Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-03T19:10:36.802Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Money as a computational machine

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 November 2023

Inigo Wilkins*
Affiliation:
Willem de Kooning Academy Netherlands
Bogdan Dragos
Affiliation:
Charta Partners UK
*
Corresponding author: Inigo Wilkins, Willem de Kooning Academy, Rotterdam University of Applied Sciences, 3011 TA Rotterdam, Netherlands. Email: [email protected].
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

This article presents a speculative philosophical account of money as a computational machine. It does so by leveraging a computational and machinic framework, drawing primarily from the work of Philip Mirowski and Jean Cartelier. The argument is focused on a specific level of abstraction, i.e., the monetary operations involved in the creation and transfer of units of account, asking whether it is possible to view these operations as computations that mediate economic relations. As the primary function of such a machine would be one of social coordination, the article also highlights the political consequences of its implementation across society.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-No Derivatives licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits noncommercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is unaltered and is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial re-use or in order to create a derivative work.
Copyright
© 2022 The Author(s)

References

Aglietta, M. and Orlean, A. (1998) La monnaie souveraine. Paris: Jacob.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Babbage, C. (1833) On the Economy of Machinery and Manufactures. Third edition. London: Charles Knight.Google Scholar
Bawa-Cavia, A. (2022) Logiciel: Six Seminars on Computational Reason. Triple Ampersand.Google Scholar
Bell, S. (2001) The role of the state and the hierarchy of money. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 25(2): 149–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benetti, C. and Cartelier, J. (1996) Money and price theory. Lecturas de Economia, 44(44): 3754.Google Scholar
Boy, N. and Gabor, D. (2019) Collateral times. Economy and Society, 48(3): 295314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braun, B. and Gabor, D. (2020) Central banking, shadow banking, and infrastructural power. In: Mader, P., Mertens, D. and van der Zwan, N. (eds.) The Routledge International Handbook of Financialization. London: Routledge, 241–52.Google Scholar
Campbell-Kelly, M. (1998) Data processing and technological change: The Post Office Savings Bank, 1861-1930. Technology and Culture, 39(1): 132.Google Scholar
Campbell-Kelly, M. (2010) Victorian data processing. Communications of the ACM, 53(10): 1921.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carruthers, B. and Stinchcombe, A. (1999) The social structure of liquidity: Flexibility, markets, and states. Theory and Society, 28(3): 353–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cartelier, J. (1996) Payments systems and dynamics in a monetary economy. In: Deleplace, G. and Nell, E.J. (eds.) Money in Motion. London: Palgrave Macmillan, 200–37.Google Scholar
Cartelier, J. (2007) The hypostasis of money: An economic point of view. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 31(2): 217–33.Google Scholar
Cartelier, J. (2010) Money is the scribe of a market economy. In: Amato, M., Doria, L. and Fantcci, F. (eds.) Money and Calculation. London: Palgrave Macmillan, 1633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cartelier, J. (2018) Money, Markets and Capital: A Case for Monetary Analysis. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castelle, M. (2015) Making markets durable: Transaction processing in finance. Working paper available upon request.Google Scholar
Chavas, J.P. and Bromley, D. (2008) On the origins and evolving role of money. Journal of Insititutional and Theoretical Economics, 164 (4): 624–51.Google Scholar
Deleuze, G. (2006) Foucault. London: Continuum.Google Scholar
Deleuze, G. and Guattari, F. (1983) Anti-Oedipus: Capitalism and Schizophrenia. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
Deleuze, G. and Guattari, F. (1988) A Thousand plateaus: Capitalism and Schizophrenia. London: Athlone Press.Google Scholar
Desan, C. (2014) Making Money: Coin, Currency, and the Coming of Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dodd, N. (2014) The Social Life of Money. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Esposito, E. (2011) The Future of Futures: The Time of Money in Financing and Society. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gabor, D. and Vestergaard, J. (2016) Towards a theory of shadow money. Available at: <https://www.ineteconomics.org/uploads/papers/Towards_Theory_Shadow_Money_GV_INET.pdf/>. Accessed 12 March 2022..+Accessed+12+March+2022.>Google Scholar
Gibson-Light, M. (2018) Ramen politics: Informal money and logics of resistance in the contemporary American prison. Qualitative Sociology, 41(2): 199220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldin, D., Smolka, S.A. and Wegner, P. (eds.) (2006) Interactive Computation: The New Paradigm. Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldin, D. and Wegner, P. (2008) The interactive nature of computing: Refuting the Strong-Church Turing thesis. Minds and Machines, 18: 1738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graeber, D. (2011) Debt: The First 5,000 Years. New York: Melville House.Google Scholar
Hayles, K. (2016) Cognitive assemblages: Technical agency and human interactions. Critical Inquiry, 43(1): 3255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayles, K. (2019) Literary texts as cognitive assemblages: The case of electronic literature. Interface Critique Journal, 2: 173–95.Google Scholar
Herrenschmidt, C. (1999) Writing, money, and networks: Inventions, ancient and modern. Le Débat, 106(4): 1736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrmann-Pillath, C. (2009) Outline of a Darwinian theory of money. Frankfurt School of Finance and Management Working Paper Series 128. Available at: <http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1468118>. Accessed 11 March 2022.CrossRef.+Accessed+11+March+2022.>Google Scholar
Herrmann-Pillath, C. (2011) Naturalizing institutions: Evolutionary principles and application on the case of money. Frankfurt School of Finance and Management Working Paper Series 182. Available at: <http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1960392/>. Accessed 11 March 2022.CrossRef.+Accessed+11+March+2022.>Google Scholar
Herrmann-Pillath, C. (2016) Institutional naturalism: Reflections on Masahiko Aoki's contribution to institutional economics. Available at: <http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2727716/>. Accessed 11 March 2022.. Accessed 11 March 2022.' href=https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2727716>CrossRef. Accessed 11 March 2022.' href=https://scholar.google.com/scholar?q=Herrmann-Pillath,+C.+(2016)+Institutional+naturalism:+Reflections+on+Masahiko+Aoki's+contribution+to+institutional+economics.+Available+at:+.+Accessed+11+March+2022.>Google Scholar
Hudson, M. (2004) The archaeology of money: Debt versus barter theories of money's origins. In: Wray, R. (ed.) Credit and State Theories of Money. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 99127.Google Scholar
Ingham, G. (1996) Money is a social relation. Review of Social Economy, 54(4): 507–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kocherlakota, N. (1998) Money is memory. Journal of Economic Theory, 81(2): 232–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawson, T. (2016) Social positioning and the nature of money. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 40(4): 961–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehrling, P. (2001) Minsky, modern finance and the case of Long Term Capital Management. In: Bellofiore, R. and Ferri, P. (eds.) Financial Keynesianism and Market Instability. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, Chapter 8.Google Scholar
Mehrling, P. (2013) The inherent hierarchy of money. In: Taylor, L., Rezai, A. and Michl, T. (eds.) Social Fairness and Economics: Economic Essays in the Spirit of Duncan Foley. London: Routledge, 394404.Google Scholar
Mehrling, P. (2015) Elasticity and discipline in the global swap network. Institute for New Economic Thinking Working Paper Series, no. 27. Available at: <https://www.ineteconomics.org/uploads/papers/WP27-Mehrling.pdf/>. Accessed 10 March 2022..+Accessed+10+March+2022.>Google Scholar
Mehrling, P. (2017) Financialization and its discontents. Finance and Society, 3(1): 110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menger, C. (1892) On the origin of money. The Economic Journal, 2(6): 239–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Millo, Y., Muniesa, F., Panourgias, N. and Scott, S.V. (2005) Organised detachment: Clearinghouse mechanisms in financial markets. Information and Organization, 15(3): 229–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, P. (1986) Mathematical formalism and economic explanation. In: Mirowski, P. (ed.) The Reconstruction of Economic Theory: Recent Economic Thought. Dordrecht: Springer, 179240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, P. (1990) Learning the meaning of a dollar: Conservation principles and the social theory of value in economic theory. Social Research, 57(3): 689717.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. (1991) Postmodernism and the social theory of value. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 13(4): 565–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, P. (2002) Machine Dreams: Economics Becomes a Cyborg Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. (2007) Markets come to bits: Evolution, computation and markomata in economic science. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 63(2): 209–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, P. (2010) Inherent vice: Minsky, markomata, and the tendency of markets to undermine themselves. Journal of Institutional Economics, 6(4): 415–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, P. (2014) Modern shadow banking as Schmittian ‘exception’: Meditations on a constructivist approach to the theory of money and debt. Paper presented at the Money and Finance Workshop, 11-12 August. University of Sydney, Australia.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. and Somefun, K. (1998) Markets as evolving computational entities. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 8(4): 329–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mumford, L. (1967) The Myth of the Machine: Technics and Human Development. London: Secker and Warburg.Google Scholar
Mumford, L. (1971) The Myth of the Machine: The Pentagon of Power. London: Secker and Warburg.Google Scholar
Negarestani, R. (2014) The labour of the inhuman, part I: Human. e-flux journal, 52. Available at: https://www.e-flux.com/journal/52/59920/the-labor-of-the-inhuman-part-i-human/>. Accessed 11 March 2022.Google Scholar
Orlean, A. (1992) The origin of money. In: Varela, F. and Dupuy, J.-P. (eds.) Understanding Origins: Boston Studies in the Philosophy and History of Science. Springer: Dordrecht, 113–43.Google Scholar
Parry, J. and Bloch, M. (eds.) (1989) Money and the Morality of Exchange. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piccinini, G. and Bahar, S. (2013) Neural computation and the computational theory of cognition. Cognitive Science, 37(3): 453–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piccinini, G. (2007) Computing mechanisms. Philosophy of Science, 74(4): 501–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pistor, K. (2019) The Code of Capital: How the Law Creates Wealth and Inequality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Searle, J. (2017) Money: Ontology and deception. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 41(5): 1453–470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shaikh, A. (2016) Capitalism: Competition, Conflict, Crises. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shannon, C. (1938) A symbolic analysis of relay and switching circuits. Transactions of the American Institute of Electrical Engineers, 57(12): 713–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmel, G. (1978) The Philosophy of Money. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Simondon, G. (1989) Du mode d'existence des objets techniques: Aubier philosophie. Paris: Aubier.Google Scholar
Stiegler, B. (1998) Technics and Time. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turing, A. (1937) On computable numbers, with an application to the Entscheidungsproblem. Proceedings of the London Mathematical Society, 42(2): 544–46.Google Scholar
Ulgen, F. (2010) La coordination en économie: un essai sur la monnaie. Available at: <https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/35468/>. Accessed 10 March 2022..+Accessed+10+March+2022.>Google Scholar
von Neumann, J. (1951) The general and logical theory of automata. In: Jeffress, L.A. (ed.) Cerebral Mechanisms in Behavior: The Hixon Symposium. Oxford: Wiley, 141.Google Scholar
Weber, I. (2019) On the necessity of money in an exchange-constituted economy: The cases of Smith and Marx. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 43(6): 1459–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiener, N. (1965) Cybernetics or Control and Communication in the Animal and the Machine. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google ScholarPubMed
Wolfram, S. (2021) Even beyond physics: Introducing multicomputation as a fourth general paradigm for theoretical science. Available at: <https://writings.stephenwolfram.com/2021/09/even-beyond-physics-introducing-multicomputation-as-a-fourth-general-paradigm-for-theoretical-science/#the-path-to-a-new-paradigm/>. Accessed 10 March 2022..+Accessed+10+March+2022.>Google Scholar