Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T14:17:28.311Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Discourse ethics for debt markets

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 January 2024

Timothy C. Johnson*
Affiliation:
Heriot-Watt University, UK
*
Corresponding author: Timothy C. Johnson, Department of Actuarial Mathematics and Statistics, Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh EH14 4AS, UK. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

This article develops a pragmatic theory of finance in which markets are considered to be centres of communicative action in the face of uncertainty. This contrasts with the conventional approach that portrays markets as centres of strategic action in the face of scarcity. The argument follows Habermas and entails that a financial market must address the truthfulness, truth, and rightness of the statements made by its participants (i.e., the prices quoted). I claim that these discursive norms have been implicit in historical financial markets as expressed in the norms of sincerity, reciprocity, and charity. I conclude by proposing that ‘trust’ in commerce is a synthesis of the three discursive norms. The motivation of the article is to address the crisis of legitimacy that the financial system is experiencing, particularly in the United Kingdom (UK) and the United States (US).

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-No Derivatives licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits noncommercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is unaltered and is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial re-use or in order to create a derivative work.
Copyright
© 2016 The Author(s)

References

Ackroyd, P. (2001) London: The Biography. London: Vintage.Google Scholar
Altman, J. (1985) Gambling as a mode of redistributing and accumulating cash among Aborigines: A case study from Arnhem Land. In: Caldwell, G., Dickerson, M., Haig, B., and Sylvan, L. (eds.) Gambling in Australia. Beckenham: Croom Helm, 5067.Google Scholar
Attard, B. (2000) Makinga market: The jobbers of the London Stock Exchange, 1800-1986. Financial History Review, 7(1): 524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auden, W. (2013) The Dyer's Hand. London: Faber & Faber.Google Scholar
Bagehot, W. (1971) The only game in town. Financial Analysts Journal, 27(2): 1217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berger, H. (2010) Mercifixion in The Merchant of Venice: The riches of embarrassment. Renaissance Drama, 38(1): 345.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beunza, D. and Stark, D. (2012) From dissonance to resonance: Cognitive interdependence in quantitative finance. Economy and Society, 41(3): 383417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bjerg, O. (2014) Making Money: The Philosophy of Crisis Capitalism. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973) The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 81(3): 637–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bradbrook, M.C. (1969) Moral theme and romantic story. In: Wilders, J. (ed.) Shakespeare: The Merchant of Venice. A Casebook. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Brenner, R. (2003) Merchants and Revolution: Commercial Change, Political Conflict, and London's Overseas Traders, 1550-1653. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Brenner, R. and Brenner, G.A. (1990) Gambling and Speculation: A Theory, a History, and a Future of Some Human Decisions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brenner, R., Brenner, G.A., and Brown, A. (2008) A World of Chance: Betting on Religion, Games, and Wall Street. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadie, S. and Rowe, C. (2011) Aristotle: Nicomachean Ethics. Translation, Introduction, Commentary. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Burgon, J.W. (2004) The Life and Times of Sir Thomas Gresham: Volume 2. Boston, MA: Adamant Media.Google Scholar
Carruthers, B.G. and Stinchcombe, A.L. (1999) The social structure of liquidity: Flexibility, markets, and states. Theory and Society, 28(3): 353–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coghill, N. (1950) The basis of Shakespearean comedy: A study in Medieval affinities. Essays and Studies, 3:128.Google Scholar
Cookson, G. (2003) Quaker families and business networks in nineteenth-century Darlington. Quaker Studies, 8(2): 119–40.Google Scholar
Coolidge, J.S. (1976). Law and love in The Merchant of Venice. Shakespeare Quarterly, 27(3): 243–63.Google Scholar
Crosby, A.W. (1997) The Measure of Reality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, J. (2008) The turn in recent economics and return to orthodoxy. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32(3): 349–66.Google Scholar
de Goede, M. (2005) Virtue, Fortune, and Faith: A Genealogy of Finance. Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
Decock, W. (2012) In defense of commercial capitalism: Lessius, partnerships and the Contractus Trinus. Max-Planck-Institute for European Legal History Research Paper Series, 1(4): 136.Google Scholar
Dickinson, J.W. (1962) Renaissance equity and Measure for Measure. Shakespeare Quarterly, 13(3): 287–97.Google Scholar
Duhon, T. (2012) How the Trading Floor Really Works. London: Wiley.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fabian, A.V. (1999) Card Sharps and Bucket Shops: Gambling in Nineteenth-Century America. New York, NY: Routledge.Google Scholar
FCIC (Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission) (2011) The Financial Crisis Inquiry Report: Final Report of the National Commission on the Causes of the Financial and Economic Crisis in the United States. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office. Available at: <https://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/GPO-FCIC/pdf/GPO-FCIC.pdf/>. Accessed 21 July 2016..+Accessed+21+July+2016.>Google Scholar
Ferber, M. (1990) The ideology of The Merchant of Venice. English Literary Renaissance, 20(3): 431–64.Google Scholar
Fibonacci, L. and Sigler, L. (2003) Fibonacci's Liber Abaci: A Translation Into Modern English of Leonardo Pisano's Book of Calculation. New York, NY: Springer.Google Scholar
Flyvbjerg, B. (1998) Habermas and Foucault: Thinkers for civil society? The British Journal of Sociology, 49(2): 210–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franklin, J. (2001) The Science of Conjecture: Evidence and Probability before Pascal. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Fraser, N. (1990) Rethinking the public sphere: A contribution to the critique of actually existing democracy. Social Text, 25/26: 5680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goetzmann, W.N. (2004) Fibonacci and the financial revolution. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series, No. 10352. Available at: <http://www.nber.org/papers/w10352.pdf/>. Accessed 21 July 2016.CrossRef.+Accessed+21+July+2016.>Google Scholar
Gollancz, I. (1931) Allegory and Mysticism in Shakespeare: A Medievalist on The Merchant of Venice.Google Scholar
London: Folcroft Library Editions. Graeber, D. (2011) Debt: The First 5,000 Years. London: Melville House.Google Scholar
Habermas, J. (1985) The Theory of Communicative Action: Reason and the Rationalization of Society. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Habermas, J. (1990) Moral Consciousness and Communicative Action. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Hadden, R.W. (1994) On the Shoulders of Merchants: Exchange and the Mathematical Conception of Nature in Early Modern Europe. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Hamlin, H. (2013) The Bible in Shakespeare. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haug, E.G. and Taleb, N.N. (2011) Option traders use (very) sophisticated heuristics, never the Black-Scholes-Merton formula. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 77(2): 97106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Homer, S. and Sylla, R. (1996) A History of Interest Rates. Third edition. Brunswick, NY: Rutgers University Press.Google Scholar
Hume, D. (2007) Essays: Moral, Political and Literary: Political Discourses. London: Lightning Source [orig. pub. 1752].Google Scholar
Jadlow, J.M. (1977) Adam Smith on usury laws. The Journal of Finance, 32(4): 1195–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, F.R. (1940) Gresham College: Precursor of the Royal Society. Journal of the History of Ideas, 1(4): 413–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, T.C. (2011) What is financial mathematics? In: Pitic, M. (ed.) The Best Writing on Mathematics: 2010. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 4346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, T.C. (2015) Reciprocity as a foundation of financial economics. The Journal of Business Ethics, 131(1): 4367.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Judson, L. (1997) Aristotle on fair exchange. In: Taylor, C.C.W. (ed.) Oxford Studies in Ancient Philosophy 15. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 147–75.Google Scholar
Kaye, J. (1998) Economy and Nature in the Fourteenth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kimball-Stanley, A. (2008/2009) Insurance and credit default swaps: Should like things be treated alike? Connecticut Insurance Law Journal, 15(1): 241–66.Google Scholar
Kirsch, A. (2008) Auden and Christianity. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Knight, F.H. (2006) Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. New York, NY: Cosimo [orig. pub. 1921].Google Scholar
Krippner, G.R. (2005) The financialization of the American economy. Socio-Economic Review, 3(2): 173208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, J. (2012) Freaks of Fortune: The Emerging World of Capitalism and Risk in America. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewalski, B.K. (1962) Biblical allusion and allegory in The Merchant of Venice. Shakespeare Quarterly, 13(3): 327–43.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2008) An Engine, Not a Camera: How Financial Models Shape Markets. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2011). The credit crisis as a problem in the sociology of knowledge. American Journal of Sociology, 116(6): 1778–841.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mackenzie, D. and Millo, Y. (2001) Negotiating a market, performing theory: The historical sociology of a financial derivatives exchange. Conference of the European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy [Online], August. Available at: <http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.279029/>. Accessed 21 July 2016.CrossRef.+Accessed+21+July+2016.>Google Scholar
McCloskey, D.N. (1998). Bourgeois virtue and the history of P and S. The Journal of Economic History, 58(2): 297317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Midgley, G. (1960) The Merchant of Venice: A Reconsideration. Essays in Criticism, 10(2): 119–33.Google Scholar
Millo, Y. (2003) Where Do Financial Markets Come From? Historical Sociology of Financial Derivatives Markets. Unpublished doctoral thesis. University of Edinburgh.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. (1998) Machine dreams: Economic agents as cyborgs. History of Political Economy, 29(1): 1340.Google Scholar
Mitchell, W.E. (1988) The defeat of hierarchy: Gambling as exchange in a Sepik Society. American Ethnologist, 15(4): 638–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mols, R. (1974) Population in Europe, 1500-1750. In: Cipolla, C. (ed.) The Fontana Economic History of Europe: The Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries. London: Collins/Fontana, 1582.Google Scholar
Mowatt, B.A. and Werstine, P. (eds) (n.d.). The Merchant of Venice. Washington, DC: Folger Shakespeare Library [Online]. Available at: <http://www.folgerdigitaltexts.org/html/MV.html/>. Accessed 21 July 2016..+Accessed+21+July+2016.>Google Scholar
Muniesa, F. (2007) Market technologies and the pragmatics of prices. Economy and Society, 36(3): 377–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, A.L. (2009) The Origins of English Financial Markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nash, R.C. (2000) The economy. In: Bergin, J. (ed.) The Seventeenth Century: Europe 1598-1715. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Newman, K. (1987) Portia's ring: Unruly women and structures of exchange in The Merchant of Venice. Shakespeare Quarterly, 38(1): 1933.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nicholas, D. (2006) Economy. In: Power, D. (ed.) The Central Middle Ages. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 5790.Google Scholar
Outhwaite, W. (2013) Bourdieu and Habermas: ‘Linguistic exchange’ versus ‘communicative action’? A reply to Simon Susen. Social Epistemologa 27(3-4): 247–49.Google Scholar
PCBS (Parliamentary Commission on Banking Standards) (2013) Changing Banking for Good [Online], June. Available at: <http://www.parliament.uk/business/committees/committees-a-z/joint-select/professional-standards-in-the-banking-industry/publications/?type=&session=1&sort=false&inquiry=all/>. Accessed 21 July 2016..+Accessed+21+July+2016.>Google Scholar
Peirce, C.S. (1957) Essays in the Philosophy of Science. Indianapolis, IN: Bobbs-Merrill.Google Scholar
Perlman, M. (1997) Looking for ourselves in the mirror of the past: With what does economics cope? and the differences in the Jewish and Christian rationales for handling usury. In: Price, B.B. (ed.) Ancient Economic Thought. London: Routledge, 5872.Google Scholar
Pindyck, R.S. (2013). Climate change policy: What do the models tell us? Journal of Economic Literature, 5(3): 860–72.Google Scholar
Poisson, S. (1837) Recherches sur la Probabilité des Jugements en Matière Criminelle et en Matière Civile. Paris: Bachelier.Google Scholar
Poitras, G. (2000) The Early History of Financial Economics, 1478-1776. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poitras, G. (2006) Life annuity valuation. In: Poitras, G. (ed.) Pioneers of Financial Economics: Contributions Prior to Irving Fisher. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 7999.Google Scholar
Prior, A. and Kirby, M. (2006) The Society of Friends and Business Culture, 1700-1830. In: Jeremy, D. (ed.) Religion, Business and Wealth in Modern Britain. London: Routledge, 115–36.Google Scholar
Rainbolt, G.W. (1990) Mercy: An independent, imperfect virtue. American Philosophical Quarterly, 27(2): 169–73.Google Scholar
Ramsey, F. (1931) Truth and probability. In: Braithwaite, R. (ed.) Ramsey, 1931: The Foundations of Mathematics and Other Logical Essays. London: Kegan, Paul, Trench, Trubner & Co., 156–98.Google Scholar
Roberts, H. (2003) Friends in business: Researching the history of Quaker involvement in industry and commerce. Quaker Studies, 8(2): 172–93.Google Scholar
Roffe, J. (2015) Abstract Market Theory. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothbard, M.N. (1996) Economic Thought before Adam Smith. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Sahlins, M. (2003) Stone Age Economics. London: Routledge [orig. pub. 1972].Google Scholar
Schneider, I. (1987) The probability calculus in the nineteenth century. In: Kruger, L., Daston, LJ., and Heidelberger, M. (eds.) The Probabilistic Revolution, Volume 1: Ideas in History. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 191214.Google Scholar
Seaford, R. (2004) Money and the Early Greek Mind: Homer, Philosophy, Tragedy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seppänen, R., Blomqvist, K., and Sundqvist, S. (2007) Measuring inter-organizational trust: A critical review of the empirical research in 1990-2003. Industrial Marketing Management, 36(2): 249–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sharp, R.A. (1986) Gift exchange and the economies of spirit in The Merchant of Venice. Modern Philology, 83(3): 250–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sisk, J. (1969) Bondage and release in The Merchant of Venice. Shakespeare Quarterly, 20(2): 217–23.Google Scholar
Sotiropoulos, D.P., Milios, J. and Lapatsioras, S. (2013) A Political Economy of Contemporary Capitalism and Its Crisis: Demystifying Finance. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, A. (1986) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: Penguin Classics [orig. pub. 1776].Google Scholar
Stern, N. (2008) The economics of climate change. American Economic Review, 98(2): 137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Susen, S. (2013) Bourdieusian reflections on language: Unavoidable conditions of the real speech situation. Social Epistemology, 27(3-4): 199246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swan, E.J. (1999) Building the Global Market: A 4,000-Year History of Derivatives. Leiden: Kluwer Law.Google Scholar
Swedberg, R. (2012) Theorizing in sociology and social science: Turning to the context of discovery. Theory and Society, 41(1): 141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tett, G. (2009) Fool's Gold: How the Bold Dream of a Small Tribe at J.P. Morgan was Corrupted by Wall Street Greed and Unleashed a Catastrophe. London: Little Brown.Google Scholar
Triana, P. (2009) Lecturing Birds on Flying: Can Mathematical Theories Destroy the Financial Markets? London: Wiley.Google Scholar
van Staveren, I. (2007) Beyond utilitarianism and deontology: Ethics in economics. Review of Political Economy, 19(1): 2135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Lilienfeld-Toal, U. and Mookherjee, D. (2010) The political economy of debt bondage. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2(3): 4484.Google Scholar
Walvin, J. (1998) The Quakers: Money and Morals. London: John Murray.Google Scholar
Waterworth, J. (1848) The Council of Trent: The Canons and Decrees of the Sacred and Oecumenical Council of Trent. London: Dolman.Google Scholar
Watts, M. (2012) JP Morgan and the CRM: How Basel 2.5 beached the London whale. Risk Magazine [Online], October. Available at: <http://www.risk.net/digital_assets/5926/jpm.pdf/> Accessed 21 July 2016.+Accessed+21+July+2016.>Google Scholar
Wilson, M.J. (1994) Views of justice in Shakespeare's The Merchant of Venice and Measure for Measure. Notre Dame Law Review, 70(3): 695726.Google Scholar