Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T05:30:52.925Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Sex ratios and gender norms: why both are needed to understand sexual conflict in humans

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 January 2024

Renée V. Hagen*
Affiliation:
Department of Anthropology, University of California, Los Angeles. United States of America
Brooke A. Scelza
Affiliation:
Department of Anthropology, University of California, Los Angeles. United States of America
*
Corresponding author: Renée V. Hagen; Email: [email protected]

Abstract

Sexual conflict theory has been successfully applied to predict how in non-human animal populations, sex ratios can lead to conflicting reproductive interests of females and males and affect their bargaining positions in resolving such conflicts of interests. Recently this theory has been extended to understand the resolution of sexual conflict in humans, but with mixed success. We argue that an underappreciation of the complex relationship between gender norms and sex ratios has hampered a successful understanding of sexual conflict in humans. In this paper, we review and expand upon existing theory to increase its applicability to humans, where gender norms regulate sex ratio effects on sexual conflict. Gender norms constrain who is on the marriage market and how they are valued, and may affect reproductive decision-making power. Gender norms can also directly affect sex ratios, and we hypothesize that they structure how individuals respond to market value gained or lost through biased sex ratios. Importantly, gender norms are in part a product of women's and men's sometimes conflicting reproductive interests, but these norms are also subject to other evolutionary processes. An integration of sexual conflict theory and cultural evolutionary theory is required to allow for a full understanding of sexual conflict in humans.

Type
Review
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

Social media summary: Hagen and Scelza argue for the integration of sexual conflict and cultural evolutionary theory to understand sexual conflict in humans.

1. Introduction

When two individuals mate, they have both converging and diverging interests. They share an interest in the success of any joint offspring, but may differ in the optimal trade-offs between current and future reproduction, or in the benefits they may be able to gain through inclusive fitness (Parker, Reference Parker, M. S. and N. A.1979; Arnqvist & Rowe, Reference Arnqvist and Rowe2005). Conflict occurs any time two partners cannot simultaneously reach their optimal fitness outcome (Parker, Reference Parker2006). Sexual conflict theory is a framework in evolutionary biology that seeks to explain how such conflicts result in adaptations over evolutionary time, including behavioural flexibility within the lifespan of individuals. One important determinant of conflict is the number of reproductive options that each party has outside of their current partnership, which regulates how much bargaining power each partner has.

Anthropologists are increasingly applying sexual conflict theory to understand human reproductive strategies (e.g. Käär et al., Reference Käär, Jokela, Merilä, Helle and Kojola1998; Bird, Reference Bird1999; Borgerhoff Mulder & Rauch, Reference Borgerhoff Mulder2009; Schacht & Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Schacht and Borgerhoff Mulder2015; Schacht & Smith, Reference Schacht and Smith2017; Lawson et al., Reference Lawson, Schaffnit, Hassan and Urassa2021; Akurugu et al., Reference Akurugu, Dery and Domanban2022; Baraka et al., Reference Baraka, Lawson, Schaffnit, Wamoyi and Urassa2022). In recent years, interest has grown in examining local sex ratios and their effect on reproductive decision-making and bargaining power in romantic relationships (e.g. Abramitzky et al., Reference Abramitzky, Delavande and Vasconcelos2011; Francis, Reference Francis2011; Wei & Zhang, Reference Wei and Zhang2011; Lainiala & Miettinen, Reference Lainiala and Miettinen2013; Schacht & Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Schacht and Borgerhoff Mulder2015; Porter, Reference Porter2016; Uggla & Mace, Reference Uggla and Mace2017; Schacht & Smith, Reference Schacht and Smith2017), and scholars have extended the theory to test predictions on how sex ratios may influence gender norms (Guttentag & Secord, Reference Guttentag and Secord1983; Grosjean & Khattar, Reference Grosjean and Khattar2019; Brooks et al., Reference Brooks, Russo-Batterham and Blake2022).

In this article, we propose a revision of sexual conflict theory when applied to humans, and discuss important considerations that are essential to understanding the relationship between human sex ratios, bargaining power and gender norms (Table 1). Here we define gender norms as social norms, rules or ideals that govern what counts as socially acceptable and virtuous behaviour and that apportion resources, roles, power and entitlements based on (perceived) sex (Ridgeway & Correll, Reference Ridgeway and Correll2004; Cislaghi & Heise, Reference Cislaghi and Heise2020). The term social norm is used to describe conventions or common behaviours in a particular community, but many norms are also injunctive or prescriptive; they refer to moral values and societal standards (Bicchieri, Reference Bicchieri2005). Social norms are thought to have evolved because they render the actions of others more predictable and thereby facilitate coordination between community members (O'Connor, Reference O'Connor2019). Violation of norms can be costly because it can lead to miscoordination with cooperative partners, or to punishment in reaction to deviance from prescriptive norms. Gender norms pertain to behaviour related to marriage, sexual divisions of labour, respectful conduct and other forms of behaviours that are dependent on one's sex. They are often not merely descriptive, but prescribe ‘morally right’ behaviour. While theoretically gender norms could culminate into complete gender egalitarianism, more typically across cultures they describe a gender hierarchy in which men have more power and higher status than women (Schneider & Gough, Reference Schneider and Gough1961; Rosaldo, Reference Rosaldo, Rosaldo and Lamphere1974; Smuts, Reference Smuts1995).

The evolution of social norms is an important topic of study in research on cultural evolution. Cultural evolution theory has been fruitful in showing the importance of biased transmission in the spread and maintenance of cultural traits (Boyd & Richerson, Reference Boyd and Richerson1985, Reference Boyd and Richerson2002; Henrich & Boyd, Reference Henrich and Boyd1998; McElreath et al., Reference McElreath, Boyd and Richerson2003; Efferson et al., Reference Efferson, Lalive, Richerson, McElreath and Lubell2008; Mesoudi, Reference Mesoudi2011b), but limited consideration has been given to power dynamics and their role in the spread of ideas (Singh et al., Reference Singh, Wrangham and Glowacki2017; Cofnas, Reference Cofnas2018) and this field of inquiry has somewhat ignored gender (Lawson et al., Reference Lawson, Alami and Somefun2023). Instead, social influence is mostly considered in the form of deference and voluntary copying of the behaviour of high-status individuals rather than coercion by those in power. In order to gain a deeper understanding of how gender norms spread, persist and change over time, and of how sex ratios and gender norms interact to affect gendered bargaining dynamics, sexual conflict theory and cultural evolution theory need to be better integrated and applied together.

In this review we summarize sexual conflict theory and discuss how it has been used to understand the influence of sex ratios on the reproductive behaviour of non-human animals. Next, we examine how in human populations, sex-ratio effects on gendered bargaining power can interact with culturally specific gender norms in important ways. We propose that to understand this complex relationship, we need to consider gender norms both as products of sexual conflict and variables affecting sexual conflict by constraining women and men's market values and their freedom of choice in reproductive decision-making. Importantly, gender norms can directly affect sex ratios and at the same time affect how people respond to market dynamics that are a product of those sex ratios. We argue that an integration of models of cultural evolution with sexual conflict theory can help to elucidate these interactions, improving our understanding of sexual conflict in humans.

Table 1. Glossary

2. Theory and applications of sexual conflict theory and sex ratios in non-human animals

Research on non-human animals shows that female and male interests may diverge over shared physiological (Trivers, Reference Trivers and B.1972; Kokko & Jennions, Reference Kokko and Jennions2008), morphological (Bonduriansky & Chenoweth, Reference Bonduriansky and Chenoweth2009) or behavioural traits, such as the number of matings (Galliard et al., Reference Galliard, Fitze, Ferrière and Clobert2005), control over fertilization (Parker, Reference Parker2006) and levels of parental investment (Arnqvist & Rowe, Reference Arnqvist and Rowe2005). Sexual conflict theory posits that the degree of bargaining power individuals have in conflicts of interest depends on the relative value of all possible conflict outcomes for each partner, which includes the opportunities each has outside the current interaction. Sexual conflicts of interest are expected to be resolved in favour of the party with a better bargaining position.

A crucial factor for determining bargaining power in sexual conflict is the quality and number of alternative partners available to each party. Holding all else equal, the party with more alternative reproductive opportunities has more leverage to achieve their interests. A classic example of sexual conflict is parental investment: when two individuals reproduce, both are interested in the survival of their offspring, but either party may prefer that the other provide the parental investment required so they can spend their own time and energy pursuing other reproductive opportunities (Trivers, Reference Trivers and B.1972; McNamara et al., Reference Mcnamara, Székely, Webb and Houston2000; Kokko & Jennions, Reference Kokko and Jennions2008). The individual with better options outside the current partnership has a better ‘fallback position’ and therefore is in a stronger bargaining position. They will, on average, see the conflict resolved closer to their optimal outcome (Clutton-Brock, Reference Clutton-Brock1991; Parker, Reference Parker, M. S. and N. A.1979; Arnqvist & Rowe, Reference Arnqvist and Rowe2005; Kokko & Jennions, Reference Kokko and Jennions2008).

At the level of the population, the ratio of males to females is strongly associated with the reproductive options of each sex, and the significance of sex ratio as a determinant of bargaining power in sexual conflict has been exemplified in numerous experimental and observational studies (Carroll, Reference Carroll1991; Székely et al., Reference Székely, Thomas and Cuthill2006; Karlsson et al., Reference Karlsson, Eroukhmanoff and Svensson2010; Liker et al., Reference Liker, Freckleton and Székely2013; Carmona-Isunza et al., Reference Carmona-Isunza, Küpper, Serrano-Meneses and Székely2015; Eberhart-Phillips et al., Reference Eberhart-Phillips, Küpper, Carmona-Isunza, Vincze, Zefania, Cruz-López and Krüger2018).

Sex ratios are usually operationalized as the ratio of males to females in a population, where high sex ratios reflect a bias towards more males and low sex ratios a bias towards more females. There are several sex ratios that are commonly used in these studies. One is the adult sex ratio (ASR), the ratio of reproductively aged males to females. Another is the operational sex ratio (OSR), the ratio of reproductively available males to females, which excludes pregnant, lactating and post-reproductive individuals (Emlen & Oring, Reference Emlen and Oring1977) and in humans sometimes excludes married people. The ASR and OSR do not always track each other because of the higher temporal variation of the latter, especially in smaller populations (Carmona-Isunza et al., Reference Carmona-Isunza, Ancona, Székely, Ramallo-González, Cruz-López, Serrano-Meneses and Küpper2017; Jennions & Fromhage, Reference Jennions and Fromhage2017). In addition, because the time and energy individuals spend on reproduction is itself a product of sexual conflict dynamics (Kokko & Jennions, Reference Kokko and Jennions2008; Kappeler et al., Reference Kappeler, Benhaiem, Fichtel, Fromhage, Höner, Jennions and Goymann2022), which ratio is most relevant depends on the reproductive biology of the species, and on the phenotypic trait and evolutionary time-scale being studied (Jennions & Fromhage, Reference Jennions and Fromhage2017). For example, when testing for sex-ratio effects on male mate guarding behaviour in primates, the ratio of adult males to estrous females may be most relevant, but when examining sexual conflict over parental investment, the OSR is a dependent rather than an independent variable (as which sex spends time in and out of the mating market is the subject of conflict) and the ASR may be more appropriate. The ASR is usually a suitable measure for considering behavioural plasticity and short-term responses to environmental cues in within-species comparisons, and is the measure that is used in most contemporary human studies (Kappeler et al., Reference Kappeler, Benhaiem, Fichtel, Fromhage, Höner, Jennions and Goymann2022).

One important domain of sexual conflict is parental investment. Following the principle of allocation, organisms have limited time and energy available to spend on reproduction. In sexually reproducing species a trade-off exists between allocating time and energy towards behaviours aimed at accessing sexual partners and behaviours associated with caring for existing offspring, as the same resource unit cannot be spent on both (Trivers, Reference Trivers and B.1972). This trade-off can result in a conflict of interest between sexual partners over parental investment, where either partner is better off if the other provides the investment needed to produce surviving offspring so that their own resources are free to be spent on mating effort (Clutton-Brock, Reference Clutton-Brock1991; Székely & Cuthill, Reference Székely and Cuthill2000).

The extent to which individuals can improve their fitness through investing time and energy in mating or parenting behaviour depends on species-level, population-level and individual factors. For example, species vary in the amount of parental care required to raise offspring to adulthood, population-level differences in environments may lead to variation in the costs of parental investment and mating effort, and individuals’ reproductive opportunities are partly determined by their ability to compete for mates with others of the same sex. At the population level, the density and ratio of adult males to females shapes the relative payoffs of mating and parenting behaviours, as it determines the number of potential sexual partners and the severity of competition between members of the same sex. For example, when the sex ratio is skewed, mate scarcity can make it more profitable for the abundant sex to devote energy into maintaining reproductive access to a current mate rather than into competing for additional mates (Kokko & Jennions, Reference Kokko and Jennions2008). To increase their chances of mating, members of the abundant sex can respond to an unfavourable sex ratio by appealing to the preferences of the rare sex, such as by providing more parental care. In addition, the opportunity costs of parental investment go down as the relative benefits of searching for mates decrease owing to strong mating competition. Members of the rare sex can drive a harder bargain in situations of sexual conflict, for example forcing their mate to provide more care while they reenter into the mating pool. We should expect ASR-responsive flexibility in reproductive strategies to occur in species where at least some paternal care is present, and where there is limited reproductive skew (when few males account for most or all offspring in a population, the effect of sex ratios on bargaining power will be minimal). Furthermore, the relationship between reproductive strategies and ASR is dynamic. For example, the mortality risks of parenting and mating strategies can affect the ASR. If increased mating effort leads to higher mortality, the sex ratio becomes more extreme because of a self-reinforcing process where the rarer sex (which would benefit the most from mating effort) becomes even rarer (Kokko & Jennions, Reference Kokko and Jennions2008).

Shorebirds (Scolopaci and Charadrii spp., sandpipers, plovers and allies) have provided an informative model for investigating the relationship between sex ratios and mating and parenting behaviour (Székely et al., Reference Székely, Carmona-Isunza, Engel, Halimubieke, Jones, Kubelka and McDonald2023). Shorebirds exhibit broad inter-specific variation in mating systems and in the ability of both sexes to provide full parental care on their own, but are generally similar in ecology and variation in sex ratios as result of sex-biases in juvenile survival (Bennett & Owens, Reference Bennett and Owens2002; Székely et al., Reference Székely, Thomas and Cuthill2006; Liker et al., Reference Liker, Freckleton and Székely2013; Carmona-Isunza et al., Reference Carmona-Isunza, Küpper, Serrano-Meneses and Székely2015; Eberhart-Phillips et al., Reference Eberhart-Phillips, Küpper, Carmona-Isunza, Vincze, Zefania, Cruz-López and Krüger2018). In line with predictions, research on these species has found that although sex differences in parental investment cannot be fully explained by considering the ASR alone, female-biased adult sex ratios are linked with more female care and higher levels of polygyny (Liker et al., Reference Liker, Freckleton and Székely2013; Eberhart-Phillips et al., Reference Eberhart-Phillips, Küpper, Carmona-Isunza, Vincze, Zefania, Cruz-López and Krüger2018). In species with male-biased adult sex ratios, males are more likely to provide the bulk of parental care, female multiple mating is more common and females have more showy plumage, a trait that is generally associated with investment in mating competition (Liker et al., Reference Liker, Freckleton and Székely2013). A competitive mating market can thus motivate individuals of the abundant sex to provide more parental care to existing offspring (Székely et al., Reference Székely, Carmona-Isunza, Engel, Halimubieke, Jones, Kubelka and McDonald2023). Similar evidence for parenting behaviour as a flexible response to ASR has been observed in other taxa, such as rails (Maynard Smith & Ridpath, Reference Maynard Smith and Ridpath1972), cichlids (Grüter & Taborsky, Reference Grüter and Taborsky2005) and dung beetles (Rosa et al., Reference Rosa, Barta, Fülöp, Székely and Kosztolányi2017).

Evidence in non-human primates for a sex ratio-effect on reproductive strategies is limited, as direct paternal care is absent in most species (Rosenbaum & Silk, Reference Rosenbaum and Silk2022), but some supportive evidence comes from callitrichids. Callitrichids are known to have flexible mating systems. While monogamy is most common, polyandrous bonds are more prevalent when the sex ratio is high; under these circumstances one breeding female may be supported by two caring males (Goldizen, Reference Goldizen1987; Dunbar, Reference Dunbar1995). Breeding pairs may receive help from the male's brother, who may have little chance of siring offspring himself and for whom the opportunity costs of caring are small.

Mating systems can thus be sensitive to a population's ASR, as it affects both the value of parenting and mating behaviours for each sex, as well as their bargaining power (Székely et al., Reference Székely, Weissing and Komdeur2014). However, appealing to the preferences of members of the rare sex is not the only possible response to an unfavourable sex ratio. Sexual conflict theory also predicts that males can use coercion to regain bargaining power lost through a skewed sex ratio, as has been observed in many taxa. Higher ASR is associated with increased rates of male-to-female aggression in crab spiders (Misumena vatia; Holdsworth & Morse, Reference Holdsworth and Morse2000), common lizards (Lacerta vivipara; Galliard et al., Reference Galliard, Fitze, Ferrière and Clobert2005), monk seals (Monachus schauinslandi; Johanos et al., Reference Johanos, Becker, Baker, Ragen, Gilmartin and Gerrodette2010) and possibly feral horses (Equus ferus caballus; Regan et al., Reference Regan, Medill, Poissant and McLoughlin2020), although not all studies have found evidence for a sex-ratio effect (e.g. Head & Brooks, Reference Head and Brooks2006; Baniel et al., Reference Baniel, Cowlishaw and Huchard2017). Aggression used to obtain sexual access to females against their will is prevalent in multiple primate species (Smuts, Reference Smuts1992; Muller & Wrangham, Reference Muller and Wrangham2009; Muller et al., Reference Muller, Thompson, Kahlenberg and Wrangham2011), but there is less evidence that this behaviour is responsive to ASR in primates. Among chimpanzees (Pan troglodytes) at Ngogo in Uganda, females received higher rates of aggression from males when the OSR was higher (Watts, Reference Watts2022), but it is unclear whether this result indicates that males increased their aggressive behaviour towards females when they had many competitors or whether aggression received by females was proportional to the greater number of males present. The latter seems to be the case among mountain gorillas (Gorilla gorilla beringei) studied by Robbins (Reference Robbins, Muller and Wrangham2009). Here the number of males present was not associated with rates of male-to-female aggression, but females did receive more threatening behaviours (chest-beating) when they were in a multi-male vs. single-male group. Similarly, the OSR does not predict how often female chacma baboons (Papio ursinus) are subject to aggression by males in their group (Baniel et al., Reference Baniel, Cowlishaw and Huchard2017). We are not aware of studies testing for a sex-ratio effect on male-to-female aggression among bonobos (Pan paniscus). However, Fruth and Hohmann (Reference Fruth and Hohmann2003) found that although female bonobos with sexual swellings are preferred targets of male aggression, male-to-female aggression is not dependent on the number of females in the group exhibiting swellings. Overall, the current literature does not show much support for consistent sex-ratio effects on male-to-female aggression in our closest relatives.

Mate guarding is another tactic used to monopolize the reproduction of a partner when strong competition owing to a male-biased ASR makes finding a new mate unlikely (Harts & Kokko, Reference Harts and Kokko2013). Adult sex ratio-sensitive mate guarding has been observed among males of some populations of soapberry bugs (Jadera haematoloma; Carroll & Corneli, Reference Carroll and Corneli1995), water striders (Gerris buenoi Kirkaldy and Gerris lacustris; Rowe, Reference Rowe1992; Vepsalainen & Savolainen, Reference Vepsalainen and Savolainen1995), beetles (Lethrus apterus; Rosa et al., Reference Rosa, Barta, Fülöp, Székely and Kosztolányi2017), various crustaceans (Wada et al., Reference Wada, Tanaka and Goshima1999; Mathews, Reference Mathews2002; Karlsson et al., Reference Karlsson, Eroukhmanoff and Svensson2010; Takeshita & Henmi, Reference Takeshita and Henmi2010) and Soay sheep (Ovis aries; Clutton-Brock, Reference Clutton-Brock2016: 632). Mate guarding is also common in some primate species, such as baboons (Papio cynocephalus; Bulger, Reference Bulger1993), sifakas (Propithecus verreauxi; Mass et al., Reference Mass, Heistermann and Kappeler2009), mandrills (Mandrillus sphinx; Setchell et al., Reference Setchell, Charpentier and Wickings2005) and chimpanzees (Watts, Reference Watts1998). Again there is little existing research testing whether this behaviour in primates is sensitive to sex ratios, and the samples in existing studies are small (usually consisting of one or two groups where ASR varies temporally). In one longitudinal study of Japanese macaques (Macaca fuscata), Takahashi (Reference Takahashi2001) was able to capture variation in male mating behaviour in relation to temporal changes in OSR. He found evidence that resident males more often violently interfered with floating males’ mating attempts in periods when the sex ratio is more male biased, although this observation could simply mean that mate guarding was less successful when competition was more fierce. Perhaps the effect of sex ratios on mate guarding behaviour is limited in primates because other population- and species-level factors are more important in determining its payoffs. For example, mate guarding often prevents effective foraging and can increase predation risk (Clutton-Brock, Reference Clutton-Brock2016), and these costs are expected to vary between environments. Mate guarding also is more costly when ovulation is inconspicuous; the absence of a clear signal of females’ fertility makes it difficult to determine when guarding will pay off (Clutton-Brock, Reference Clutton-Brock2016: 480–482). The low reliability of bonobos’ sexual swellings as a signal for ovulation (Reichert et al., Reference Reichert, Heistermann, Keith Hodges, Boesch and Hohmann2002; Douglas et al., Reference Douglas, Hohmann, Murtagh, Thiessen-Bock and Deschner2016) may therefore partly explain why mate guarding and male-to-female aggressive behaviours are rare compared with chimps.

Mate guarding can pave the way for paternal care by decreasing the opportunity costs of care as active guarding places males in closer proximity to their offspring. Several scholars have suggested that male mate guarding preceded the evolution of pair bonding in mammals (Lukas & Clutton-Brock, Reference Lukas and Clutton-Brock2013), and more specifically in humans (Schacht & Bell, Reference Schacht and Bell2016; Loo et al., Reference Loo, Hawkes and Kim2017), but see Gavrilets (Reference Gavrilets2012) for an alternative view. Loo et al. (Reference Loo, Rose, Hawkes and Kim2021) hypothesize that mate guarding as a response to high sex ratios may have preceded the high level of paternal care common in callitrichids.

This summary of current research shows that biased sex ratios can drive sexual conflict by affecting the reproductive opportunities of individuals in the population and are an important source of bargaining power in situations of sexual conflict. Having fewer reproductive options changes the value of different reproductive strategies for both sexes, and can lead to individuals of the more abundant sex adhering more to the preferences of potential mates. Alternatively, males have been shown to respond to an unfavourable bargaining position with physical coercion of females. Evidence for this sex ratio-effect is weak in primates. This could be due to the difficulties in obtaining large sample sizes of populations that vary in ASR but where other factors affecting mating behaviour are held constant (or are statistically accounted for). Alternatively, sex-ratio effects may be completely absent when other ecological factors play a larger role in determining the costs and benefits of parenting and mating strategies.

3. Applying sexual conflict theory and sex ratio predictions to human populations

Following theory and findings in non-human animal populations, sex ratios are also predicted to influence the payoffs of different reproductive strategies in humans. Going one step further, sex ratios have also been hypothesized to affect the status and treatment of women, a point first made by Guttentag and Secord (Reference Guttentag and Secord1983). They argued that while men hold ‘structural’ power in patriarchal societies, women can gain ‘dyadic’ power from a male-biased marriage market, thereby gaining higher status within the domain of the household and family. Guttentag and Secord's (Reference Guttentag and Secord1983) predictions on sex ratio-effects somewhat overlap with evolutionary hypotheses, but where Guttentag and Secord do not question the origins of men's ‘structural power’, evolutionary anthropologists have argued that patriarchal norm systems are the result of a long evolutionary history of sexual conflict (Smuts, Reference Smuts1995). According to this view, the reproductive biologies of females and males result in men's greater interest in control over women's reproduction. Over evolutionary time, this resulted in gender norms that have justified men's dominance over women. Variation in women's status and bargaining power within marriage however is, similar to Guttentag and Secord's concept of dyadic power, hypothesized to depend on their alternative reproductive options, which are partly determined by the population's sex ratio.

Many studies testing sex ratio hypotheses on human reproductive behaviour have suffered from methodological issues and yielded mixed results (reviewed by Schacht & Smith, Reference Schacht and Smith2017). One common issue with studies on sex-ratio effects highlighted by Pollet et al. (Reference Pollet, Stoevenbelt and Kuppens2017) is the use of aggregate national-level data (such as in South & Messner, Reference South and Messner1987; Diekmann, Reference Diekmann, Haag, Mueller and Troitzsch1992; Barber, Reference Barber2000; Kruger et al., Reference Kruger, Fitzgerald and Peterson2010). Adult sex ratio is non-normally distributed at the national level, which can result in a strong but spurious effect of outliers. These analyses also often disregard the confounding effects of geographic clustering and shared cultural histories, which can lead to similarities between nearby populations that may mistakenly be interpreted as the result of shared ecological factors (Pollet et al., Reference Pollet, Stoevenbelt and Kuppens2017). More fine-grained studies have been able to avoid some of these issues by relying on localized sex ratio data, and these studies have been more successful in convincingly identifying cases in which biased sex ratios affect reproductive strategies in line with sexual conflict predictions. We will now review empirical work that uses local ASR data to study these topics, and then discuss how this work is limited by not seriously considering the role of cultural norms.

Many studies find that romantic relationships are more stable in areas when the ASR is male-biased, supporting the sexual conflict prediction that men are more motivated to stay with current partners (and perhaps invest more in their children) when alternative partners are scarce (e.g. Pedersen, Reference Pedersen1991; Pouget, Reference Pouget2017; Uggla & Mace, Reference Uggla and Mace2017; Uggla & Andersson, Reference Uggla and Andersson2018; Grosjean & Khattar, Reference Grosjean and Khattar2019). Anthropologists have also looked for evidence of increased bargaining power of members of the rarer sex. For example, Pollet and Nettle (Reference Pollet and Nettle2008) examine men's probability of marriage in a representative US sample from 1910. They found a positive interaction effect between socioeconomic status (SES) and local ASR on marriage; higher SES was a more important predictor for the probability of marrying in states where the ASR was more male-biased. This could indicate women's better ability to make demands on partners owing to their better bargaining position, although this is not universally true. In a study of cohabitation patterns in Northern Ireland, Uggla and Mace (Reference Uggla and Mace2017) find that women are more likely to cohabitate in areas with higher ASR, but do not find evidence that men's SES becomes more important as a predictor of their probability to be in a stable relationship when the ASR rises.

Schacht and Smith (Reference Schacht and Smith2017) test for sex-ratio effects in a historical sample from nineteenth-century Utah, where the population-level sex ratio was male-biased owing to the immigration of Mormon men, while local differences correlated with variation in male mortality rates and child sex ratios, as well as the incidence of polygyny. Comparing 206 districts with varying sex ratios, their results show that men married later in districts with more male-biased ASR. Schacht and Smith interpret this as evidence for women's higher bargaining power when they are scarce, as women are expected to prefer older partners who are in a better economic position. In a study on the relationship preferences of women and men in French Guyana, Schacht and Borgerhoff Mulder (Reference Schacht and Borgerhoff Mulder2015) find that men hold stronger preferences for long-term relationships in villages with higher ASR. Building on sexual strategies theory (Buss & Schmitt, Reference Buss and Schmitt1993), they assume that, on average, women have a stronger interest in long-term vs. short-term sexual relationships compared with men, and therefore argue that this result may indicate that men adjust their preferences to meet women's interests when they have a poorer market position. An alternative interpretation of their result is that men's varying preferences for stable relationships may reflect ASR-sensitive mate guarding. Another study shows that in Chinese regions where the ASR is higher, families with sons save more money (Wei & Zhang, Reference Wei and Zhang2011). These savings may function as parents’ investment in the marital position of their sons where women (and their families) can make high demands on potential grooms. Also in China, Porter (Reference Porter2016) reports that men smoke and drink less under more male-biased sex ratios, and proposes that this is an effort to make themselves more attractive as romantic partners. Similarly suggesting men's increased efforts to appease potential partners, Francis (Reference Francis2011) finds that when the ASR in Taiwan increased sharply after 1950 as male soldiers and refugees arrived from China, children were more highly educated in regions where sex ratios were higher. These findings are explained as evidence of men's higher parental investment in response to women's increased bargaining power. Finally, historical sex ratios in Australia have been found to predict current-day attitudes towards women's work. In areas that historically had high sex ratios owing to the in-migration of European male convicts, women and men today are more likely to be in favour of traditional gender roles in which women stay at home while men are the sole breadwinners (Grosjean & Khattar, Reference Grosjean and Khattar2019). Women in areas with historically high ASR also report more leisure time, and men provide a larger share of the household income. The authors interpret these results as evidence of women's greater bargaining power, arguing that these historical bargaining dynamics are still reflected in today's norms.

One methodological issue in many of these studies is the comparison of only a few subpopulations: often the behaviours or attitudes of people from only a few towns, regions or cities are compared, and the possibility that factors beyond ASR confound study results is rarely considered. Cultural differences may covary with the ASR in consequential ways. For example, Uggla and Mace (Reference Uggla and Mace2017) report that in their Northern Irish sample ASR is on average higher in rural areas as women more often leave the countryside to move to cities. This suggests that the co-occurrence of high ASR and higher cohabitation rates could at least in part result from cultural differences between urban and rural areas, and gender norms could confound the relationship between ASR and cohabitation rates if women migrate because of a preference for the qualities of urban men. In the Taiwanese study (Francis, Reference Francis2011), the observed correlation between ASR and children's education could be caused by other factors. For example, education may have been more readily available in those areas that attracted more migrants.

Another important issue is the interpretation of various measures of bargaining outcomes. For example, social scientists often regard women's lower fertility as evidence of their higher bargaining power, drawing from the assumption that women tend to prefer fewer children, and when they have greater autonomy are better able to exert preferences over ideal family size (Bankole & Singh, Reference Bankole and Singh1998; Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Borgerhoff Mulder and Rauch2009; Snopkowski & Sear, Reference Snopkowski and Sear2013). Adaptive logic used to explain this difference is that women face greater reproductive costs than men do, and therefore men can afford to have higher fertility preferences (Penn & Smith, Reference Penn and Smith2007; Borgerhoff Mulder & Rauch, Reference Borgerhoff Mulder and Rauch2009). However, Moya et al. (Reference Moya, Snopkowski and Sear2016) point out that this assumption may be faulty, as men and women do not necessarily have conflicts over ideal family size, and men also suffer costs to reproduction. One of the key costs that Moya et al. highlight relates to sex ratios and bargaining power. The assumption that men can easily replace a wife who dies in childbirth does not take into consideration that men compete for access to wives, and this competition will be particularly strong when the ASR is male-biased. Men may be better off adjusting their fertility preferences to match that of their wives (e.g. with longer interbirth intervals or lower overall fertility) in order to reduce her reproductive costs.

In another example, men's higher paternal investment has also been attributed to women's increased bargaining power (Francis, Reference Francis2011). While this is one possibility, the opportunity costs of paternal care decrease when partners are scarce, so this behaviour is therefore not conclusive evidence of women's higher bargaining power. A similar point complicates the finding of higher endorsements of traditional gender roles in Australian regions that experienced high sex ratios in the past (Grosjean & Khattar, Reference Grosjean and Khattar2019). Grosjean and Khattar understand men's higher contributions to the household income and support for traditional gender roles as a result of women's high bargaining power. We suggest another, and perhaps more likely, explanation: that men's willingness to be the sole breadwinner reflects a mate guarding strategy. Men may have preferred for their wives to stay at home when they were faced with strong competition from other men in an unfavourable marriage market.

These examples illustrate how the interpretation of bargaining outcomes as favouring men or women is not always clear-cut. This is important, because theory and findings from the animal literature suggest that partner scarcity can lead to either coercive or conciliatory behaviour. Currently the most conclusive evidence for people's use of coercion in response to unfavourable sex ratios comes from studies on intimate-partner violence (IPV) against women. Intimate-partner violence has been theorized as a male strategy to seek control over a female romantic partner in situations where she has a higher market value than he has (Macmillan & Gartner, Reference Macmillan and Gartner1999; Kilgallen et al., Reference Kilgallen, Schaffnit, Kumogola, Galura, Urassa and Lawson2021). Research in India (Bose et al., Reference Bose, Trent and South2013) and several US subpopulations (Avakame, Reference Avakame1999; D'Alessio & Stolzenberg, Reference D'Alessio and Stolzenberg2010; Vanterpool et al., Reference Vanterpool, Yarber, Rosenberg, Mowatt and Garcia2021) indicates that IPV is more prevalent in regions with male-biased sex ratios. Here the work of Bose et al. (Reference Bose, Trent and South2013) is most convincing. They use survey data from married women in the 2005–2006 Indian National Family Health Survey to test the effect of ASR (measured at the level of the village or neighbourhood block) on their reports of husband-to-wife violence. India's male-biased ASR is the result of a strong son bias that has led to biased sex ratios at birth and gender differences in child mortality in many parts of the country. Bose et al. (Reference Bose, Trent and South2013) find a small positive association between ASR and physical, sexual and psychological IPV. Other studies have found similar results using data from the US. For example, D'Alessio and Stolzenberg (Reference D'Alessio and Stolzenberg2010) use city-level data on male-to-female intimate-partner violent crime rates in the US (which include murder, abduction, rape, sexual assault, etc.) as their dependent variable. They find that more IPV crimes occur in cities with male-biased sex ratios, although the very high coefficients in their model results are difficult to interpret and suggest their models may be overfitted or lack appropriate controls for variables correlated with ASR (D'Alessio & Stolzenberg, Reference D'Alessio and Stolzenberg2010: table 2). Furthermore, it is unclear whether their results could be explained by a higher prevalence of marriage and lower divorce rates generally, factors that have been associated with high sex ratios (e.g. Angrist, Reference Angrist2002; Abramitzky et al., Reference Abramitzky, Delavande and Vasconcelos2011; Brainerd, Reference Brainerd2017), rather than an increase in the rate of IPV in romantic relationships. In a similar study, Vanterpool et al. (Reference Vanterpool, Yarber, Rosenberg, Mowatt and Garcia2021) recruited Black women from the US on MTurk, as Black communities in the US experience wide variation in ASR resulting from high incarceration rates in some areas. They too find an association between perceptions of high sex ratios and experiences of IPV, but their study is limited by the use of perceptions of both variables rather than demographic data.

As these studies show, it is difficult to ascertain what causes the observed relationship between the ASR and IPV, especially in settings where biases in ASR result from patriarchal norms. In India for example, regional differences in ASR exist owing to the occurrence of cross-cousin marriage, matrilocality and matrilineal inheritance in some parts of the country. These cultural traits are associated with a lack of son preference as well as with higher status and better treatment of women (Dyson & Moore, Reference Dyson and Moore1983; Chakraborty & Kim, Reference Chakraborty and Kim2010), leaving the possibility that differences in attitudes towards women's status explain variation in both ASR and the prevalence of IPV, without a causal link between the two.

While locally contextualized studies have shown the potential for ASR to interact with reproductive strategies, we find that they rarely address the complex gender dynamics that form a pathway between ASR and resulting reproductive strategies. Examining the relationship between ASR, gender norms and reproductive strategies may help us to understand why simple mating market predictions sometimes fail to explain variation in reproductive strategies and bargaining power, as is also suggested by Schacht and Smith (Reference Schacht and Smith2017). In the remaining part of this review, we revise existing theory to incorporate the role of gender norms and cultural evolution in human sexual conflict. We focus on five important points that address how gender norms interact with sex ratios to affect mating market dynamics, reproductive strategies and gendered bargaining positions: (1) gender norms do not always reflect bargaining outcomes but are subject to their own selective processes; (2) gender norms create bounds on who can reproduce with whom and what is valued on the marriage market; (3) gender norms have the potential to constrain people's reproductive decision-making power in a way that is unequal between genders; (4) biases in local ASRs themselves are often the result of gender norms; and (5) gender norms affect how individuals respond to biased sex ratios. Collectively these points show that sex ratio dynamics – and sexual conflict more broadly – in humans are deeply interlinked with gender norms (see Figure 1), and that the interpretation of sex ratio biases as favouring men or women is not always clear-cut. This fits with theory and findings from the animal literature, which suggest that partner scarcity can lead to either coercive or conciliatory behaviour. Here we have shown some examples that are clearly coercive (e.g. IPV) and examples that are more conciliatory in nature (e.g. paternal investment), but most of the studies we have highlighted have data that can be interpreted multiple ways, and reflect the need for deeper contextualization of history, culture and demographics.

Figure 1. Schematic representation of the relationship between ASR and gender ideology.

We conclude this paper by arguing that human sexual conflict may be better termed ‘gendered conflict’ (Lawson et al., Reference Lawson, Alami and Somefun2023), because it can only be understood by explicitly modelling the role of gender norms and by integrating models of cultural evolution.

3.1. Gender norms are a product of sexual conflict as well as other evolutionary processes

Evolutionary anthropologists have argued that gender norms are the result of a long evolutionary history of sexual conflict (Smuts, Reference Smuts1995; Hrdy, Reference Hrdy1997). According to this view, the reproductive biologies of females and males result in males’ higher interest in control over females’ reproduction than vice versa. Smuts (Reference Smuts1995) argues that patriarchal norms that justify men's dominance over women have evolved as a continuation and extension of male efforts to control female reproduction, common in the animal kingdom and specifically in mammals and primates. Importantly, ‘human males are not “genetically programmed” to coerce and control women, and […] women are not “genetically programmed” to accept subordinate status’ (Smuts, Reference Smuts1995: 21). The evolution of patriarchy refers to the cultural evolution of social norms prescribing male dominance, and Smuts argues that human residence patterns, male control over resources and the uniquely human ability to convey information through language have enabled greater control of men over women than is possible in other animals (Smuts, Reference Smuts1995). Gender norms are socially enforced by group members (and often by the state) through punishment or social exclusion (Egan & Perry, Reference Egan and Perry2001; Blakemore, Reference Blakemore2003; Parrott, Reference Parrott2009; Skočajić et al., Reference Skočajić, Radosavljević, Okičić, Janković and Žeželj2020). Like other social norms, gender norms may adjust to changing community members’ interests in norm-governed behaviours, as well as to their bargaining positions (Singh et al., Reference Singh, Wrangham and Glowacki2017). Sex ratio dynamics can therefore influence gender norms by changing individuals’ interests. For example, extreme sex ratios can motivate a tolerance of polygamy (Starkweather & Hames, Reference Starkweather and Hames2012), and in other cases have led to the relaxation of exogamy rules (Mishra, Reference Mishra2013; Larsen & Kaur, Reference Larsen and Kaur2013). However, there are various reasons why norms do not always reflect a bargaining outcome of the optimal strategies of individuals in a social group.

First, social norms are often subject to a period of mismatch when adaptations have not yet caught up with current selection pressures. Such ‘adaptive lags’ may be caused by a number of processes. One example is group members’ efforts to coordinate behaviour by adhering to social norms. Social norms structure human behaviour in such a way that makes it predictable and facilitates smooth coordination between group members. People who deviate from the norm could experience costs simply from miscoordination (Young, Reference Young1993; Centola & Baronchelli, Reference Centola and Baronchelli2015; O'Connor, Reference O'Connor2019). In China, women who pursue higher education risk not finding a partner, as they often seek men who are willing to leave behind traditional roles of the husband as breadwinner and the wife as homemaker, while many men prefer women who are less educated than themselves and will take on the role of homemaker (Ji, Reference Ji2015; Hong Fincher, Reference Hong Fincher2016). Such mismatches in partner preferences may occur when one tries to depart from common gender norms. In addition, once a norm becomes an important part of the moral code of a group, deviance from the norm can lead to important social costs, such as exclusion or punishment by other group members. Deviance from culturally dominant gender norms also can result in negative health outcomes via negligence or violence (Macmillan & Gartner, Reference Macmillan and Gartner1999; Weber et al., Reference Weber, Cislaghi, Meausoone, Abdalla, Mejía-Guevara, Loftus and Rao Gupta2019; Kilgallen et al., Reference Kilgallen, Schaffnit, Kumogola, Galura, Urassa and Lawson2021). The coordination benefits of norm adherence as well as the social costs of deviance therefore can lead to cultural inertia that results in a disconnect between a group's norms and group members’ optimal behaviour. Because of this, cultural phylogeny constrains changes in social norms, as is probably the case for marriage norms: in a phylogenetic analysis of cultural groups included in the Standard Cross-Cultural Sample, the cultural history of populations explained twice the variance in local rules on polygyny and in the occurrence of polygyny as relevant ecological predictors (Minocher et al., Reference Minocher, Duda and Jaeggi2019). Here adaptive lag is one possible explanation for the lack of divergence between related groups.

Second, norms themselves are subject to evolutionary processes that are separate from the payoffs they provide to group members. Cultural evolution theory hypothesizes that cultural traits, among which social norms, are subject to processes similar but not identical to Darwinian evolution, as traits vary and some are more likely to spread than others. At the micro-level, this theoretical framework considers how cultural traits are passed between individuals, such as through biased social learning (Boyd & Richerson, Reference Boyd and Richerson1985; Boyd et al., Reference Boyd, Richerson and Henrich2011; Mesoudi, Reference Mesoudi2011a; Richerson & Boyd, Reference Richerson and Boyd2005). For example, the rate at which norms spread depends on the cultural ‘models’ displaying those norms. Various studies have shown that people are more likely to adopt cultural traits held by high-status individuals (Henrich & Gil-White, Reference Henrich and Gil-White2001; Atkisson et al., Reference Atkisson, O'Brien and Mesoudi2012; Chudek et al., Reference Chudek, Heller, Birch and Henrich2012). Common norms may also spread more easily by virtue of their popularity when people conform to the majority (Henrich & Boyd, Reference Henrich and Boyd1998; Efferson et al., Reference Efferson, Lalive, Richerson, McElreath and Lubell2008; Muthukrishna et al., Reference Muthukrishna, Morgan and Henrich2016; Hagen & Scelza, Reference Hagen and Scelza2020). As an example, practices of female genital cutting (FGC) are thought to have culturally evolved from conflicting interests between women and men by limiting women's desire for extra-pair sex while increasing their husbands’ paternity certainty. However, recent research on this topic shows that while FGC is clearly harmful to women, its effect on women's sexual behaviour and thereby men's paternity certainty may be limited (Howard & Gibson, Reference Howard and Gibson2019). Rather than being an outcome of continued sexual conflict, frequency-dependent copying may drive the persistence of FGC (Howard & Gibson, Reference Howard and Gibson2017). Specific to marriage norms, Henrich et al. (Reference Henrich, Boyd and Richerson2012) have suggested that group-level benefits to monogamous marriage drove the spread of monogamy to many populations around the world. In their argument, social enforcement of monogamous marriage is argued to reduce intrasexual competition, result in more men being married and higher paternal investment. Henrich et al. (Reference Henrich, Boyd and Richerson2012) argue that norms prescribing monogamy may have increased the economic prosperity of monogamous people, and that this prosperity helped spur its spread to other populations. If correct, this implies that marriage rules, like other gender norms, can spread as a result of biased cultural transmission.

In summary, gender norms are thought to result, in part, from an evolutionary history of sexual conflict. While the norms in a population are probably subject to change depending on the interests and bargaining positions of its members, they are also subject to other processes and are therefore unlikely to perfectly reflect sexual conflict-derived bargaining outcomes.

3.2. Gender norms constrain someone's value on the market

Gender norms both constrain who is on the market and regulate what their value is. Concerning the first, marriage systems are a well-known constraint on reproductive strategies, and interact with ASR in important ways. Whether socially or legally enforced, norms about who is ‘on the market’ and about how they are valued are often not gender-neutral. For example, gender differences may exist in the social acceptance of remarriage after divorce or after the death of a spouse (Whyte, Reference Whyte1978), and the legal minimum age for marriage is lower for women than for men in 43 out of 201 countries (UN Statistics Division, 2013). Furthermore, the acceptance or rejection of polygamy plays a large role in determining the ‘market value’ of women and men. In populations where polygyny is culturally normative, some men have the ability to monopolize the reproduction of multiple women. In populations where the ASR is female-biased, polygyny can increase the demand for women, which – all else equal – could improve their bargaining position (Becker, Reference Becker1981). The costs to men in this situation may also be minimized, as a female-biased sex ratio can lead to most men being able to have at least one wife (see Figure 2). This is very different from cultures where polygyny is allowed and the sex ratio is equal or male-biased. In these cases, reproductive skew would be exacerbated by the concurrent demographic and cultural restrictions on access to women. In 77% of cultures in the Standard Cross-cultural Sample, men are allowed to have multiple spouses, whereas only 6.5% allow women to have multiple spouses (Whyte, Reference Whyte1978). Today polygyny is legal in 50 countries, and in these countries between 2 and 36% of people live in polygynous households (Pew Research Center, 2019). At least one study examines the level of polygyny in relation to local sex ratios: Pollet and Nettle (Reference Pollet and Nettle2009) find that in Uganda, the percentage of men in polygynous unions tracks the regional adult sex ratio, with more men in polygynous unions when the sex ratio is female-biased. Polyandry can also be affected by sex ratios. Starkweather and Hames (Reference Starkweather and Hames2012) review the literature on non-classical polyandry and find that it is sometimes practised when populations are faced with a particularly male-biased sex ratio. However, strong cultural norms prohibiting polygamy prevent this from happening in many cultural groups. For example, the scarcity of French men after World War II led to higher bargaining power for men, but not to a tolerance for polygynous marriage (Abramitzky et al., Reference Abramitzky, Delavande and Vasconcelos2011). Therefore, while it is possible for polygamy to dampen sex-ratio effects on marriage market dynamics, strong cultural norms and marriage rules can limit this potential.

Figure 2. This diagram illustrates the effect of polygyny on partnership opportunities in social groups depending on the local ASR. Green circles indicate women, orange triangles refer to men, and lines around individuals indicate marriages or pair bonds. Rows represent different ASR, and columns vary in their marriage rules. The ASR and local marriage rules interact to determine marriage opportunities. For example, in the upper row the population ASR is female biased. When monogamy is the norm, some women remain without a partner. When men can have multiple partners, this dampens the effect of a female-biased sex ratio (and could even result in some men remaining partnerless). If polyandry occurs, this exacerbates the scarcity of partners for women.

When the sex ratio is skewed but all else is equal, does polygamy result in higher bargaining power for the abundant sex by increasing their demand, as follows from a marriage market approach (and is suggested by, among others, Becker, Reference Becker1981)? Importantly, all else is usually not equal. As we argue in this paper, marriage rules, gender norms and sex ratios are all interlinked. Polygyny is often accompanied by a strong gender hierarchy, male-controlled access to resources and reduced decision-making power for women. This issue is further discussed by Grossbard (Reference Grossbard2015).

Norms regarding beauty standards and gender roles have a strong influence on partner preferences and thereby affect how people are value on the marriage market. Norms regarding gender roles and divisions of labour can also affect bargaining power in a special way: they can create a stronger interdependence among romantic partners who have a family to care for. This is true for gendered divisions of labour common in subsistence-based communities, such as in hunter–gatherer populations where men and women have complementary foraging tasks, as well as the breadwinner–homemaker division of labour that is common in urbanized populations around the world, where men more often work outside the home while women perform more of the childcare labour and other household duties. The types of labour and the roles prescribed to women and men have far-reaching consequences for women's and men's relative dependence on another. Earning an income by working outside the home is a source of power for a variety of reasons, an important reason being decreased dependency on a spouse by improving someone's options outside of a relationship, as is discussed extensively in a large literature in anthropology, sociology, feminist economics and development studies (for example see Schlegel & Barry, Reference Schlegel and Barry1986; Lundberg & Pollak, Reference Lundberg and Pollak1996; Agarwal, Reference Agarwal1997; Kantor, Reference Kantor2003; Vyas & Watts, Reference Vyas and Watts2009). On the other hand, men are also reported to respond to women's employment with violent backlash when women's work conflicts with their perceived notions of traditional gender roles (Atkinson et al., Reference Atkinson, Greenstein and Lang2005; Weitzman, Reference Weitzman2014; Cools & Kotsadam, Reference Cools and Kotsadam2017; Kilgallen et al., Reference Kilgallen, Schaffnit, Kumogola, Galura, Urassa and Lawson2021).

Marriage rules, beauty standards and gender roles are thus three examples of ways in which gender norms have a strong effect on people's value on the marriage market.

3.3. Gender norms affect freedom of choice in a way that can override marriage market opportunities

In many populations, women and men do not have the same degree of freedom in reproductive decision-making. Sometimes individuals of only one gender can approach the other with a marriage proposal, allowing the other party only a choice between refusal or acceptance. Parents often influence the choice of spouse for children of both women and men, but cross-culturally men have a say in their own marriage choices more often than women (Whyte, Reference Whyte1978). Parents’ and children's interests often do not completely overlap, especially when high marriage payments are involved or marriage is in another way consequential to a woman's family (Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Borgerhoff Mulder1998; Apostolou, Reference Apostolou and Pearlman2009). Bridewealth is subject to market demands for women and can rise under male-biased sex ratios (Francis, Reference Francis2011), increasing parental interests in controlling a daughter's marital decisions and causing further divergence of parents’ and daughters’ interests. This can have the effect of limiting women's autonomy where their value on the marriage market is high. Here the function of the bridewealth is important. For example, in China bride wealth is skyrocketing owing to male-biased sex ratios (Wei & Zhang, Reference Wei and Zhang2011), but much of the bride wealth devolves to the couple (for example in the form of real estate, cars or other valued goods), making it more similar to dowry (Yan, Reference Yan2003; Wei & Zhang, Reference Wei and Zhang2011). Dowries can also be sensitive to the demand for men (e.g. Rao, Reference Rao1993), but high dowry does not lead to the same level of parental control because dowries often function as pre-mortem inheritance that will be owned by the married couple rather than as a ‘payment’ to the groom's family (Goody, Reference Goody1976; Gaulin and Boster, Reference Gaulin and Boster1990).

Second, normative restrictions on pre- or extra-marital sex constrain people's ability to benefit from a favourable marriage market. Premarital sex allows people entering the marriage market to learn about potential partners available to them while extramarital sex can make it easier to switch partners (Buss et al., Reference Buss, Goetz, Duntley, Asao and Conroy-Beam2017; Scelza & Prall, Reference Scelza and Prall2023). A double standard where men have more freedom to engage in both premarital and extramarital sex is common throughout the world, limiting women's access to information about available partners (Broude, Reference Broude1980). Once again, however, gender norms can interact with ASR to affect these practices. Himba have a strongly female-biased ASR, but this co-occurs with a long history of matriliny and a pastoralist production system that requires long periods of spousal separation (Scelza et al., Reference Scelza, Prall and Starkweather2021). In this setting, while the female-biased ASR may be leading to a marriage market that is more favourable for men, the social history and ecological circumstances have contributed to gender norms that allow women significant sexual autonomy, so that both premarital and extramarital sex are common for women.

Lastly, gender-based differences in the right and ability to initiate divorce (and remarry) potentially have a strong effect on women and men's bargaining power in marriage (Scelza, Reference Scelza2013). Bargaining power derived from a favourable mating market can be nullified if the costs of divorce are high, for example because of legal restrictions or social stigma on divorce (Bargain et al., Reference Bargain, Loper and Ziparo2020), and normative restrictions on women's ability to initiate divorce are more common than on men's (Broude & Greene, Reference Broude and Greene1983). In most countries women and men legally have equal access to divorce, but restricted unilateral or fault-based divorce laws in some pose limits on divorce that may disproportionately affect women's ability to leave their husbands. Furthermore, women's prospects after divorce may be further limited by their financial dependence on husbands (Leopold, Reference Leopold2018). Gender-based restrictions on divorce could lead to counterintuitive situations in which a biased sex ratio results in a good bargaining position of one gender when looking for a marriage partner, but very little bargaining power in the marriage itself. These double standards on women's and men's freedom of choice in marriage are expected to lead to an asymmetric relationship between their market value as derived from the ASR and women's and men's bargaining power, where women are often more constrained in their ability to gain leverage from a favourable sex ratio owing to stronger limits on their freedom of choosing partners, initiating divorce and having pre- and extramarital sex.

3.4. Gender norms directly affect sex ratios

To test mating market predictions, many studies understandably focus on populations in which the factors resulting in biased sex ratios are exogenous to bargaining dynamics. Many researchers purposefully select populations in which sex-biased migration (Angrist, Reference Angrist2002; Schacht & Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Schacht and Borgerhoff Mulder2015; Uggla & Mace, Reference Uggla and Mace2017; Grosjean & Khattar, Reference Grosjean and Khattar2019), excess male mortality (Jones & Ferguson, Reference Jones and Ferguson2006; Abramitzky et al., Reference Abramitzky, Delavande and Vasconcelos2011; Brainerd, Reference Brainerd2017) or high male incarceration rates (Fossett & Kiecolt, Reference Fossett and Kiecolt1993; Cready et al., Reference Cready, Fossett and Kiecolt1997; Vanterpool et al., Reference Vanterpool, Yarber, Rosenberg, Mowatt and Garcia2021) are the main cause of bias in the ASR, rather than the respective status of women and men. However, gender norms themselves in many cases directly influence local adult sex ratios. This can happen through various pathways. Norms enforcing a gendered division of labour can affect the adult sex ratio when some tasks are associated with increased mortality. Hunting and warfare are examples of work typically assigned to men that carries a high mortality risk and that can contribute to biased adult sex ratios (Abramitzky et al., Reference Abramitzky, Delavande and Vasconcelos2011; Brainerd, Reference Brainerd2017). Labour migration until recently was more often male-biased, but women constitute a growing part of the world's main migration flows, either following their partners or seeking better employment or education by themselves (summarized by Clarke, Reference Clarke, Demeny and McNicoll2003).

There are various pathways through which gender norms, and the differential valuation of boys and girls, can affect sex ratios. A preference for either girls or boys can be a strong motivator for parity progression and thereby have important demographic consequences. For example, among Mosuo people in southwest China, where descent practices vary between communities, matrilineal descent practices are associated with an increased likelihood of continued fertility after a son, and patriliny is linked with continued fertility after a daughter (Mattison et al., Reference Mattison, Beheim, Chak and Buston2016). In India the last-born child is more likely to be a boy than a girl, and Chaudhuri (Reference Chaudhuri2012) estimates that 7% of the births are the result of son preference. In addition, a preference for one gender can lead to inferior treatment of the other, resulting in biased mortality rates. Under-five mortality is biased against girls in the Caucasus and Central Asia, and biased against boys in Uganda, Guinea–Bissau, Uzbekistan and Mongolia (Alkema et al., Reference Alkema, Chao, You, Pedersen and Sawyer2014). At the extreme, sex preferences can result in sex-biased infanticide, with evidence suggesting this practice was once widespread in South and East Asia, Europe and small-scale societies across the globe (Sen, Reference Sen1990; Divale & Harris, Reference Divale and Harris1976; Smith & Smith, Reference Smith and Smith1994; Mungello, Reference Mungello2008; King, Reference King2014; Dong & Kurosu, Reference Dong and Kurosu2016). On top of these sources of bias in child sex ratios, access to sex-selective abortion in combination with child-limiting and family-planning policies have led to skyrocketing sex ratios at birth in India and China (Banister, Reference Banister2004; Zhu et al., Reference Zhu, Lu and Hesketh2009; World Bank, Reference Bank2022).

Although the effects can be somewhat mitigated through sex-biased migration, biased sex ratios at birth generally result in biased ASR in the next generation. Countries where the sex ratio at birth is statistically higher than would be expected in the absence of son-preference account for 38% of today's world population and for 91% of all people living in countries with an ASR over 1.05 (calculation based on population estimates from World Bank, Reference Bank2022; Chao et al., Reference Chao, Gerland, Cook and Alkema2019). These numbers underline the significance of gender norms and their role in the origin of biased sex ratios. This relationship cannot be ignored, especially because of our final point: gender ideology can affect how people may respond to their market value and how market value is translated into gendered bargaining positions.

3.5. Gender norms affect how people respond to gains or decreases in their market value

Theory and findings from the non-human animal literature suggest that men have two options in their treatment of women when faced with high competition on the marriage market. They can increase their chances by moving towards the preferences of a (potential) partner, which would indicate a true improvement of women's bargaining position and result in women's higher status. Alternatively, when men's market value is low because of a biased ASR, they can force their bargaining position through coercive tactics such as mate guarding or (threats of) social or physical coercion. Which of these strategies becomes prominent in a particular place is likely to reflect existing gender ideologies. For example, in a population that already strongly enforces men's dominance over women, the latter may be more prominent, while in more gender egalitarian settings conciliatory tactics might be more common. Guttentag and Secord (Reference Guttentag and Secord1983) were among the first to predict a role for gender ideologies in shaping people's responses to biased sex ratios. They argue that under a biased sex ratio, members of the rare sex gain ‘dyadic’ power in romantic relationships. However, they also state that the effect of high sex ratios on women's status will not have the same effect as low sex ratios on men's status, as men disproportionately hold ‘structural power’ in human societies. The combination of these two factors means that the ways that sex ratio imbalances play out are not mirror images of one another. According to Guttentag and Secord, a male-biased sex ratio will lead to an increased valuation of women's reproductive value, but not women's empowerment. Under a male-biased sex ratio, men ‘must treat [their partner] well or run the risk of losing her to another man. But their structural power is sufficient to allow them to place constraints on women's freedoms and impose a sexual morality on them’ (Guttentag & Secord, Reference Guttentag and Secord1983: 28). This can be seen in many cross-cultural instances of restrictions on female autonomy and sexuality. But more conciliatory responses to a male-biased sex ratio might be more common in places where gender norms are more egalitarian. For example, in a historical US study, Pollet and Nettle (Reference Pollet and Nettle2008) found that in states with a more male-biased ASR, women were able to leverage greater demands, with higher SES men being more likely to be married. Here, men were winning the mating competition by investing.

When it comes to female-biased sex ratios, Guttentag and Secord predict a devaluation of women in society and the relegation of women as mere sex objects. Several studies suggest that men may a higher preference for short-term relationships and uncommitted sex in places where there is a more female-biased ASR, including among US college students (Adkins et al., Reference Adkins, England, Risman and Ford2015), in US cities (Kruger & Schlemmer, Reference Kruger and Schlemmer2009) and in rural southwestern Guyana (Schacht & Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Schacht and Borgerhoff Mulder2015). However, gender norms can temper this effect. For example, Himba pastoralists have a strongly female-biased ASR, but also a history of matriliny and strong norms for female sexual autonomy and freedom of movement. Their labour in both production and reproduction is also highly valued. This means that although women have lower market value because they are more plentiful, gender norms that allow for easy divorce and concurrent partnerships mean that women are still able to exert partner choice and leverage the market value they do have in ways that benefit them (Scelza et al., Reference Scelza, Prall, Swinford, Gopalan, Atkinson, McElreath, Sheehama and Henn2019, 2021). The ways in which women respond to unfavourable market conditions may also relate to other factors like post-marital residence patterns and the availability of allocare. For example, where women can rely on others to help care for their children, the costs of reduced male support will not be as great as they are in patrilineal, patrilocal societies where women are more separated from their kin and have less access to alternative forms of support if their partner leaves them.

Where Guttentag and Secord do not question the origins of men's ‘structural power’, evolutionary anthropologists understand patriarchy to be the result of a long history of sexual conflict (Smuts, Reference Smuts1995; Hrdy, Reference Hrdy1997). Our perspective is similar in that it predicts that the common gender ideology in a population influences how people respond to their market value as derived from the sex ratio. As reviewed above, responsivity to biased sex ratios has been documented in human populations for both conciliatory and coercive behaviours. We further show that gender norms can affect mating market dynamics. However, more work in this area is needed. In particular, more empirical studies looking at how market dynamics may be responsive to gender ideology would help to test and refine our predictions.

4. Discussion

Currently much of the research in the human literature is limited by its reliance on samples from only a few areas with a limited ecological range, making it difficult to separate sex-ratio effects on gender norms from other differences between subpopulations. For example, environmental factors can correlate with sex ratios in a non-causal way and lead to false estimates of sex-ratio effects. Importantly, not all variables interpreted as bargaining outcomes are conclusively indicative of women's or men's preferred bargaining outcome, further complicating this research. In order to effectively study this relationship between sex ratios and bargaining over reproductive strategies, anthropologists must reckon with the endogenous role of gender norms in sexual conflict dynamics. Gender ideology can be an important cause of biases in sex ratios, and probably affect how individuals respond to biased sex ratios. Gender norms thereby have the potential to influence how sex ratios translate to gendered bargaining dynamics, and future work should explicitly take this into account in their predictions as well as in the interpretation of their findings.

In this paper we have argued that the interaction between gender norms and sexual conflict adds a layer of complexity that cannot be ignored when studying sexual conflict in humans. To explicitly foreground this important role of gender norms, we agree with Lawson et al.'s (2023) proposal of the term ‘gendered conflict’ when applying sexual conflict theory to human behaviour. We have provided evidence and suggest hypotheses for some of the myriad ways in which gender norms and sexual conflict interact specifically in the context of sex ratios. As Lawson et al. (Reference Lawson, Alami and Somefun2023) discuss, referring to gendered conflict does not negate the central role of sex and reproduction in conflict over evolutionary time, but is useful in that it helps underline the role of social and cultural influences. The term gendered conflict works to disessentialize differences between women and men by underlining the fact that women and men's conflicting interests cannot be reduced to sex-based biological differences, but are very much shaped by gender norms. We further argue that models of cultural evolution are crucial in understanding gendered conflict, while gender norms as well as bargaining and power dynamics are somewhat neglected in cultural evolution theory itself (Singh et al., Reference Singh, Wrangham and Glowacki2017; Lawson et al., Reference Lawson, Alami and Somefun2023). Sexual conflict theory has been used quite extensively to model and measure bargaining over gender roles and over women's autonomy and decision-making power (e.g. Smuts, Reference Smuts1995; Käär et al., Reference Käär, Jokela, Merilä, Helle and Kojola1998; Borgerhoff Mulder & Rauch, Reference Borgerhoff Mulder2009; O'Connor, Reference O'Connor2019; Kilgallen et al., Reference Kilgallen, Schaffnit, Kumogola, Galura, Urassa and Lawson2021). This work centres on the question of how fitness payoffs can affect the spread and maintenance of gender norms and is mostly separate from the literature on cultural evolution theory, which has long studied the evolution of social norms but rarely looks explicitly at gender. Some notable exceptions include a theoretical study of the evolution of sex-biased transmission (Zefferman, Reference Zefferman2016) and a study showing FGC as a frequency-dependent behaviour that is associated with increased fitness (Howard & Gibson, Reference Howard and Gibson2017). Future studies could go further to use models of cultural evolution will be required to understand how gender norms spread, persist and change over time. These models will need to consider how power dynamics and gendered fitness interests affect these dynamics. At minimum, future studies on sex-ratio effects need to consider the processes leading to biased sex ratios and their relationship to gender ideologies. Where previous research has somewhat neglected the causal role of gender norms or simply avoided populations in which gender norms are an obvious source of variation in ASR, there is opportunity for future research to study these topics in populations where there is a direct link between gender ideology and ASR. Disentangling the complex links between sex ratios, gender norms and gendered bargaining power will be no easy feat. Finding suitable cases to test the proposed hypotheses is challenging, precisely because of this complex relationship, but exogenous factors that affect ASR and marriage rules may offer a way out. For example, to our knowledge there is currently no research that empirically tests whether levels of polygamy dampen the effect of sex ratios on the relative bargaining power of women and men by changing the demand for partners. Future work may address this question by studying gendered bargaining dynamics in a population where the level of polygamy regionally varies owing to ecological factors unrelated to gender ideology. Legislative changes of legal differences between regions can further provide natural experiments for studying how marriage rules or freedom of choice in marriage and divorce can constrain people's ability to gain leverage from a biased sex ratio. More broadly, understanding the causal role that gender norms might play would benefit from more longitudinal work, particularly from areas undergoing rapid cultural and economic change. Alternatively, experimental norm-change studies that specifically posit causal direction in the study design can be another way to see how gender norms might alter beliefs about processes that affect the ASR (e.g. sex-biased investment).

5. Conclusion

A growing body of research addresses the effect of sex ratios on reproductive behaviour in humans. This research follows predictions from sexual conflict theory and findings from the non-human animal literature, where sex ratios have been shown to affect mating strategies and bargaining in many species in line with predictions. When a population's sex ratio is biased, this changes both the interests of each sex in parenting and mating strategies, as well as individuals’ bargaining power in sexual conflicts of interest. Furthermore, the costs and benefits of different mating strategies in turn can influence sex ratios, resulting in a dynamic relationship between sex ratios and mating and parenting behaviour. The fitness payoffs of these behaviours are also dependent on environmental factors, such as mortality risks associated with parenting or mate search, which can constrain the effect of sex ratios. In humans, sexual conflict dynamics are even more complex owing to the role of cultural norms regarding gender, and here we believe the term ‘gendered conflict’ is useful in directing researchers’ focus to this additional layer of complexity (Lawson et al., Reference Lawson, Alami and Somefun2023).

In this paper we argue that sexual conflict theory must be revised in order to understand these processes in human populations, where culture adds a layer of complexity that cannot be ignored. Gender norms themselves are in part a product of conflicts of interest between women and men. However as cultural traits they are also subject to cultural evolutionary processes, resulting in their detachment from expected sexual conflict outcomes and their potential to in turn influence conflict dynamics. Gender norms play a central role in marriage market and bargaining dynamics by altering who is on the market, how individuals are valued and how much freedom of choice they have, and by directly affecting sex ratios. Crucially, gender norms may also structure how individuals respond to market value gained or lost through biased sex ratios. Integrating sexual conflict theory and cultural evolution theory is crucial to understanding gendered conflict dynamics.

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank the Center for Behaviour, Evolution and Culture, and specifically Clark Barrett, David Lawson, Nancy Levine and Brian Wood for fruitful discussions and thoughtful comments on the manuscript. We would like to thank the four anonymous reviewers for their helpful suggestions.

Author contributions

RVH led and BAS supported the conceptualization of this paper. RVH wrote the original draft, and RVH and BAS equally contributed to editing and revising.

Financial support

This work was supported by the Hiroshi Wagatsuma Memorial Fellowship.

Competing interests

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

Research transparency and reproducibility

n/a

Data availability statement

n/a

References

Abramitzky, R., Delavande, A., & Vasconcelos, L. (2011). Marrying up: The role of sex ratio in assortative matching. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 3(3), 124157.Google Scholar
Adkins, T., England, P., Risman, B. J., & Ford, J. (2015). Student bodies: Does the sex ratio matter for hooking up and having sex at college? Social Currents, 2(2), 144162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Agarwal, B. (1997). ‘Bargaining’ and gender relations: Within and beyond the household. Feminist Economics, 3(1), 151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akurugu, C. A., Dery, I., & Domanban, P. B. (2022). Marriage, bridewealth and power: Critical reflections on women's autonomy across settings in Africa. Evolutionary Human Sciences, 4, e30.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Alkema, L., Chao, F., You, D., Pedersen, J., & Sawyer, C. C. (2014). National, regional, and global sex ratios of infant, child, and under-5 mortality and identification of countries with outlying ratios: A systematic assessment. The Lancet Global Health, 2(9), e521e530. Elsevier.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Angrist, J. (2002). How do sex ratios affect marriage and labour markets? Evidence from America's second generation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 9971038.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Apostolou, M. (2009). Parent–offspring conflict over mating: Current advancements, future directions. In Pearlman, K. S. (Ed.), Marriage: Roles, stability and conflict (pp. 7794). Nova Science.Google Scholar
Arnqvist, G., & Rowe, L. (2005). Sexual conflict. Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, M. P., Greenstein, T. N., & Lang, M. M. (2005). For women, breadwinning can be dangerous: Gendered resource theory and wife abuse. Journal of Marriage and Family, 67(5), 11371148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkisson, C., O'Brien, M. J., & Mesoudi, A. (2012). Adult learners in a novel environment use prestige-biased social learning. Evolutionary Psychology: An International Journal of Evolutionary Approaches to Psychology and Behaviour, 10(3), 519537.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Avakame, E. F. (1999). Sex ratios, female labour force participation, and lethal violence against women: Extending Guttentag and Secord's thesis. Violence Against Women, 5(11), 13211341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baniel, A., Cowlishaw, G., & Huchard, E. (2017). Male violence and sexual intimidation in a wild primate society. Current Biology, 27(14), 21632168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banister, J. (2004). Shortage of girls in China today. Journal of Population Research, 21(1), 1945.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bankole, A., & Singh, S. (1998). Couples’ fertility and contraceptive decision-making in developing countries: Hearing the man's voice. International Family Planning Perspectives, 24(1), 1524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baraka, J., Lawson, D. W., Schaffnit, S. B., Wamoyi, J., & Urassa, M. (2022). Why marry early? Parental influence, agency and gendered conflict in Tanzanian marriages. Evolutionary Human Sciences, 4, e49.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Barber, N. (2000). On the relationship between country sex ratios and teen pregnancy rates: A replication. Cross-Cultural Research, 34(1), 2637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bargain, O., Loper, J., & Ziparo, R. (2020). Traditional norms, access to divorce and women's empowerment: Evidence from Indonesia. Labouratoire d'analyse et de recherche en économie et finance internationales.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1981). A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bennett, P., & Owens, I. (2002). Evolutionary ecology of birds: Life histories, mating systems and extinction. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bicchieri, C. (2005). The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bird, R. (1999). Cooperation and conflict: The behavioural ecology of the sexual division of labour. Evolutionary Anthropology: Issues, News, and Reviews, 8(2), 6575.3.0.CO;2-3>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blakemore, J. E. O. (2003). Children's beliefs about violating gender norms: Boys shouldn't look like girls, and girls shouldn't act like boys. Sex Roles, 48(9), 411419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonduriansky, R., & Chenoweth, S. F. (2009). Intralocus sexual conflict. Trends in Ecology & Evolution, 24(5), 280288.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Borgerhoff Mulder, M. (1998). Brothers and sisters: How sibling interactions affect optimal parental allocations. Human Nature, 9, 119162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borgerhoff Mulder, M. (2009). Tradeoffs and sexual conflict over women's fertility preferences in Mpimbwe. American Journal of Human Biology, 21(4), 478487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borgerhoff Mulder, M., & Rauch, K. L. (2009). Sexual conflict in humans: Variations and solutions. Evolutionary Anthropology: Issues, News, and Reviews, 18(5), 201214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bose, S., Trent, K., & South, S. J. (2013). The effect of a male surplus on intimate partner violence in India. Economic and Political Weekly, 48(35), http://www.epw.in/consequences–gender–imbalance/effect–male–surplus–intimate–partner–violence–india.html.Google ScholarPubMed
Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. (1985). Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. (2002). Group beneficial norms can spread rapidly in a structured population. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 215, 287–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyd, R. T., Richerson, P. J., & Henrich, J. (2011). The cultural niche: Why social learning is essential for human adaptation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(Supplement 2), 1091810925.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Brainerd, E. (2017). The lasting effect of sex ratio imbalance on marriage and family: Evidence from World War II in Russia. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 99(2), 229242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brooks, R. C., Russo-Batterham, D., & Blake, K. R. (2022). Incel activity on social media linked to local mating ecology. Psychological Science, 33(2), 249258.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Broude, G. J. (1980). Extramarital sex norms in cross-cultural perspective. Behaviour Science Research, 15(3), 181218. SAGE.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broude, G. J., & Greene, S. J. (1983). Cross-cultural codes on husband–wife relationships. Ethnology, 22(3), 263280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bulger, J. B. (1993). Dominance rank and access to estrous females in male savanna baboons. Behaviour, 127(1/2), 67103. Brill.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buss, D. M., Goetz, C., Duntley, J. D., Asao, K., & Conroy-Beam, D. (2017). The mate switching hypothesis. Personality and Individual Differences, 104, 143149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buss, D. M., & Schmitt, D. P. (1993). Sexual strategies theory: An evolutionary perspective on human mating. Psychological Review, 100(2), 204232.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Carmona-Isunza, M. C., Ancona, S., Székely, T., Ramallo-González, A. P., Cruz-López, M., Serrano-Meneses, M. A., & Küpper, C. (2017). Adult sex ratio and operational sex ratio exhibit different temporal dynamics in the wild. Behavioural Ecology, 28(2), 523532.Google Scholar
Carmona-Isunza, M. C., Küpper, C., Serrano-Meneses, M. A., & Székely, T. (2015). Courtship behaviour differs between monogamous and polygamous plovers. Behavioural Ecology and Sociobiology, 69(12), 20352042.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carroll, S. P. (1991). The adaptive significance of mate guarding in the soapberry bug, Jadera haematoloma (Hemiptera: Rhopalidae). Journal of Insect Behaviour, 4(4), 509530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carroll, S. P., & Corneli, P. S. (1995). Divergence in male mating tactics between two populations of the soapberry bug: II. Genetic change and the evolution of a plastic reaction norm in a variable social environment. Behavioural Ecology, 6(1), 4656.Google Scholar
Centola, D., & Baronchelli, A. (2015). The spontaneous emergence of conventions: An experimental study of cultural evolution. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 112(7), 19891994.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chakraborty, T., & Kim, S. (2010). Kinship institutions and sex ratios in India. Demography, 47(4), 9891012.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chao, F., Gerland, P., Cook, A. R., & Alkema, L. (2019). Systematic assessment of the sex ratio at birth for all countries and estimation of national imbalances and regional reference levels. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 116(19), 93039311.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chaudhuri, S. (2012). The desire for sons and excess fertility: A household-level analysis of parity progression in India. International Perspectives on Sexual and Reproductive Health, 38(4), 178186.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chudek, M., Heller, S., Birch, S., & Henrich, J. (2012). Prestige-biased cultural learning: Bystander's differential attention to potential models influences children's learning. Evolution and Human Behaviour, 33(1), 4656.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cislaghi, B., & Heise, L. (2020). Gender norms and social norms: Differences, similarities and why they matter in prevention science. Sociology of Health & Illness, 42(2), 407422.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Clarke, J. (2003). Sex ratio. In Demeny, P., & McNicoll, G. (Eds.), Encyclopedia of population (pp. 875878). Macmillan.Google Scholar
Clutton-Brock, T. H. (1991). The evolution of parental care. Monographs in Behaviour and Ecology, 64. Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clutton-Brock, T. H. (2016). Mammal societies. John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Cofnas, N. (2018). Power in cultural evolution and the spread of prosocial norms. The Quarterly Review of Biology, 93(4), 297318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cools, S., & Kotsadam, A. (2017). Resources and intimate partner violence in Sub-Saharan Africa. World Development, 95, 211230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cready, C. M., Fossett, M. A., & Kiecolt, K. J. (1997). Mate availability and African American family structure in the U. S. nonmetropolitan south, 1960–1990. Journal of Marriage and Family, 59(1), 192203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D'Alessio, S. J., & Stolzenberg, L. (2010). The sex ratio and male-on-female intimate partner violence. Journal of Criminal Justice, 38(4), 555561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diekmann, A. (1992). Sex-Ratio, divorce, and labour force participation – An analysis of international aggregate data. In Haag, G., Mueller, U., & Troitzsch, K. G. (Eds.), Economic evolution and demographic change: Formal models in social sciences. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems (pp. 283293). Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Divale, W. T., & Harris, M. (1976). Population, warfare, and the male supremacist complex. American Anthropologist, 78(3), 521538.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dong, H., & Kurosu, S. (2016). Missing girls and missing boys: Differential effects of marital residence, coresident kin, and household wealth in two Japanese villages, 1716–1870. Population Association of Japan, 68th Annual Meeting, June 2016, Reitaku University, Kashiwa-shi, Chiba, Japan.Google Scholar
Douglas, P. H., Hohmann, G., Murtagh, R., Thiessen-Bock, R., & Deschner, T. (2016). Mixed messages: Wild female bonobos show high variability in the timing of ovulation in relation to sexual swelling patterns. BMC Evolutionary Biology, 16(1), 140.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dunbar, R. I. M. (1995). The mating system of Callitrichid primates: I. Conditions for the coevolution of pair bonding and twinning. Animal Behaviour, 50, 10571070.Google Scholar
Dyson, T., & Moore, M. (1983). On kinship structure, female autonomy, and demographic behaviour in India. Population and Development Review, 9(1), 3560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eberhart-Phillips, L. J., Küpper, C., Carmona-Isunza, M. C., Vincze, O., Zefania, S., Cruz-López, M., …, Krüger, O. (2018). Demographic causes of adult sex ratio variation and their consequences for parental cooperation. Nature Communications, 9(1), 1651.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Efferson, C., Lalive, R., Richerson, P. J., McElreath, R., & Lubell, M. (2008). Conformists and mavericks: The empirics of frequency-dependent cultural transmission. Evolution and Human Behaviour, 29(1), 5664.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Egan, S. K., & Perry, D. G. (2001). Gender identity: A multidimensional analysis with implications for psychosocial adjustment. Developmental Psychology, 37, 451463.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Emlen, S. T., & Oring, L. W. (1977). Ecology, sexual selection, and the evolution of mating systems. Science, 197(4300), 215223.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fossett, M. A., & Kiecolt, K. J. (1993). Mate availability and family structure among African Americans in U. S. metropolitan areas. Journal of Marriage and Family, 55(2), 288302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Francis, A. M. (2011). Sex ratios and the red dragon: Using the Chinese Communist Revolution to explore the effect of the sex ratio on women and children in Taiwan. Journal of Population Economics, 24(3), 813837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fruth, B., & Hohmann, G. (2003). Intra- and inter-sexual aggression by bonobos in the context of mating. Behaviour, 140(11–12), 13891413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galliard, J.-F. L., Fitze, P. S., Ferrière, R., & Clobert, J. (2005). Sex ratio bias, male aggression, and population collapse in lizards. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 102(50), 1823118236.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gaulin, S. J. C., & Boster, J. S. (1990). Dowry as female competition. American Anthropologist, 92(4), 9941005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gavrilets, S. (2012). Human origins and the transition from promiscuity to pair-bonding. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 109(25), 99239928.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Goldizen, A. (1987). Facultative polyandry and the role of infant-carrying in wild saddle-back tamarins (Saguinus fiscicollis). Behavioural Ecology and Sociobiology, 20, 89109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goody, J. (1976). Production and reproduction: A comparative study of the domestic domain. Cambridge Studies in Social Anthropology. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Grosjean, P., & Khattar, R. (2019). It's raining men! Hallelujah? The long-run consequences of male-biased sex ratios. The Review of Economic Studies, 86(2), 723754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossbard, S. (2015). Sex ratios, polygyny, and the value of women in marriage – A Beckerian approach. Journal of Demographic Economics, 81(1), 1325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grüter, C., & Taborsky, B. (2005). Sex ratio and the sexual conflict about brood care in a biparental mouthbrooder. Behavioural Ecology and Sociobiology, 58(1), 4452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guttentag, M., & Secord, P. F. (1983). Too many women?: The sex ratio question. SAGE.Google Scholar
Hagen, R. V., & Scelza, B. A. (2020). Adoption of outgroup norms provides evidence for social transmission in perinatal care practices among rural Namibian women. Evolution, Medicine, and Public Health, 2020(1), 161173.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Harts, A. M. F., & Kokko, H. (2013). Understanding promiscuity: When is seeking additional mates better than guarding an already found one? Evolution, 67(10), 28382848.Google ScholarPubMed
Head, M. L., & Brooks, R. (2006). Sexual coercion and the opportunity for sexual selection in guppies. Animal Behaviour, 71(3), 515522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., & Boyd, R. T. (1998). The evolution of conformist transmission and the emergence of between-group differences. Evolution and Human Behaviour, 19(4), 215241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., & Gil-White, F. J. (2001). The evolution of prestige: Freely conferred deference as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evolution and Human Behaviour, 22(3), 165196.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Henrich, J., Boyd, R. T., & Richerson, P. J. (2012). The puzzle of monogamous marriage. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 367(1589), 657669.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Holdsworth, A. R., & Morse, D. H. (2000). Mate guarding and aggression by the crab spider Misumena vatia in relation to female reproductive status and sex ratio. The American Midland Naturalist, 143(1), 201211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hong Fincher, L. (2016). Leftover women: The resurgence of gender inequality in China. Zed Books.Google Scholar
Howard, J. A., & Gibson, M. A. (2017). Frequency-dependent female genital cutting behaviour confers evolutionary fitness benefits. Nature Ecology & Evolution, 1(3), 0049.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Howard, J. A., & Gibson, M. A. (2019). Is there a link between paternity concern and female genital cutting in West Africa? Evolution and Human Behaviour, 40(1), 111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hrdy, S. B. (1997). Raising Darwin's consciousness: Female sexuality and the prehominid origins of patriarchy. Human Nature (Hawthorne, NY), 8(1), 149.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jennions, M. D., & Fromhage, L. (2017). Not all sex ratios are equal: The Fisher condition, parental care and sexual selection. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 372(1729), 20160312.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ji, Y. (2015). Between tradition and modernity: ‘Leftover’ women in Shanghai. Journal of Marriage and Family, 77(5), 10571073.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johanos, T. C., Becker, B. L., Baker, J. D., Ragen, T. J., Gilmartin, W. G., & Gerrodette, T. (2010). Impacts of sex ratio reduction on male aggression in the Critically Endangered Hawaiian monk seal Monachus schauinslandi. Endangered Species Research, 11(2), 123132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, J. H., & Ferguson, B. (2006). The marriage squeeze in Colombia, 1973–2005: The role of excess male death. Social Biology, 53(3-4), 140151.Google Scholar
Käär, P., Jokela, J., Merilä, J., Helle, T., & Kojola, I. (1998). Sexual conflict and remarriage in preindustrial human populations: Causes and fitness consequences. Evolution and Human Behaviour, 19(3), 139151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kantor, P. (2003). Women's empowerment through home–based work: Evidence from India. Development and Change, 34(3), 425445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kappeler, P. M., Benhaiem, S., Fichtel, C., Fromhage, L., Höner, O. P., Jennions, M. D., …, Goymann, W. (2022). Sex roles and sex ratios in animals. Biological Reviews, 98(2), 462480.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Karlsson, K., Eroukhmanoff, F., & Svensson, E. I. (2010). Phenotypic plasticity in response to the social environment: Effects of density and sex ratio on mating behaviour following ecotype divergence. PLOS ONE, 5(9), e12755.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kilgallen, J. A., Schaffnit, S. B., Kumogola, Y., Galura, A., Urassa, M., & Lawson, D. W. (2021). Positive correlation between women's status and intimate partner violence suggests violence backlash in Mwanza, Tanzania. Journal of Interpersonal Violence, 37(21-22), NP20331NP20360.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
King, M. T. (2014). Between birth and death: Female infanticide in nineteenth-century China. Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Kokko, H., & Jennions, M. D. (2008). Parental investment, sexual selection and sex ratios. Journal of Evolutionary Biology, 21(4), 919948.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kruger, D. J., Fitzgerald, C. J., & Peterson, T. (2010). Female scarcity reduces women's marital ages and increases variance in men's marital ages. Evolutionary Psychology, 8(3), 147470491000800309.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kruger, D. J., & Schlemmer, E. (2009). Male scarcity is differentially related to male marital likelihood across the life course. Evolutionary Psychology, 7(2), 147470490900700210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lainiala, L., & Miettinen, A. (2013). Skewed marriage markets and sex ratios of Finnish People in their twenties. Finnish Yearbook of Population Research, 48, 5163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larsen, M., & Kaur, R. (2013). Signs of change? Sex ratio imbalance and shifting social practices in northern India. Economic and Political Weekly, 48(35), 4552.Google Scholar
Lawson, D. W., Alami, S., & Somefun, O. D. (2023). Gendered conflict in the human family. Evolutionary Human Sciences, 5, e12.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lawson, D. W., Schaffnit, S. B., Hassan, A., & Urassa, M. (2021). Shared interests or sexual conflict? Spousal age gap, women's wellbeing and fertility in rural Tanzania. Evolution and Human Behaviour, 42(2), 165175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leopold, T. (2018). Gender differences in the consequences of divorce: A study of multiple outcomes. Demography, 55(3), 769797.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Liker, A., Freckleton, R. P., & Székely, T. (2013). The evolution of sex roles in birds is related to adult sex ratio. Nature Communications, 4(1), 1587. Number: 1 Nature Publishing Group.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Loo, S. L., Hawkes, K., & Kim, P. S. (2017). Evolution of male strategies with sex-ratio-dependent pay-offs: Connecting pair bonds with grandmothering. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 372(1729), 20170041CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Loo, S. L., Rose, D., Hawkes, K., & Kim, P. S. (2021). Mate guarding in primates arises due to partner scarcity, even if the father provides no paternal care at all. Theoretical Population Biology, 142, 100113.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lukas, D., & Clutton-Brock, T. H. (2013). The evolution of social monogamy in mammals. Science, 341(6145), 526530.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lundberg, S. J., & Pollak, R. A. (1996). Bargaining and distribution in marriage. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(4), 139158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macionis, J. (2010). Sociology, 13th ed. Pearson Education.Google Scholar
Macmillan, R., & Gartner, R. (1999). When she brings home the bacon: Labour-force participation and the risk of spousal violence against women. Journal of Marriage and Family, 61(4), 947958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mass, V., Heistermann, M., & Kappeler, P. M. (2009). Mate-guarding as a male reproductive tactic in Propithecus verreauxi. International Journal of Primatology, 30(3), 389409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mathews, L. M. (2002). Tests of the mate-guarding hypothesis for social monogamy: Does population density, sex ratio, or female synchrony affect behaviour of male snapping shrimp (Alpheus angulatus)? Behavioural Ecology and Sociobiology, 51(5), 426432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mattison, S. M., Beheim, B., Chak, B., & Buston, P. (2016). Offspring sex preferences among patrilineal and matrilineal Mosuo in Southwest China revealed by differences in parity progression. Royal Society Open Science, 3(9), 160526.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Maynard Smith, J., & Ridpath, M. G. (1972). Wife sharing in the Tasmanian native hen, Tribonyx mortierii: A case of kin selection? The American Naturalist, 106(950), 447452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McElreath, R., Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. (2003). Shared norms and the evolution of ethnic markers. Current Anthropology, 44, 122130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mcnamara, J. M., Székely, T., Webb, J. N., & Houston, A. I. (2000). A dynamic game-theoretic model of parental care. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 205(4), 605623.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mesoudi, A. (2011a). Cultural evolution. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mesoudi, A. (2011b). An experimental comparison of human social learning strategies: Payoff-biased social learning is adaptive but underused. Evolution and Human Behaviour, 32(5), 334342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minocher, R., Duda, P., & Jaeggi, A. V. (2019). Explaining marriage patterns in a globally representative sample through socio-ecology and population history: A Bayesian phylogenetic analysis using a new supertree. Evolution and Human Behaviour, 40(2), 176187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mishra, P. (2013). Sex ratios, cross-region marriages and the challenge to caste endogamy in Haryana. Economic and Political Weekly, 48(35), 7078.Google Scholar
Moya, C., Snopkowski, K., & Sear, R. (2016). What do men want? Re-examining whether men benefit from higher fertility than is optimal for women. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 371(1692), 20150149.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Muller, M. N., Thompson, M. E., Kahlenberg, S. M., & Wrangham, R. W. (2011). Sexual coercion by male chimpanzees shows that female choice may be more apparent than real. Behavioural Ecology and Sociobiology, 65(5), 921933.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muller, M. N., & Wrangham, R. W. (2009). Sexual coercion in primates and humans. Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mungello, D. E. (2008). Drowning girls in China: Female infanticide in China since 1650. Rowman & Littlefield.Google Scholar
Muthukrishna, M., Morgan, T. J. H., & Henrich, J. (2016). The when and who of social learning and conformist transmission. Evolution and Human Behaviour, 37(1), 1020.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Connor, C. (2019). The origins of unfairness: Social categories and cultural evolution. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parker, G. (1979). Sexual competition and sexual conflict. In M. S., Blum, & N. A., Blum (Eds.), Sexual selection and reproductive competition in insects (pp. 123166). Academic Press.Google Scholar
Parker, G. (2006). Sexual conflict over mating and fertilization: An overview. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 361(1466), 235259.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Parrott, D. J. (2009). Aggression toward gay men as gender role enforcement: Effects of male role norms, sexual prejudice, and masculine gender role stress. Journal of Personality, 77(4), 11371166.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pedersen, F. A. (1991). Secular trends in human sex ratios. Human Nature, 2(3), 271291.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Penn, D. J., & Smith, K. R. (2007). Differential fitness costs of reproduction between the sexes. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 104(2), 553558.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pew Research Center (2019). Religion and living arrangements makeup around the world. https://www.pewforum.org/2019/12/12/religion-and-living-arrangements-around-the-world/Google Scholar
Pollet, T. V., & Nettle, D. (2008). Driving a hard bargain: Sex ratio and male marriage success in a historical US population. Biology Letters, 4(1), 3133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pollet, T. V., & Nettle, D. (2009). Market forces affect patterns of polygyny in Uganda. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106(7), 21142117.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pollet, T. V., Stoevenbelt, A. H., & Kuppens, T. (2017). The potential pitfalls of studying adult sex ratios at aggregate levels in humans. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 372(1729), 20160317.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Porter, M. (2016). How do sex ratios in China influence marriage decisions and intra-household resource allocation? Review of Economics of the Household, 14(2), 337371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pouget, E. R. (2017). Social determinants of adult sex ratios and racial/ethnic disparities in transmission of HIV and other sexually transmitted infections in the USA. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 372(1729), 20160323.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Queller, D. C. (1997). Why do females care more than males? Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences, 264(1388), 15551557.Google Scholar
Rao, V. (1993). The rising price of husbands: A hedonic analysis of dowry increases in rural India. Journal of Political Economy, 101(4), 666677.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Regan, C. E., Medill, S. A., Poissant, J., & McLoughlin, P. D. (2020). Causes and consequences of an unusually male-biased adult sex ratio in an unmanaged feral horse population. Journal of Animal Ecology, 89(12), 29092921.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reichert, K. E., Heistermann, M., Keith Hodges, J., Boesch, C., & Hohmann, G. (2002). What females tell males about their reproductive status: Are morphological and behavioural cues reliable signals of ovulation in bonobos (Pan paniscus)? Ethology, 108(7), 583600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richerson, P. J., & Boyd, R. T. (2005). Not By genes alone. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Ridgeway, C. L., & Correll, S. J. (2004). Unpacking the gender system: A theoretical perspective on gender beliefs and social relations. Gender & Society, 18(4), 510531.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, M. M. (2009). Male aggression against females in mountain gorillas: Courtship or coercion? In Muller, M. N., & Wrangham, R. W. (Eds.), Sexual coercion in primates and humans (pp. 112127). Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rosa, M. E., Barta, Z., Fülöp, A., Székely, T., & Kosztolányi, A. (2017). The effects of adult sex ratio and density on parental care in Lethrus apterus (Coleoptera, Geotrupidae). Animal Behaviour, 132, 181188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosaldo, M. Z. (1974). Women, culture, and society: A theoretical overview. In Rosaldo, M. Z., & Lamphere, L. (Eds.), Women, culture, and society. Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Rosenbaum, S., & Silk, J. B. (2022). Pathways to paternal care in primates. Evolutionary Anthropology: Issues, News, and Reviews, 31(5), 245262.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rowe, L. (1992). Convenience polyandry in a water strider: Foraging conflicts and female control of copulation frequency and guarding duration. Animal Behaviour, 44, 189202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scelza, B., Prall, S., & Starkweather, K. (2021). The role of spousal separation on norms related to gender and sexuality among Himba pastoralists. Social Sciences, 10(5), 174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scelza, B., Prall, S., Swinford, N., Gopalan, S., Atkinson, E., McElreath, R., Sheehama, J., & Henn, B. (2019). Husband, lover, pater, genitor: Concurrency and paternity in Himba pastoralists. American Journal of Physical Anthropology, 168, 218.Google Scholar
Scelza, B. A. (2013). Choosy but not chaste: Multiple mating in human females. Evolutionary Anthropology: Issues, News, and Reviews, 22(5), 259269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scelza, B. A., & Prall, S. P. (2023). Only death will separate us: The role of extramarital partnerships among Himba pastoralists. Archives of Sexual Behaviour, 52, 13551363.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schacht, R., & Bell, A. V. (2016). The evolution of monogamy in response to partner scarcity. Scientific Reports, 6, 32472.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schacht, R., & Borgerhoff Mulder, M. (2015). Sex ratio effects on reproductive strategies in humans. Royal Society Open Science, 2(1), 140402.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schacht, R., & Smith, K. R. (2017). Causes and consequences of adult sex ratio imbalance in a historical U.S. population. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 372(1729), 20160314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlegel, A., & Barry, H. (1986). The cultural consequences of female contribution to subsistence. American Anthropologist, 88(1), 142150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, D. M., & Gough, K. (1961). Matrilineal kinship. University of California Press.Google Scholar
Sen, A. K. (1990). Gender and cooperative conflicts. In Persistent inequalities: Women and world development. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Setchell, J. M., Charpentier, M., & Wickings, E. J. (2005). Mate guarding and paternity in mandrills: Factors influencing alpha male monopoly. Animal Behaviour, 70(5), 11051120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singh, M., Wrangham, R., & Glowacki, L. (2017). Self-interest and the design of rules. Human Nature, 28(4), 457480.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Skočajić, M. M., Radosavljević, J. G., Okičić, M. G., Janković, I. O., & Žeželj, I. L. (2020). Boys just don't! Gender stereotyping and sanctioning of counter-stereotypical behaviour in preschoolers. Sex Roles, 82(3), 163172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, E. A., & Smith, S. A. (1994). Inuit sex-ratio variation: Population control, ethnographic error, or parental manipulation? [And Comments and Reply]. Current Anthropology, 35(5), 595624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smuts, B. (1992). Male aggression against women. Human Nature, 3(1), 144.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Smuts, B. (1995). The evolutionary origins of patriarchy. Human Nature, 6(1), 132.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Snopkowski, K., & Sear, R. (2013). Kin influences on fertility in Thailand: Effects and mechanisms. Evolution and Human Behaviour, 34(2), 130138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
South, S. J., & Messner, S. F. (1987). The sex ratio and women's involvement in Crime: A cross-national analysis. The Sociological Quarterly, 28(2), 171188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Starkweather, K. E., & Hames, R. (2012). A survey of non-classical polyandry. Human Nature, 23(2), 149172.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Székely, T., & Cuthill, I. C. (2000). Trade-off between mating opportunities and parental care: Brood desertion by female Kentish plovers. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences, 267(1457), 20872092.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Székely, T., Carmona-Isunza, M. C., Engel, N., Halimubieke, N., Jones, W., Kubelka, V., … McDonald, G. C. (2023). The causes and implications of sex role diversity in shorebird breeding systems. Ibis. Eprint: https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/pdf/10.1111/ibi.13277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Székely, T., Thomas, G. H., & Cuthill, I. C. (2006). Sexual conflict, ecology, and breeding systems in shorebirds. BioScience, 56(10), 801808.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Székely, T., Weissing, F. J., & Komdeur, J. (2014). Adult sex ratio variation: Implications for breeding system evolution. Journal of Evolutionary Biology, 27(8), 15001512.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Takahashi, H. (2001). Influence of fluctuation in the operational sex ratio to mating of troop and non-troop male Japanese macaques for four years on Kinkazan Island, Japan. Primates, 42(3), 183191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Takeshita, F., & Henmi, Y. (2010). The effects of body size, ownership and sex-ratio on the precopulatory mate guarding of Caprella penantis (Crustacea: Amphipoda). Journal of the Marine Biological Association of the United Kingdom, 90(2), 275279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trivers, L. R. (1972). Parental investment and sexual selection. In B., Campbell (Ed.), Sexual selection and the descent of Man (pp. 136180). Heinemann.Google Scholar
Uggla, C., & Andersson, G. (2018). Higher divorce risk when mates are plentiful? Evidence from Denmark. Biology Letters, 14(9), 20180475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uggla, C., & Mace, R. (2017). Adult sex ratio and social status predict mating and parenting strategies in Northern Ireland. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 372(1729), 20160318.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
UN Statistics Division (2013). Indicators on women and men. https://data.un.org/Google Scholar
Vanterpool, K. B., Yarber, W. L., Rosenberg, M., Mowatt, R. A., & Garcia, J. R. (2021). Association of Black women's perceptions of the sex ratio to their attitudes toward and experiences of intimate partner violence. Violence Against Women, 28(3-4), 946965.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Vepsalainen, K., & Savolainen, R. (1995). Operational sex ratios and mating conflict between the sexes in the water strider Gerris lacustris. The American Naturalist, 146(6), 869880.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vyas, S., & Watts, C. (2009). How does economic empowerment affect women's risk of intimate partner violence in low and middle income countries? A systematic review of published evidence. Journal of International Development, 21(5), 577602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wada, S., Tanaka, K., & Goshima, S. (1999). Precopulatory mate guarding in the hermit crab Pagurus middendorffii (Brandt) (Decapoda: Paguridae), effects of population parameters on male guarding duration. Journal of Experimental Marine Biology and Ecology, 239(2), 289298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watts, D. P. (1998). Coalitionary mate guarding by male chimpanzees at Ngogo, Kibale National Park, Uganda. Behavioural Ecology and Sociobiology, 44(1), 4355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watts, D. P. (2022). Male chimpanzee sexual coercion and mating success at Ngogo. American Journal of Primatology, 84(2), e23361.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Weber, A. M., Cislaghi, B., Meausoone, V., Abdalla, S., Mejía-Guevara, I., Loftus, , …, Rao Gupta, G. (2019). Gender norms and health: Insights from global survey data. The Lancet, 393(10189), 24552468.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wei, S.-J., & Zhang, X. (2011). The competitive saving motive: Evidence from rising sex ratios and savings rates in China. Journal of Political Economy, 119(3), 511564.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weitzman, A. (2014). Women's and men's relative status and intimate partner violence in India. Population and Development Review, 40(1), 5575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whyte, M. K. (1978). Cross-cultural codes dealing with the relative status of women. Ethnology, 17(2), 211237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bank, World (2022). DataBank: Population estimates and projections. https://databank.worldbank.org/source/population-estimates-and-projections/Google Scholar
Yan, Y. (2003). Private life under socialism: Love, intimacy, and family change in a Chinese village, 1949–1999. Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, H. P. (1993). The evolution of conventions. Econometrica, 61(1), 5784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zefferman, M. R. (2016). Mothers teach daughters because daughters teach granddaughters: The evolution of sexbiased transmission. Behavioural Ecology, 27(4), 11721181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhu, W. X., Lu, L., & Hesketh, T. (2009). China's excess males, sex selective abortion, and one child policy: Analysis of data from 2005 national intercensus survey. The BMJ, 338, b1211.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Figure 0

Table 1. Glossary

Figure 1

Figure 1. Schematic representation of the relationship between ASR and gender ideology.

Figure 2

Figure 2. This diagram illustrates the effect of polygyny on partnership opportunities in social groups depending on the local ASR. Green circles indicate women, orange triangles refer to men, and lines around individuals indicate marriages or pair bonds. Rows represent different ASR, and columns vary in their marriage rules. The ASR and local marriage rules interact to determine marriage opportunities. For example, in the upper row the population ASR is female biased. When monogamy is the norm, some women remain without a partner. When men can have multiple partners, this dampens the effect of a female-biased sex ratio (and could even result in some men remaining partnerless). If polyandry occurs, this exacerbates the scarcity of partners for women.