms will not only reduce suspicion when Chinese SOEs engage in international trade and investment activities, but also help them become truly competitive global champions.
Acknowledgements
The author wishes to thank Dr Leonardo Borlini and anonymous reviewers for their insights, and student editors for their meticulous editing work.
Funding statement
The author declares that he has not any financial or non-financial interests that are directly or indirectly related to the work submitted for publication.
Competing interests
None.