Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T17:04:48.995Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Development of German Corporate Law Until 1990: An Historical Reappraisal

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 March 2019

Extract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

The development of modern corporate law can be located in four “origin” legal systems: France, England, Germany and the United States (specifically in leading State Jurisdictions such as New York, New Jersey and Delaware). These systems are often segregated between an Anglo-American “outsider” system of corporate law and governance and the Continental “insider” system. This has its political economy parallel in the “Varieties of Capitalism” literature, which separates the major capitalist economies into “Liberal Market Economies”, such as the UK and the USA, and “Co-ordinated Market Economies”, such as Germany. These distinctions concentrate, in particular, on whether the system of corporate finance is based on open stock markets and widely dispersed “outsider” shareholding, as in the Anglo-American model, or on finance carried out by “insider” universal investment banks with places on the supervisory organs of corporations as is often claimed to be the case for the German system.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 2013 by German Law Journal GbR 

References

1 See also Alan Dignam & Michael Galanis, The Globalization of Corporate Governance 43–45 (2010); Henry Hansmann & Reiner Kraakman, The End of History of Corporate Law, in Convergence and Persistence in Corporate Governance 33 (Jeffrey Gordon & Mark Roe eds., 2004), also published in 89 Georgetown Univ. L.R. 439 (2001).Google Scholar

2 See Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Peter Hall & David Soskice eds., 2001). For a critical appraisal of this approach, see Gregory Jackson & Richard Deeg, From Comparing Capitalisms to the Politics of Institutional Change, 15(4) Rev. of Int'l Pol. Econ. 680 (2008).Google Scholar

3 In France, the role of the State as financier is emphasised. See also Dignam & Galanis, supra note 1, at 46–48; Hansmann & Kraakman, supra note 1.Google Scholar

4 For the proposition that the common law countries are more suited to the development of financial markets because they offer, on average, better creditor rights, shareholder rights, and private property rights than countries following a civil law tradition, see Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez de Silanes, Adrei Shleifer & Robert Vishny, Legal Determinants of External Finance, LII J. of Fin. 1131 (1997); Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez de Silanes, Adrei Shleifer & Robert Vishny, Law and Finance, 106 J. of Pol Econ. 1113 (1998); Thorsten Beck, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt & Ross Levine, Law and Finance: Why Does Legal Origin Matter?, (National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 9379, 2002), available at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w9379 (last accessed: 1 February 2013).Google Scholar

5 See La Porta et. al., supra note 4; Hansmann & Kraakman, supra note 1; see also Dignam & Galanis, supra note 1, Ch. 8, discussing how contemporary German corporate law is possibly converging towards the “outsider” approach.Google Scholar

6 See Pistor, Katerina, Yoram Keinan, Jan Kleinheisterkramp & Mark West, The Evolution of Corporate Law: A Cross-Country Comparison, 23 U. Pa. J. Int'l. Econ. L. 791 (2002). For a critique of the ‘legal families’ approach of La Porta, see Mathias Siems, Legal Origins: Reconciling Law & Finance and Comparative Law, 52 McGill L. J. 55 (2007). For a critique specifically dealing with Germany, and rejecting the idea that Germany offers weaker protection, see Udo Braendle, Shareholder Protection in the USA and Germany - On the Fallacy of LLSV (German Working Papers in Law and Economics Paper No. 18, 2006), available at: http://www.bepress.com/gwp/default/vol2006/iss1/art18/ (last accessed: 1 February 2013).Google Scholar

7 For a detailed analysis, see Adalbert be ala Levy, Private Corporations and their Control, Vol. I, Chapter I, sections 12, 15, 21 and 23 (1950); for a recent, very brief, summary, see Dignam & Galanis, supra note 1, at 263–267.Google Scholar

8 On which, see Mattei, Ugo, Why the Wind Changed: Intellectual Leadership in Western Law, 42 Am. J. Comp. L. 195 (1994); Harris, Ron, The Transplantation of Legal Discourse on Corporate Personality Theories: From German Codification to British Political Pluralism and American Big Business, 63 Wash. & Lee L. Rev. 1422 (2006); Konrad Zweigert & Hein Kotz, An Introduction to Comparative law 154–156 (1998).Google Scholar

9 On the problems of the history of corporate governance, and the dangers of crude, a-historical, classifications, see Gary Herrigel, Guest Editor's Introduction: A New Wave in the History of Corporate Governance, 8(3) Enterprise and Soc. 475 (2007); and Corporate Governance, in The Oxford Handbook of Business History 470 (Geoffrey Jones & Jonathan Zeitlin eds., 2009). There is also a wider problem in the apparent assumption of similarity, if not sameness, in the law and its underpinnings: see Nicholas Foster, Company Law Theory in Comparative Perspective: England and France, 48 Amer. J. of Com. L. 573 (2000).Google Scholar

10 See e.g., Mads Andenas & Frank Wooldridge, European Comparative Corporate Law (2009); Andreas Cahn & David Donald, Comparative Company Law: Text and Cases on the Laws Governing Corporations in Germany, the UK and the USA (2010); Jean Du Plessis, Bernhard Grossfeld, Claus Luttermann, Ingo Saenger, Otto Sandrock & Matthias Casper, German Corporate Governance in an International and European Context (2nd ed., 2012.Google Scholar

11 This can be contrasted with the existing interdisciplinary literature on the historical development of English company law; see e.g., Ron Harris, Industrialising English law: Entrepreneurship and Business Organisation 1720–1844 (2000); Rob McQueen, A Social History of Company law: Great Britain and the Australian Colonies 1854–1920 (2009). One interdisciplinary work in German covers the period 1945–1990, but it is not centred on corporate law alone: see Knut Wolfgang Nörr, Die Republik der Wirtschaft. Recht, Wirtschaft und Staat in der Geschichte Westdeutschlands. Teil 1 Von der Besatzungszeit bis zur Großen Koalition (The republic of the economy; the legal and economic state in West Germany: Part 1, 2007); Knut Wolfgang Nörr, Die Republik der Wirtschaft. Recht, Wirtschaft und Staat in der Geschichte Westdeutschlands. Teil 2 Von der sozialliberalen Koalition bis zur Wiedervereinigung (The republic of the economy; the legal and economic state in West Germany: Part 2, 2007).Google Scholar

12 See further, Helmut Coing, Europaisches Privatrecht Band II, 19. Jahrhundert 145–147 (European Private Law, Volume II: 19th Century, 1989); Bernhard Grossfeld, Aktiengesellschaft, Unternehmenskonzentration und Kleinaktionär 132 (Corporation, Corporate Concerntration and Minority Shareholders, 1968).Google Scholar

13 In 1866, the year when Bismarck embarked on the first stage of German unification after the defeat of Austria by Prussia, there were 38 German States: see David Thomson, Europe since Napoleon 307–320 (rev. ed., 1966).Google Scholar

14 On which, see further Hans Schlosser, Grundzuge der Neuren Privatrachtsgeschichte (Outline of the recent history of private law, 9th ed., 2001), in particular, Chapter 7, Die Kodifikation des Privatrechts in Deutschland (the codification of private law in Germany); see also Zweigert & Kotz, supra note 8, at 141–154.Google Scholar

15 The classic exposition of this approach is the influential work by Karl Lehmann, Die Geschichtliche Entwiklung des Aktienrechts bis zum Code de Commerce (he Historical Development of Corporate Law up to the Code de Commerce, 1895).Google Scholar

16 See e.g., Karl Lehmann, Das Recht der Aktiengesellschaften Band 75–82 (The law of joint stock corporations, 1898). Norbert Reich also identifies the origins of German corporate law as beginning after the adoption of the Code de Commerce and its reception into various German State laws: Norbert Reich, Die Entwicklung des Deutschen Aktienrechts im Neunzehnten Jahrhundert (The development of the German Stock Corporation Law in the Nineteenth Century), IUS Commune II (1969), available at: http://data.rg.mpg.de/iuscommune/ic02_reich.pdf (last accessed: 1 February 2013). See also Coing, supra note 12, at 99.Google Scholar

17 Levy defines the societas as an association in which, “all the parties share the risks both as capitalists and as traders” while the commenda is an association in which, “one party alone undertakes the management and bears the commercial risk”: Levy, supra note 7, at 3. Levy attributes the rise of the medieval commenda to Italy where one party the tractator undertook the management of the venture, the purchase, transport and sale of the goods and was responsible to creditors, while the other partner, the commendator, provided the capital but undertook no further obligations or liability: Levy, supra note 7, at 8. See also, Lehmann, Das Recht der Aktiengesellschaften, supra note 16, at 26–28.Google Scholar

18 See Uwe Wesel, Geschichte des Rechts: Von den Fruhformen bis zur Gegenwart 394 (History of the Law: From Early Forms to the Present, 3rd ed., 2006), who writes that in the years between the Middle Ages and the French Revolution business associations were dominated by “Personengesellchaften des Mittelalters.” See also Lehmann, Das Recht der Aktiengesellschaften, supra note 16, at 20–21.Google Scholar

19 Wesel, , supra note 18, at 336; Levy, supra note 7, at 9.Google Scholar

20 Levy, , supra note 7, at 11. Another example is the Ravensburg Company, which lasted from 1380 to 1530 on the basis of renewable contracts: Levy, supra note 7; Wesel, supra note 18, at 336.Google Scholar

21 Lehmann, Das Recht der Aktiengesellschaften, supra note 16, at 28–29, discussing the Mediterranean origins of this type of business association; Levy, supra note 7, at 97.Google Scholar

22 Levy, , supra note 7, at 11–12.Google Scholar

23 Grossfeld, , supra note 12, at 115–116; Levy, supra note 7, at 17–30; and generally, see Stephen Brown, Merchant Kings: When Companies Ruled the World 1600–1900 (2010).Google Scholar

24 Levy, , supra note 7, at 95–96; Lehmann, Das Recht der Aktiengesellschaften, supra note 16, at 75.Google Scholar

25 For a comparison of the Seehandel with the Dutch and English East India Companies, see Wilhelm Hartung, Geschichte und Rechtsstellung der Compagnie in Europa Eine Untersuchung am Beispiel der englischen East-India Company, der niederliindischen Vereenigten Oostindischen Compagnie und der preuBischen Seehandlung (History and Legal Status of the Company in Europe: A study of the English East India Company the Dutch United East India Company and the Prussian Seehandlung, 2000). Copy on file with author.Google Scholar

26 According to Coing, the State grant of incorporation was a general principle of law recognised by all European systems and was at the heart of the French Code de Commerce. See Helmut Coing, Rechtsvergleichung als Grundlage von Gesetzgebung im 19 Jahrhundert (Law as the Basis of Legislation in the 19th Century), IUS Commune VII, 168 (1978), available at: http://data.rg.mpg.de/iuscommune/ic07_coing.pdf (last accessed: 1 February 2013)Google Scholar

27 Grossfeld, , supra note 12, at 117.Google Scholar

28 Levy, , supra note 7, at 97. For the difficulties associated with this system in Prussia, see Reich, supra note 16, at 246- 247. On unease over corporations in Prussia, see Grossfeld, supra note 12, at 122–127.Google Scholar

29 On which, see Hans Ulrich Wehler, Deutsche Gesellschaftsgeschichte Band 2 1815–1845/49, 95–107 (History of German Society, Volume 2, 4th ed., 2005).Google Scholar

30 See Coing, , supra note 12, at 95–96.Google Scholar

31 See Wehler, , supra note 29, at 96, 614–631; for a comparative analysis of the role of railways in German, US and English industrialization between the 1830s and 1860s, see Rainer Fremdling, Railroads and German Economic Growth: A Leading Sector Analysis with a Comparison to the United States and Great Britain, 37 J. of Econ. Hist. 583 (1977); see also Reich, supra note 16, at 249–250, on the connection between railway development and the corporate legal form.Google Scholar

32 Gesetz über Eisenbahnunternehmungen (Railway corporate law) 3.11.1838 GS fur die Koniglichen Preussichen Staaten 1838 (GS for Royal Prussian State), s. 505 (Ger.).Google Scholar

33 Reich, , supra note 16, at 250; Levy, supra note 7, at 98.Google Scholar

34 Preussiche Aktiengesetz (Prussian corporation law) 9.11.1843 GS Fur Die Konglichen Preussichen Staaten 1843, 9 Nov. 1843, Nr 31 s.341 (Gr.). The following summary draws on Reich, supra note 16, at 251; Levy, supra note 7, at 98–99, and Grossfeld, supra note 12, at 127–131. See also Gesetz uber die Aktiengesellschaften fur die Königlich Preussischen Staaten von 9 November 1843 (Law on Companies for the Royal Prussian State, Theodor Baums ed., 1981). Other German States had also adopted corporate laws at this time. Thus, the Prussian and Bavarian Rhineland Provinces, Hessen and Baden, used the Code de Commerce after 1815 and only in the Prussian Rhine Province was it supplanted by the 1843 law. Wurttemberg codified its commercial law in 1839 and followed the Dutch Commercial Code in relation to corporations. Nassau codified its commercial law in 1842: Reich, supra note 16, at 243–244; Wehler, supra note 29, at 104.Google Scholar

35 Reich, , supra note 16, at 251; Wesel, supra note 18, at 463; Coing, supra note 26, at 169.Google Scholar

36 Levy, , supra note 7, at 98–99. The basic principle behind the société en commandite is that it must comprise of at least two partners: the commandite, who is the managing partner and takes full liability for the commercial debts of the entity, and the commanditaire, who is a limited liability partner and who takes no part in the management of the undertaking. Such entities pre-date the French Code de Commerce: see Levy, supra note 7, at 55. See also Code de Commerce, Art. L 222–1 (Fr.).Google Scholar

37 See also Reich, , supra note 16, at 253–254.Google Scholar

38 Coing, , supra note 26, at 172: the Code de Commerce “Dementsprechend kannte es das Konzessionssystem; dagegwen war die Institution des Aufrichtsrates unbekannt.” Google Scholar

39 Grossfeld, , supra note 12, at 128.Google Scholar

40 Id. at 130–131.Google Scholar

41 Reich, , supra note 16, at 245; Levy, supra note 7, at 101.Google Scholar

42 Reich, , supra note 16, at 260; Grossfeld, supra note 12, at 134; Coing, supra note 26, at 173.Google Scholar

43 Reich, , supra note 16, at 255; Wehler, supra note 29, at 105–106.Google Scholar

44 Grossfeld, , supra note 12, at 134.Google Scholar

45 Reich, , supra note 16, at 260.Google Scholar

46 Grossfeld, , supra note 12, at 134–135, citing Art. 249 of the ADHGB: “Den Landegesetzen bleibt es vorbehalten zu bestimmen, dass es der staatlichen Gehnemigung zur errichtung von Aktiengesellschaften im allgemienem oder von einzelnen Arten derselbern nicht bedarf.” Google Scholar

47 Reich, , supra note 16, at 261–262.Google Scholar

48 See Reich, , supra note 16, at 264–265.Google Scholar

49 Grossfeld, , supra note 12, at 136–137.Google Scholar

50 Id. at 137–138.Google Scholar

51 For a detailed analysis of the discussions leading to the 1870 Law, see Werner Schubert, Die Abschaffung des Konzessionssystems durch die Aktienrechtnovelle von 1870 (The abolition of the concession system by the Company Law Amendment of 1870), 10 Zeitschrift für Unternehmens- und Gesellschaftsrecht 2, 285 (1981), available at: http://www.degruyter.com/dg/viewarticle/j$002fzgre.1981.10.issue-2$002fzgre.1981.10.2.285$002fzgre.1981.10.2.285.xml;jsessionid=5ECE5F7390DE5D53017F5B595FDA4F2F (last accessed: 1 February 2013). For a more general overview of the codification process, see Klaus Hopt, Ideelle und wirtschafliche Grundlagen der Aktien- Bank- und Borsen rechtsentwicklung in 19. Jahrhundert, in Wissenschaft unde Kodifikation des Privatrechts im 19. Jaherhunderts 128 (The science and codification of private law, Helmut Coing & Walter Wilhelm eds., 1980).Google Scholar

52 Gesetz betreffend die Kommanditgesellschaften auf Aktien und die AktiengesellschafteN, 11 June 1870, s. 375–386 Artikel (Art.) 210a and Art. 211: “Der Anmeldung Behufs der Eintragung in das Handelsregister muß beigefügt sein: 1) die Bescheinigung, dass der gesammte Betrag des Grundkapitals durch Unterschriften gedeckt ist; 2) Die Bescheinigung, dass mindestens zehn Prozent, bei Versicherungsgesellschaften mindestens zwanzig Prozent, des von jedem Aktionair gezeichneten Betrages eingezahlt sind; 3) der Nachweis, dass der Aufsichtsrath nach Inhalt des Vertrages in einer Generalversammlung der Aktionaire gewählt ist; 4) betreffenden Falls die gerichtliche oder notarielle Urkunde über die in den Artikeln 209a und 209b bezeichneten Beschlüsse der Generalversammlung. Die Anmeldung muß von sämmtlichen Mitgliedern des Vorstandes vor dem Handelsgericht unterzeichnet oder in beglaubigter Form eingereicht werden. Die der Anmeldung beigefügten Schriftstücke werden bei dem Handelsgericht in Urschrift oder in beglaubigter Abschrift aufbewahrt.”Google Scholar

53 Schubert, , supra note 51, at 302–312.Google Scholar

54 Schubert, , supra note 51, at 306.Google Scholar

55 Adolf Cahn, Der Aufsichtsrat der Aktiengesellschaft 6–10 (The Supervisory Board of the Corporation, 1907). For a detailed historical analysis of the rise of the Aufsichtsrat in German law, see Tanja Schnorr, Historie und Recht des Aufsichtsrats - Deutsche Erfahrungen als Beitrag zum Statut der Europäischen Aktiengesellschaft 1991 (Inaugural-Dissertation Zur Erlangung der Würde eines doctor iuris der Juristischen Fakultät der Bayerischen Julius-Maximilians-Universität Würzburg, 2000), available at: http://ebookbrowse.com/diss-tanja-schnorr-pdf-pdf-d89249780 or http://d-nb.info/971589054/34 (last accessed: 1 February 2013).Google Scholar

56 See Levy, supra note 7, at 128; Reich, supra note 16, at 267–268; Coing, supra note 26, at 173. Gesetz betreffend die Kommanditgesellschaften auf Aktien und die Aktiengesellschaften Vom 18 Juli 1884 [Aktiengesetz 1884], 18 Jul. 1884, Deutsches Reichsgesetzblatt Band 1884, Nr 22 s. 123–170 Art. 175e (Ger.): “Jede Kommanditgesellschaft auf Aktien muss einen Aufsichtsrath haben”, Art. 209f: “Jede Aktiengesellschaft muss ausser dem Vorstande einen Aufsichtsrath haben.”Google Scholar

57 Coing, , supra note 26, at 173. Some dispute exists as to how this idea was taken from French to German law with the suggestion made by Passow, rejected by Levy, that German legislators had wrongly translated the French Conseil de Surveillance literally when they only intended the supervisory organ to be an advisory body to the management board based on the German Verwaltungsrat: see Levy, supra note 7, at 129. Francks, Mayer and Wagner accept Passow's view: Julian Franks, Colin Mayer & Hannes Wagner, The Origins of the German Corporation - Finance, Ownership and Control, 10 Rev. of Fin. 537 (2006). They cite Richard Passow, Die Entstehung Des Aufsichtsrats der Aktiengesellschaft, 64 Zeitschrift fuer das gesamte Handelsrecht und Konkursrecht, 27–57 (1909), and Richard Passow, Die Aktiengesellschaft: Eine Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Studie (The Corporation: An Economic Study, 2nd ed., 1922).Google Scholar

58 See Hans-Ulrich Wehler, Deutsche Gesellschaftsgeschichte Band 3, 1849–1914, 81–86 (History of German Society, Volume 3, 2nd ed., 2006).Google Scholar

59 See Reich, , supra note 16, at 268.Google Scholar

61 See Reich, , supra note 16, at 270–276, on which the following paragraph relies, and Grossfeld above n.12 at 144–145. See also, Hundert Jahre Modernes Aktienrecht: Sammlung von Texten und Quellen zur Aktienrechtsreform 1884 (One Hundred Years of Modern Company Law: Collection of Texts and Sources on Corporate Law Reform, Werner Schubert & Peter Hommelhoff eds., 1985).Google Scholar

62 Gesetz betreffend die Kommanditgesellschaften auf Aktien und die Aktiengesellschaften Vom 18 Juli 1884, supra note 56. For a brief summary in English, see Levy, supra note 7, at 128–131.Google Scholar

63 Gesetz betreffend die Kommanditgesellschaften auf Aktien und die Aktiengesellschaften Vom 18 Juli 1884, supra note 56, for KGaA at Arts. 175–179, for AG Arts. 207–212. 64 Id., for KGaA, Art. 173a; for AG, Art. 207a.Google Scholar

65 Id., for KGaA, Arts. 180–180b and Art. 193 on duties of the supervisory board members; for AG, Arts. 213–213c.Google Scholar

66 Id., Arts. 249–249g.Google Scholar

67 Id., for KGaA, Arts. 185–185c; for AG, Art. 239.Google Scholar

68 Id., for KGaA, Arts 180f-180i; for AG, Arts. 215 and 215a.Google Scholar

69 Id., for KGaA, Arts. 181–183a, 184–184d; for AG, Arts. 215b-215d.Google Scholar

70 Id., for KGaA, Art. 183b; for AG, Art. 219.Google Scholar

71 Id., for KGaA, Art. 204: “die sorgfalt eines ordentlichen Geschaftsmanns anzuweden”; for the AG, Art. 226.Google Scholar

72 Id., for KGaA and AG, Art. 190 (ensuring that each shareholder has a vote in the General Meeting and larger shareholders could be subjected to limits in voting); for AG shareholder remedies, see Arts. 221–223.Google Scholar

73 Id., for KGaA, Art. 175e and Art. 191, which also applies to AGs under Art.224.Google Scholar

74 Id., Art. 225a. The supervisory function of the Aufsichtsrat is established by Art. 225. On the duties of the Vorstand, see Arts. 227–241. Members of the Vorstand are also subject to the duty of care of the ordinary businessman: Art. 241.Google Scholar

75 Deutsche Handelsgesetzbuch vom 10 Mai 1897 [RGBl], 1 Jan. 1900, s. 219.Google Scholar

76 See Levy, , supra note 7, at 132–133; see also jan von Hein, die Rezeption US-amerikanischen Gesellschaftsrechts in Deutschland 99–100 (Reception of United States Corporate Law in Germany, 2008), who notes that little comparative law analysis infomred the codification of 1897.Google Scholar

77 Gerschenkron, Alexander, The Modernisation of Entrepreneurship, in Continuity in History and Other Essays (1968), at 137: “The German investment banks - a powerful invention, comparable in economic effect to that of the steam engine - were in their capital-supplying functions a substitute for the insufficiency of the previously created wealth willingly placed at the disposal of entrepreneurs.” See also Alexander Gerschenkron, The Approach to European Industrialization: A Postscript, in Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective 353–354 (1962).Google Scholar

78 For an overview, see Caroline Fohlin, Finance Capitalism and Germany's Rise to Industrial Power 31–37 (2007). See also, e.g., Alfred Chandler, Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism 417–419 (1990); Marco Da Rin & Thomas Hellmann, Banks as Catalyst for Industrialisation, 11 J. of Fin. Intermediation 266 (2002); Toni Pierenkemper & Richard Tilly, The German Economy During the Nineteenth Century (2004), at Chatper 7; for a Marxist interpretation, see Rudolph Hilferding, Finance Capital (1910) (Tom Bottomore trans., 1981); see also Marco Da Rin, Understanding the Development of German Kreditbanken, 1850–1914: an Approach from the Economics of Information, 3 Fin.'l Hist. Rev. 29 (1996), who argues that the development of effective systems for information gathering by the universal banks was key to their ability to control industrial enterprises in which they held an interest.Google Scholar

79 See Fohlin, , supra note 78, at 33–34, citing Gerschenkron: [T]hrough the development of the institution of the supervisory boards to the most powerful organs within corporate organisations, the banks acquired a formidable degree of ascendancy over industrial enterprises, which extended far beyond the sphere of financial control into that of entrepreneurial and managerial decisions.” See, on the impact of the 1884 Law on corporate concentration, Norbert Reich, Auswirkungen der deutschen Aktienrechtsreform von 1884 auf die Konzentrazion der deutschen Wirtschaft, in Recht und Entwicklung der Grossunternehmen im 19. und fruhen 20 Jahrhundert; law and the Formation of Big Enterprises in the 19 and Early 20 Centuries 255–273 (Norbert Horn & Jurgen Kocha eds., 1979). See also, Norbert Horn, Aktienrechtliche Unternehmensorganisation in der Hochindustialisierung (1860-1920) Deutschland, England, Frankreich und die USA im Vergleich, in Recht und Entwicklung der Grossunternehmen im 19. und fruhen 20 Jahrhundert; Law and the Formation of Big Enterprises in the 19 and Early 20TH Centuries, 123–189 (Norbert Horn & Jurgen Kocha eds., 1979).Google Scholar

80 See Pierenkemper & Tilly, supra note 78, at 120–121; Jeremy Edwards & Sheilagh Ogilvie, Universal Banks and German Industrialization: a Reappraisal, XLIX Economic History Review 427 (1996); for a summary of the main authorities for and against the bank dominance thesis, see Fohlin, supra note 78, at 40–44.Google Scholar

81 Franks, , supra note 57, at 7; Fohlin, supra note 78, at 121–125.Google Scholar

82 Fohlin, , supra note 78, at 122.Google Scholar

83 For detailed data on the actual numbers of bank members of supervisory boards, bank shareholding patterns in non financial firms and interlocking directorships of bank representatives, all of which, she asserts, show more limited involvement than the Gerschenkron thesis supposes, see Fohlin, supra note 78, at 43 and Chapter 5. However, not all proponents of the bank dominance thesis are convinced: see note 101, infra. Google Scholar

84 Edwards, , supra note 80, at 436.Google Scholar

85 See also, Richard Deeg, On the Development of Universal Banking in Germany, in The Origins of National Financial Systems: Alexander Gerschenkron Reconsidered 87 (Douglas Forsyth & Daniel Verdier eds., 2003).Google Scholar

86 Edwards, , supra note 80, at 434.Google Scholar

87 Id. at 437–440.Google Scholar

88 See Wehler, supra note 58, at 630; see also Levy, supra note 7, at 128, 142–145, who notes that supervisory boards were not very effective at control over managers and that managers acquired the upper hand over the aufsichtsrat and the generalversammelung. Google Scholar

89 Neuburger, Hugh, The Industrial Politics of the Kreditbanken, 1880-1914, 51 Bus. Hist. Rev. 190 (1977).Google Scholar

90 Edwards, , supra note 80, at 440.Google Scholar

91 See Fohlin, , supra note 78, at 43.Google Scholar

92 See Fohlin, , supra note 78, at 45, citing Jacob Reisser, die deutschen grossbanken und ihre Konzentration (The German banks and their concentration, 1910), who was a director of one of the universal banks, Otto Jeidels, Das Verhaltnis der deutschen Grossbanken zur Industire (The relationship of German banks for industry, 1905), who was a bank employee, and Hilferding, supra note 78. For criticisms of Hilferding's analysis, see Wehler, supra note 58, at 630; see also, Neuberger, supra note 89, who doubts that the evidence of the “dictatorship of the banks” asserted by Hilferding and Gerschenkron can survive empirical analysis. Subsequent research has proved him correct.Google Scholar

93 Fohlin, , supra note 78, at 41–43, and the sources cited therein.Google Scholar

94 See e.g., Fohlin, , supra note 78, and Caroline Fohlin, Does Civil Law Tradition and Universal Banking Crowd out Securities Markets?, 8(3) Enterprise and SOC. 602 (2007).Google Scholar

95 Franks, , supra note 57, at 4–5. See further, Wolfgang Schultz, Das Deutsche Borsengesetz: die Entstehungsgeschichte und Wirtschaflichen Auswirkungen des Borsengesetzes von 1896 (The German Stock Exchange Act: The History and Economic Impact of the Exchange Act, 1994); for a critical contemporary appraisal, see Ernst Loeb, The German Exchange Act of 1896, 11 The Qtr'ly J. of Econ. 388 (1897), available at: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1880717?origin=JSTOR-pdf (last accessed: 1 February 2013).Google Scholar

96 Fohlin, , supra note 94, at 615.Google Scholar

98 Fohlin, , supra note 78, at 232.Google Scholar

99 Fohlin, , supra note 94, at 616–617.Google Scholar

100 Id. at 618.Google Scholar

101 See further, the critique of Fohlin's views by Dyke, Alexander, in his response to Caroline Fohlin, The History of Corporate Ownership and Control in Germany, in A History of Corporate Governance around the World: Family Business Groups to Professional Managers 277–281 (Randall Morck ed., 2005).Google Scholar

102 See further Leslie Hannah, Mergers Cartels and Concentration: Legal Factors in the US and European Experience, in Horn, supra note 78, at 306–316.Google Scholar

103 See Tilley, Richard, External Growth, and Finance in the Development of Large-Scale Enterprise in Germany, 1880–1913, 42 J. of Econ. Hist. 629 (1982).Google Scholar

104 See Peter Muchlinski, Multinational Enterprises and the Law 35 (2007).Google Scholar

105 Grossfeld, , supra note 12, at 149–150.Google Scholar

106 Gesetz betreffend die Kommanditgesellschaften auf Aktien und die Aktiengesellschaften Vom 18 Juli 1884, supra note 56; for KGaA, Art. 179; for AG, Art. 212.Google Scholar

107 Grossfeld, , supra note 12, at 154–155.Google Scholar

108 See Tilley, , supra note 103.Google Scholar

109 See Cornish, William, Legal Control over Cartels and Monopolisation 1880–1914 A Comparison, in Horn, supra note 78, at 280–305.Google Scholar

110 “Corporatism” is used here to denote a system of industrial organisation in which the State co-ordinates, or directs, corporate and sectoral policy in co-operation with the representatives of business and industry and, where politically acceptable, organised labour and worker representatives. On the problems of this concept, see Leo Panitch, Recent Theorizations of Corporatism: Reflections on a Growth Industry, 31 Brit. J. of Soc. 159 (1980). On the historical roots of German corporatism in the Kaiserreich, see Wehler, supra note 58, at 662–680.Google Scholar

111 See further von Hein, supra note 76 at 143, who argues that the reforms of 1870 and 1884 were typical products of liberalism based on private law principles that were compatible with the basic premises that informed English and French law of the time. To have considered these laws as interventionist at that time would have appeared as a relapse into the concession system which they had been adopted to replace. In a similar vein, see F.A. Mann, The New German Company Law and its Background, 19 J. Comp. Legis. & Int'l L. 3d ser. 220, at 223 (1937). See also Richard Overy, State and Industry in Germany in the Twentieth Century, 12(2) German History 180 (1994), who notes (at 181) that in the period from the late 19th century to 1916, “[t]he state certainly interfered more in German economic life than was the case in Britain or the United States, but the gap should not be exaggerated. Industry did much of its own regulating, through cartels and trusts. When war broke out in 1914, it was industry that took up the challenge of war production…Up to 1916 the domestic war economy was still left mainly to private initiative. “ For the argument that the reform of 1884 represented a non-liberal position, see Shawn Donnelly, Andrew Gamble, Gregory Jackson & John Parkinson, The Public Interest and the Company in Britain and Germany 13–16 (2000), available at: http://www.agf.org.uk/cms/upload/pdfs/CR/2000_CR1215_e_public_interest_and_the_company.pdf (last accessed: 1 February 2013).Google Scholar

112 Fohlin, , supra note 94, at 609–611.Google Scholar

113 Gesetz Betreffend die Gesellschaften mit Beschrankter Haftung vom 20 April 1892 (Law Concerning Private Limited Companies, 20 April 1892) [Gmbh Gesetz 1892], 20 Apr. 1892, as amended, available at: http://www.gesetze-im-internet.de/bundesrecht/gmbhg/gesamt.pdf (last accessed: 1 February 2013). For a useful brief summary, see Coing, supra note 12, at 127–130.Google Scholar

114 Gmbh Gesetz 1892, supra note 113, Art. 13.Google Scholar

115 See Andenas & Wooldridge, supra note 10, at 116, and further, for an account of the origins of the GmbH, see Timothy Guinnane, Ron Harris, Naomi Lamoreaux & Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, Putting the Corporation in its Place, 8(3) Enter. and Soc'y 687, 697–703 (2007). They stress the difficulties of incorporation under the 1884 Law as a factor in the development of the GmbH. Perhaps, the answer lies in the nature of German business ownership of the time and in the continued importance of family owned enterprises and of smaller entities that did not need, or want, the AG form but wanted limited liability.Google Scholar

116 See e.g., Bundesverband der Deutschen Industrie e. V. [BDI] [Federation of German Industries], Major family businesses in Germany Facts, figures, potential 21 (2012), available at: http://www.ifmbonn.org/assets/documents/BDI-major-family-businesses-Spring-2012.pdf (last accessed: 1 February 2013); family run GmbH's may have a supervisory board due to provisions in the company contract or as a result of the requirements of the Co-determination Laws.Google Scholar

117 See also Guinnane, , supra note 115, undertaking a comparative study of the development of private limited liability corporations in the UK, US, France and Germany. On the 19th century figures, see Edwards, supra note 80. Contemporary figures show that the SME sector still dominates the German economy. According to the German Federal Ministry of Economics and Technology, “Small and medium-sized companies in Germany represent 99.7% of all businesses, produce 38% of taxable turnover, account for nearly 49% of total net value added by companies, and provide roughly 60% of all jobs requiring social insurance contributions.” See Federal Ministry of Economics and Technology, Policy for small and medium-sized businesses (2012), available at: http://www.bmwi.de/English/Navigation/Economic-policy/small-business-policy.html (last accessed: 1 February 2013).Google Scholar

118 Verordnung des Reichspresidanten uber Akteinrecht, Bankenaussichtt und uber die Steueramnestie vom 19 September 1931 Reichsgesetzblatt [RGBl], 19 Sep. 1931, Historische Rechts- und Gesetzestexte Online Osterreichische Nationalbibliotek, Teil 1 Nr.63 s.493, ALEX available at: http://alex.onb.ac.at/cgicontent/alex?aid=dra&datum=1931&page=591&size=45 (last accessed: 1 February 2013). More generally, see Richard Rosendorff, The New German Company Act and the English Companies Act 1929, Part I, 14 J. Comp. Legis. & Int'l L. 3d ser. 94 (1932), Richard Rosendorff, The New German Company Act and the English Companies Act 1929, Part II, 15 J. Comp. Legis. & Int'l L. 3d ser. 112 (1933); Richard Rosendorff, The New German Company Act and the English Companies Act 1929, Part III, 15 J. Comp. Legis. & Int'l L. 3d ser. 242 (1933).Google Scholar

119 Gesetz uber Aktiengesellschaften und Kommanditgesellschaften auf Aktien (Aktiengesetz) vom 30 Januar 1937 Reichsgesetzblatt (RGBl), 30 Jan. 1937, Historische Rechts- und Gesetzestexte Online Osterreichische Nationalbibliotek (Ger.), Teil 1 Nr. 15 s. 107, ALEX available at: http://alex.onb.ac.at/cgicontent/alex?aid=dra&datum=1937&page=213&size=45 (last accessed: 1 February 2013).Google Scholar

120 See Hans-Ulrich Wehler, Deutsche Gesellschaftsgeschichte Band 4 1914–1949 (History of German Society, Volume 4, 3rd ed., 2008) at 47–52 on which this account draws. On the impact of this policy on Schering AG, see Christopher Kobrak, Politics, Corporate Governance and the Dynamics of German Managerial Innovation: Schering AG between the Wars, 3 Enter. and Soc'y 429, 438 (2002).Google Scholar

121 See Wehler, , supra note 120, at 52–54, who feels that this led to a sharpening of distributional conflicts that fuelled the abortive socialist revolution at the end of the war.Google Scholar

122 Id. at 57.Google Scholar

123 Walter Rathenau, Vom Aktienwesen: eine Geschichtliche Betrachtung (1918).Google Scholar

124 Id. at 13–33.Google Scholar

125 According to Rathenau, “die Grossunternehmung ist heute uberhaupt nicht mehr lediglich ein Gebilde privatrechtlicher Interessen, sie ist vielmehr, sowohl einzeln wie in ihrer Gesamtzhal, ein nationaliwirschaftlicher, der Gesammtheit angehoriger Faktor, der zwar aus feiner herkunft, zu Recht oder zu Unrecht, noch die privatrechlichen Zuge des reinen Erwerbsunternehmens tragt, wahrend er langst und in steigendem Masse offentlichen Interessen dienseitbar geworden ist und hierdurch sich ein neues Dasainreacht geschoffen hat.” Rathaneau, supra note 123, at 38–39:Google Scholar

126 Id. at 41, 62. This approach has acquired the label “unternehmen an sich”, given by Haussmann when he commented on Rathenau's famous rhetorical example of the risk that the Deutsche Bank could be overvalued and then forced into liquidation by the general meeting, saying that Rathenau had posited the need for the enterprise to secure the undertaking for itself against the majority of the general meeting: “Schutz des Unternehmens an sich gegenuber der Mehrheit in der Generalversammlung.” See von Hein, supra note 76, at 140, citing Fritz Haussman, Vom Aktienwesen und Aktienrecht 14, 27 (1928).Google Scholar

127 von Hein, supra note 76; Mann, supra note 111, at 226–227, who links Rathenau's ideas with the 1937 Law.Google Scholar

128 von Hein, supra note 76, at 141–142, citing Geiler.Google Scholar

129 For a detailed analysis of the process and of the role played by US ideas, see id. at 126–169; see also Rosendorff, Part I, supra note 118, at 95. The DJT discussions of 1926 and 1928 are documented in Quellen fur Aktienrechtsreform der Weimarer Republic 1926–31, Vol. 1, 33–205 (Werner Schubert ed., 1999); the work of the Ministry of Justice is documented therein, at 207–442.Google Scholar

130 Rosendorff, , Part I, supra note 118.Google Scholar

131 See Levy, , supra note 7, at 168–169; Fohlin, supra note 78, at 299.Google Scholar

132 Levy, , supra note 7, at 169–170; Fohlin, supra note 101, at 262.Google Scholar

133 Levy, , supra note 7; see further von Hein, supra note 76, at 149–157.Google Scholar

134 Rosendorff, , Part II, supra note 118, at 113.Google Scholar

135 Verordnung des Reichspresidanten uber Akteinrecht, Bankenaussichtt und uber die Steueramnestie vom 19 September 1931 Reichsgesetzblatt, supra note 118, Arts. V and VI.Google Scholar

136 Rosendorff, , Part III, supra note 118, at 242–246.Google Scholar

137 Fohlin, , supra note 101, at 262–263. See Gesetz uber Aktiengesellschaften und Kommanditgesellschaften auf Aktien (Aktiengesetz) vom 30 Januar 1937 Reichsgesetzblatt (RGBl), supra note 119, Arts. 159–168 on pre-emptive rights; Arts. 169–173, allowing special issue of shares without permission of stockholders for up to five years; Art. 174, specific permission of stockholders and the Reich Ministry of Economics needed in specific cases of issues of convertible and participating bonds. Further, see Mann, supra note 111, at 235–237.Google Scholar

138 Verordnung des Reichspresidanten uber Akteinrecht, Bankenaussichtt und uber die Steueramnestie vom 19 September 1931 Reichsgesetzblatt, supra note, 118 Art.1(1) new s. 227 HGB; see also, Rosendorff, Part III, supra note 118 at 248–249. This was carried through to the 1937 Law: see Mann, supra note 111, at 237–238.Google Scholar

139 Verordnung des Reichspresidanten uber Akteinrecht, Bankenaussichtt und uber die Steueramnestie vom 19 September 1931 Reichsgesetzblatt, supra note 118, at Art. VII new s.266(3) HGB.Google Scholar

140 Rosendorff, , Part II, supra note 118, at 112.Google Scholar

141 See von Hein, supra note 76, at 161–163; Rosendorff, Part I, supra note 118, at 98–100.Google Scholar

142 On patterns of industrial concentration in this period, see Fohlin, supra note 101, at 229–230; Wehler, supra note 120, at 262–268.Google Scholar

143 Rosendorff, , Part I, supra note 118.Google Scholar

144 See Rosendorff, Part III, supra note 118, at 250–253, discussing the proposed rules of holding companies in the 1930 Draft Law that were not adopted in the NotVO; Levy, supra note 7, at 172.Google Scholar

145 See Fohlin, supra note 101, at 267.Google Scholar

146 Id. at 113.Google Scholar

147 See von Hein, supra note 76, at 172. See further, Kobrak, supra note 120. On Nazi privatisations, see Germa Bel, Against the Mainstream: Nazi Privatisation in 1930s Germany, 63(1) Econ. Hist. Rev. 34 (1210). According to Overy, state ownership became much more widespread during the Second World War particularly in sectors related to armaments and strategic industries: Overy, supra note 111, at 184. For example, the Reichswerke, set up in 1937 by Goering, Hermann, grew into a vast state holding company in iron ore mining, iron and steel, and armaments.Google Scholar

148 This includes a minimum capital on formation of 500,000 Reichsmarks (Art. 7); no shares issued without a minimum par value of at least 1000 Reichsmarks (Arts. 6 and 8); see Mann, supra note 111, at 227–228.Google Scholar

149 This includes more information about corporate members (Arts. 100 and 128), more information for shareholders (Art. 112), and more details about group ownership structures as well as membership of cartels (Art.128 (8) and (9)); See Mann, supra note 111, at 231–233.Google Scholar

150 See Kessler, William, The German Corporation Law of 1937, 28(4) Am. Econ. Rev 653 (1938).Google Scholar

151 von Hein, , supra note 76, at 179–181.Google Scholar

152 By Art. 70: “(1) Der vorstand hat unter eigener Verantwortung die Gesellschaft so zu leiten, wie dass Wohl des Betriebes und seiner Gefolgschaft und der gemeine Nutzen von Volk und Reich es forderen.”Google Scholar

153 For a detailed discussion, see Kessler, supra note 150, at 658–660; Mann, supra note 111, at 228–231; Detlev Vagts, Reforming the “Modern” Corporation: Perspectives from the German, 80 Harv. L. Rev. 1 23, 41–43 (1966).Google Scholar

154 See Levy, , supra note 7, at 214.Google Scholar

155 Fohlin, , supra note 78, at 300.Google Scholar

156 See Kobrak, , supra note 120, at 455–456.Google Scholar

157 See Vagts, , supra note 153, at 42–43.Google Scholar

158 Fohlin, , supra note 78, at 303.Google Scholar

159 This paragraph is based on Fohlin, supra note 78, at 301–304.Google Scholar

160 Id. at 304.Google Scholar

162 Id.; see also Overy, supra note 111, at 182, 184. But see the Volkswagen privatisation law which allowed the State of Lower Saxony to retain control over the new firm through controlling a fifth of all shares. This law was successfully challenged under EU law in 2007: see Peer Zumbansen & Daniel Saam, The ECJ, Volkswagen and European Corporate Law: Reshaping the European Varieties of Capitalism, 8 Germ. L. J. 1026 (2007).Google Scholar

163 See further, Mary Fulbrook, A Concise History of Germany 204–212(2nd ed., 2004).Google Scholar

164 Id., at 235–238. On the rise and fall of the centrally planned GDR economy, see Hans-Ulrich Wehler, Deutsche Gesellschaftsgeschichte Band 5 1949 – 1990, 88–107 (History of German Society, Volume 5, 2008).Google Scholar

165 See Vagts, supra note 153, at 26, citing the Federal Governments draft proposal for new legislation of 1960, Entwurf Eines Aktiengesetzes mit Begrundung 93 (1960).Google Scholar

166 See Vagts, , supra note 153, at 30–31.Google Scholar

167 Overy, , supra note 111, at 189. For a detailed analysis of how West Germany returned to a liberal market economy, see Nörr, Teil 1, supra note 11, Chs. 2 and 3.Google Scholar

168 Overy, , supra note 111, at 189; von Hein, supra note 76, at 193–194.Google Scholar

169 See Basic Law of the Federal Republic of Germany (Grundgesetz), 23 May 1949 Chapter One Basic Rights (Deutscher Bundestag, Official English Translation, 2010) available at: http://www.gesetze-iminternet.de/englisch_gg/index.html (last accessed: 1 February 2013).Google Scholar

170 For an English summary of German Ordoliberal views from the period, see Carl Friedrich, The Political Thought of Neo-Liberalism, 49 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 509 (1965); Kurt Hanslowe, Neo-liberalism an Analysis and Proposed Application, 9 J. Pub. L. 96, 97–102 (1960). See also Razeen Sally, Classical Liberalism and International Economic Order (1998), Chapter 6, “Ordoliberalism and the Social Market.” For a recent examination, see Ralf Ptak, Neoliberalism in Germany: Revisiting the Ordoliberal Foundations of the Social Market Economy, in The Road from Mont Pelerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective 98 (Philip Mirowski & Dieter Plehwe eds., 2009). In German, see Nörr, Teil 1, supra note 11, Chapter 4. The main organ of the ordoliberal movement is the journal Ordo: Jahrbuch fur die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft (Yearbook of Business & Society), available online at: http://www.ordo-jahrbuch.de/en/available-volumes.html (last accessed: 1 February 2013).Google Scholar

171 Dignam & Galanis, supra note 1, at 264, incorrectly assert that “By 1884 corporate law reform led to the supervisory board being introduced with employee representation on it…”Google Scholar

172 See Du Plessis et al., supra note 10, at 154–155; Gregory Jackson, Contested Boundaries: Ambiguity and Creativity in the Evolution of German Codetermination 13 (RIETI Discussion Paper Series No. 04-E-022, 2004), available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=569541 (last accessed: 1 February 2013); Donnelly et. al., supra note 111, at 18–21, discussing early forms of worker participation in the 19th century German coal industry and in war industries during World War I.Google Scholar

173 Donnelly et. al, supra note 111, at 21. On the impact of this policy on Schering AG, see Kobrak, supra note 120, at 483.Google Scholar

174 Reichsgesetzblatt (RGBl) 1920 I s.147; see also Jackson, supra note 172.Google Scholar

175 Gesetz uber die Entsendung von Betriebsratmitgliedern in den Aufsichtsrat vom 15Februar 1922, 15Feb. 1992, Reichsgesetzblatt (RGBl) 1922 I No. 17 pp. 209/10 (Ger.). See Du Plessis et al., supra note 10, at 154. Levy feels these laws were ineffective: see Levy, supra note 7, at 172.Google Scholar

176 See Donnelly et al, supra note 111, at 22–23; Vagts, supra note 153, at 64–89; von Hein, supra note 76, at 219–224; Nörr, Teil 1, supra note 11, at Chapter 6. For the leading historical treatise on co-determination, see Hans Teutenberg, Geschichte der Industriellen Mitbestimmung in Deutschland (History of Industrial Co-Determination in Germany, 1961).Google Scholar

177 Mitbestimmungsgesetz vom 4. Mai 1976, 4 May 1976, BGBl I S. 1153, Arts. 1, 7; German version available at: http://bundesrecht.juris.de/bundesrecht/mitbestg/gesamt.pdf (last accessed: 1 February 2013). For analysis of the background to the 1976 reforms, see Heinz Hartmann, Codetermination Today and Tomorrow, 13(1) Brit. J. Ind. Rel 54 (1975); Nörr, Teil 2, supra note 11, at Chapter 6.Google Scholar

178 Du Plessis et al., supra note 10, at 155. See also Herbert Spero, Co-Determination in Germany, 48 Am. Pol Sci. Rev. 1114 (1954).Google Scholar

179 Unternehmensrechtskommission 177 (Corporate Law Commission, 1980), cited by von Hien, supra note 76, at 224.Google Scholar

180 Aktiengesetz vom 6 September 1965, 6 Sep. 1965, BGBl I, s. 1089, available at: http://www.gesetze-iminternet.de/bundesrecht/aktg/gesamt.pdf (Ger.)(last accessed: 1 February 2013). For comparative analysis, see Andenas & Wooldridge, supra note 10. For a recent account of the current law, see Tim Drygala, Marko Staake & Stephan Szalai, Kapitalgesellschaftrecht (2012). See also Vagts, supra note 153, at 27; and, for a detailed analysis of the debates leading to the 1965 Law, see Nörr, Teil 1, supra note 11, at 201–214 and Chapter 9. See also Heinz-Uwe Dettling, Die Entstehungsgeschichte des Konzernrechts im Aktiengesetz von 1965 (1997).Google Scholar

181 von Hein, supra note 76, at 195–196.Google Scholar

182 See Aktiengesetz vom 6 September 1965, supra note 180, Arts. 17–18, 291–323; see Nörr, Teil 1, supra note 11, at 253–256. In 1985, these rules were extended by the Federal Supreme Court to GmbH based groups in the Autokran judgment: see Nörr, Teil 2, supra note 11, at 257–258. For a more recent analysis, see Rene Reich-Graefe, Changing Paradigms: The Liability of Corporate Groups in Germany, 37 Conn. L. R. 785 (2005).Google Scholar

183 See Aktiengesetz vom 6 September 1965, supra note 180, Arts. 128,135.Google Scholar

184 For evidence of levels of concentration and bank control in late 20th century Germany, see Jeremy Edwards & Markus Nibbler, Corporate Governance: Banks Versus Concentration in Germany, 15 Economic Policy No. 31 (2000), available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=247410 (last accessed: 1 February 2013); Ekkehart Boehmer, Who Controls German Corporations?, in Corporate Governance Regimes: Convergence and Diversity 268 (Joseph McCahery, Piet Moerland, Theo Raaijmakers & Luc Renneboog eds., 2002); see also Fohlin, supra note 101, at 231–237.Google Scholar

185 See Fohlin, supra note 101, at 231–237.Google Scholar

186 Further, , see Muchlinski, supra note 104, at 329–330.Google Scholar

187 von Hein, , supra note 76, at 196.Google Scholar

188 See Fohlin, , supra note 78, at 314.Google Scholar

189 On which, see von Hein, supra note 76, at 218–248; Fohlin, supra note 101, at 267–268.Google Scholar

190 Unification Treaty, August 31, 1990, Aug. 31, 1990, GB1. (GDR) I, s. 1629; BGB1. (FRG) II, s. 889, available at: http://germanhistorydocs.ghi-dc.org/pdf/eng/Unification_Treaty.pdf (last accessed: 1 February 2013).Google Scholar

191 See further Wasmuth, Johannes, The Reunification Treaty between the Federal Republic of Germany and the German Democratic Republic and its effects on commercial, company and bankruptcy law, 1991 Int'l Bus. L. J. 765 (1991), who lists the following types of entities: “volkseigene Kombinate” (peoples’ combines), “Kombinatsbetriebe” (combine enterprises) and “volkseigene Betriebe” (peoples’ enterprises).Google Scholar

192 Treuhandgesetz vom 17 Juni 1990 (Trust Law), 17 June 1990, GBl. (GDR) I, s. 300, available at: http://www.gesetze-im-internet.de/bundesrecht/treuhg/gesamt.pdf (Ger.)(last accessed: 1 February 2013). The handling of privatization by the Treuhand has been controversial: see Wendy Carlin, Privatization in East Germany, 1990–92, 10(3) Germ. Hist. 335 (1992); Joerg Roesler, Privatisation Alone Cannot Solve East Germany's Economic Problems: Reflections on Wendy Carlin's Article ‘Privatisation in East Germany 1990–92', 12(1) Germ. Hist. 64 (1994); Wendy Carlin, Wages, Privatization and Industrial Collapse: A Reply to Jorg Roesler's reply ‘Privatization alone cannot solve east Germany's economic problems’ (German History 12/1 (1994)), 12(2) Germ. Hist. 190 (1994).Google Scholar

193 For the legal forms of enterprises in transformation, see Michael Gruson & Georg F. Thoma, Investments In The Territory Of The Former German Democratic Republic, 14(3) Fordham Int'l L. J. 540, 545–552 (1990).Google Scholar

194 Fohlin, , supra note 101, at 267.Google Scholar

195 See Dignam & Galanis, supra note 1, at 362–371.Google Scholar

196 This is achieved through the declaration of conformity pursuant to Article 161 of the Aktiengesetz 1965, as amended by Art.1 (16) of the Transparency and Disclosure law, 19 July 2002, BGBl 2002 I, Nr. 50 s. 2681, available at: http://www.bgbl.de/Xaver/start.xav?startbk=Bundesanzeiger_BGBl (last accessed: 1 February 2013), which entered into force on 26 July 2002. See The German Corporate Governance Code, as amended on 15 May 2012, available at: http://www.corporate-governance-code.de/eng/download/kodex_2012/D_CorGov_final_May_2012.pdf (last accessed: 1 February 2013). See also Dignam & Galanis, supra note 1, at 342–343.Google Scholar

197 Case C-212/97, Centros Ltd v. Erhvervs-OG Selskabsstyrelsen, 1999 2 CM.LR. 551; see also Dignam & Galanis, supa note 1, at 315–319.Google Scholar

198 Martin Höpner & Gregory Jackson An Emerging Market for Corporate Control? The Mannesmann Takeover and German Corporate Governance, Discussion Paper 01/4 (2001), available at: http://www.mpi-fgkoeln.mpg.de/pu/mpifg_dp/dp01-4.pdf (last accessed: 1 February 2013); Dignam & Galanis, supra note 1, at 371–378.Google Scholar

199 See Dignam & Galanis, supra note 1, at 319–322; Jackson, supra note 172.Google Scholar

200 For the extensive discussion by Dignam and Galanis, who see a degree of convergence but also consider that the insider model of German law has on the whole endured and could resurface as a superior response to the impact of global economic crisis, see Dignam & Galanis, supra note 1, at 409–419.Google Scholar

201 See the papers by Herrigel, , supra note 9, the special issue of Enterprise and Society (Vol.8(3), 2007), and - on Germany - the work of Fohlin cited in the paper.Google Scholar

202 See Herrigel, supra note 9, at 481–482.Google Scholar

203 See Franks et. al., supra note 57, at 4 note 3, citing the criticism of the supervisory board by Georg Siemens.Google Scholar

204 On which, see Fulbrook, supra note 163, at 137–144, who believes that the state was intervening in industry but does not document the point. The more convincing position is given by von Hein, supra note 76 as discussed in supra note 111, Mann, supra note 111, and Overy, supra note 111.Google Scholar

205 See Klages, Philipp, The contractual turn: How legal experts shaped corporate governance reforms in Germany, 1 Socio-Economic Review Advance Access (2012).Google Scholar

206 See Eva Heidhues & Chris Patel, A critique of Gray's framework on accounting values using Germany as a case study, 22 Critical Perspectives on Accounting 273, 281 (2011).Google Scholar