Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T19:31:11.718Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Better-than-chance prediction of cooperative behaviour from first and second impressions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 January 2024

Eric Schniter*
Affiliation:
Economic Science Institute, Chapman University, Orange, CA 92866, USA Center for the Study of Human Nature, California State University Fullerton, Fullerton, CA 92831, USA Argyros School of Business and Economics, Chapman University, Orange, CA 92866, USA Division of Anthropology, California State University Fullerton, Fullerton, CA 92831, USA
Timothy W. Shields
Affiliation:
Economic Science Institute, Chapman University, Orange, CA 92866, USA Argyros School of Business and Economics, Chapman University, Orange, CA 92866, USA
*
Corresponding author: Eric Schniter; E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

Could cooperation among strangers be facilitated by adaptations that use sparse information to accurately predict cooperative behaviour? We hypothesise that predictions are influenced by beliefs, descriptions, appearance and behavioural history available for first and second impressions. We also hypothesise that predictions improve when more information is available. We conducted a two-part study. First, we recorded thin-slice videos of university students just before their choices in a repeated Prisoner's Dilemma with matched partners. Second, a worldwide sample of raters evaluated each player using videos, photos, only gender labels or neither images nor labels. Raters guessed players’ first-round Prisoner's Dilemma choices and then their second-round choices after reviewing first-round behavioural histories. Our design allows us to investigate incremental effects of gender, appearance and behavioural history gleaned during first and second impressions. Predictions become more accurate and better-than-chance when gender, appearance or behavioural history is added. However, these effects are not incrementally cumulative. Predictions from treatments showing player appearance were no more accurate than those from treatments revealing gender labels and predictions from videos were no more accurate than those from photos. These results demonstrate how people accurately predict cooperation under sparse information conditions, helping explain why conditional cooperation is common among strangers.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

Social media summary: People can predict others’ cooperative behaviours in a repeated Prisoner's Dilemma with better-than-chance accuracy.

1. Introduction

Opportunities for cooperation with strangers and repeated interaction have presented recurrent adaptive problems throughout human evolutionary history (Fehr & Henrich, Reference Fehr, Henrich and Hammerstein2003). Potentially valuable interactions with strangers entail danger, exploitation and mistrust (Daly & Wilson, Reference Daly and Wilson1988; Martin & Frayer, Reference Martin and Frayer2014; Wrangham, Reference Wrangham2019). Once reputations from interaction histories are established, partners can reap steady gains from iterated cooperation (Andreoni & Miller, Reference Andreoni and Miller1993; Kaplan et al., Reference Kaplan, Schniter, Smith and Wilson2012, Reference Kaplan, Schniter, Smith and Wilson2018; Kreps et al., Reference Kreps, Milgrom, Roberts and Wilson1982). However, established cooperators remain vulnerable to opportunistic exploitation by previously cooperative partners. These consequences have shaped our minds to detect and predict cooperators and cheaters in social contracts (Cosmides & Tooby, Reference Cosmides and Tooby1992; Green & Phillips, Reference Green and Phillips2004). These adaptive problems continue to present themselves in modern society (Nowak & Sigmund, Reference Nowak and Sigmund2005; Seabright, Reference Seabright2010). Despite these challenges, cooperation is often achieved. We study cooperative behaviour prediction based on demographic beliefs, contextual clues and evidence of past behaviour.

We test the general hypothesis that people can rapidly forecast behavioural propensities under sparse information conditions such as upon first and second impressions of strangers. We also evaluate the general hypothesis that behaviour predictions improve as more information is made available for first and second impressions. Below we explain our experimental approach and detail our predictions that people inform their guesses about strangers by applying their prior demographic beliefs and available clues revealed by the target's description, appearance and behaviours.

We conducted a non-deceptive two-part study with financially motivated participants. In part one, across multiple rounds of play between matched partners, we recorded ‘thin-slice’ videos only a few seconds in duration (Ambady & Rosenthal, Reference Ambady and Rosenthal1993) showing face-and-shoulder closeups of a university sample of participants taken just before their choices in each round of a ‘Split or Take All’ Prisoner's Dilemma (Prisoner's Dilemma) game variant with unknown end-game. In the second part of our study, we recruited online a set of raters to first make guesses about expected male and female cooperation rates from the Prisoner's Dilemma, then to guess the players’ Prisoner's Dilemma game behaviours. For each player guessed about, we provided a unique identification number and manipulated whether raters viewed either a thin-slice video showing the player, a photo still from the video, the player's self-identified gender label without photo or video or only the identification number. After forming a first impression, raters guessed each player's behaviour in the first round of gameplay. Raters also guessed behaviour in the second round after viewing first-round behavioural history and forming a second impression.

A unique feature of our thin slice and photo stimuli is that they feature contextually relevant information for the formation of first and second impressions. These stimuli may evoke relevant and difficult to fake signals that could diagnose behavioural propensity in the context of the player facing a social dilemma.

In social dilemmas like the repeated Prisoner's Dilemma, pursuing short-term non-cooperative benefits is at odds with the interests of developing cooperative partnerships. Despite the higher monetary rewards from successful non-cooperation, social dilemma experiments have demonstrated that cooperation can develop with unrelated strangers in one-shot environments (Balliet & Van Lange, Reference Balliet and Van Lange2013; Dawes & Thaler, Reference Dawes and Thaler1988; Dickhaut et al., Reference Dickhaut, Hubbard, McCabe and Smith2008; Kiyonari et al., Reference Kiyonari, Tanida and Yamagishi2000; McCabe et al., Reference McCabe, Rassenti and Smith1996, Reference McCabe, Rigdon and Smith2003; Ostrom & Walker, Reference Ostrom and Walker2003; Schneider & Shields, Reference Schneider and Shields2022), finitely repeated games (Andreoni & Miller, Reference Andreoni and Miller1993; Dawes & Thaler, Reference Dawes and Thaler1988; Embrey et al., Reference Embrey, Fréchette and Yuksel2018; Mao et al., Reference Mao, Dworkin, Suri and Watts2017) and infinitely repeated games with unknown endgame (Camera & Casari, Reference Camera and Casari2009; Duffy and Ochs, Reference Duffy and Ochs2009; van den Assem et al., Reference van den Assem, van Dolder and Thaler2012; Normann & Wallace, Reference Normann and Wallace2012). One explanation for this successful cooperation is that players can glean contextually evoked information and rely on accurate beliefs for predicting one another's game behaviour only moments later. The ability to predict cooperative behaviour from contextually relevant clues would also be valuable for navigating strategic interactions extending into the future, and therefore of great evolutionary significance since it could provide a basis for assortment.

Dawkins (Reference Dawkins1976) suggested that cooperation could evolve through self-assortment among conditional cooperators, if facilitated by a salient signal. He gave an example of a gene coding for a conspicuous ‘greenbeard’ phenotype with a propensity towards conditional cooperation; if those cooperators with greenbeard genes successfully self-assort, they can benefit from cooperation with one another and avoid exploitation by free riding, non-altruistic genes. However, as soon as non-altruists find a way to fake green beards, all bets are off for greenbeard fitness. Considering this problem, Price (Reference Price2006) argued that greenbeard selection should be expected for reliable and relevant signals of cooperative propensity such as a behavioural history of cooperative behaviour. To this we add: when behavioural history is unavailable, reliable demographic information about a person revealed by their belonging to a population or gender, or perhaps revealed by their appearance, might also provide relevant signals of cooperative propensity.

When a population of players contains a mix of cooperative and uncooperative types, one might expect that players who have cooperative intentions will initially choose to cooperate and those with exploitative intentions will initially choose to cheat. For conditional cooperators who prefer cooperating when their partner is a cooperator, beliefs about the ratio of cooperators to cheater types in a population should be an important predictor of the strategies deployed in first-round interactions (Kiyonari et al., Reference Kiyonari, Tanida and Yamagishi2000). Upon first-impression, when no prior reputational information is available, one can apply their ‘homemade’ prior beliefs about the ratio of cooperators to non-cooperators likely to be encountered (Camerer & Weigelt, Reference Camerer and Weigelt1998) or derived from stereotyped assumptions about targets (Ames et al., Reference Ames, Weber and Zou2012; McCabe et al., Reference McCabe, Smith and LePore2000). How those prior beliefs inform prediction strategies is less clear. One possibility is that forecasts are made using ‘probability matching’ strategies, where future outcomes are predicted with the frequency that approximately matches a prior belief or expected frequency. On average, probability matching tends to be less successful than using a pure optimisation strategy – predicting only the more expected outcome. While probability matching has been observed across various experiments, it tends to be less common under conditions like ours where participants are financially motivated and rewarded for correct predictions (Holt, Reference Holt2007; Siegel et al., Reference Siegel, Siegel and Andrews1964; Siegel & Goldstein, Reference Siegel and Goldstein1959; Vulkan, Reference Vulkan2000). From these considerations, we derive our first prediction: (P1) in the treatment where gender is not revealed, guesses of players’ Round 1 cooperativeness will be influenced by prior beliefs about cooperation propensity in the player population.

People expect behaviour in social dilemmas to vary by gender, and when players’ gender is revealed, people expect gender to be predictive of strategic behaviour (Fetchenhauer et al., Reference Fetchenhauer, Groothuis and Pradel2010; Schniter & Shields, Reference Schniter and Shields2020; Sylwester et al., Reference Sylwester, Lyons, Buchanan, Nettle and Roberts2012). Across cultures, people expect that others’ tendencies to cooperate depend on their gender, with women characterised as generally more communal and cooperative than men (Eagly, Reference Eagly2009). Upon visual inspection, male and female gender is differentiated in less than a second (Fletcher-Watson et al., Reference Fletcher-Watson, Findlay, Leekam and Benson2008), and usually achieving accuracy above 95% (Bruce et al., Reference Bruce, Burton, Hanna, Healey, Mason, Coombes, Fright and Linney1993; Bruce & Young, Reference Bruce and Young2011; Hill et al., Reference Hill, Bruce and Akamatsu1995; Jaeger et al., Reference Jaeger, Sleegers and Evans2020). This suggests that descriptions and appearance revealing gender inform raters of gender-specific behavioural propensities that could be used for predicting Prisoner's Dilemma strategies that males and females deploy in interactions with strangers. Of course, to successfully apply beliefs about gender to predictions of strangers’ behaviour, their gender needs to be known and the beliefs about each gender need to be accurate. In treatments where raters know players’ gender, we expect that beliefs about gender influence guesses such that (P2) sufficiently correct gender beliefs are associated with more correct guesses.

When faces can be seen in photos (Fetchenhauer et al., Reference Fetchenhauer, Groothuis and Pradel2010; Tognetti et al., Reference Tognetti, Berticat, Raymond and Faurie2013) or thin-slice video (Ambady et al., Reference Ambady, Bernieri and Richeson2000; Ambady & Rosenthal, Reference Ambady and Rosenthal1993; Fetchenhauer et al., Reference Fetchenhauer, Groothuis and Pradel2010; Vogt et al., Reference Vogt, Efferson and Fehr2013), or during brief personal interaction (Brosig, Reference Brosig2002; DeSteno et al., Reference DeSteno, Breazeal, Frank, Pizarro, Baumann, Dickens and Lee2012; Frank et al., Reference Frank, Gilovich and Regan1993; Reed et al., Reference Reed, Zeglen and Schmidt2012), first impressions are formed using the static or dynamic clues encountered (Snyder, Reference Snyder and Berkowitz1984). Faces may communicate information about stable dispositional traits like cooperativeness (Fetchenhauer et al., Reference Fetchenhauer, Groothuis and Pradel2010; Frank, Reference Frank1988; Frank et al., Reference Frank, Gilovich and Regan1993), and distinguishing characteristics like gender, formidability, health, kinship and ethnicity (Bruce et al., Reference Bruce, Burton, Hanna, Healey, Mason, Coombes, Fright and Linney1993; Fasolt et al., Reference Fasolt, Holzleitner, Lee, O'Shea and DeBruine2019; Zilioli et al., Reference Zilioli, Sell, Stirrat, Jagore, Vickerman and Watson2015). Facial displays of happiness and anger could also be helpful for behaviour prediction, as these displays are produced and understood by everyone, quickly interpreted – in well under a second (Batty & Taylor, Reference Batty and Taylor2003), and may be reliably informative of behavioural propensity (Ekman et al., Reference Ekman, Friesen, O'Sullivan, Chan, Diacoyanni-Tarlatzis, Heider and Tzavaras1987; Hirshleifer, Reference Hirshleifer and J.1987; Reed et al., Reference Reed, Zeglen and Schmidt2012; Verplaetse et al., Reference Verplaetse, Vanneste and Braeckman2007). As facial clues can be diagnostic of cooperative propensity, and first impressions from appearances may sometimes be accurate (Fetchenhauer et al., Reference Fetchenhauer, Groothuis and Pradel2010; Tognetti et al., Reference Tognetti, Berticat, Raymond and Faurie2013; Verplaetse et al., Reference Verplaetse, Vanneste and Braeckman2007; Vogt et al., Reference Vogt, Efferson and Fehr2013), we predict that (P3) guesses of Round 1 cooperativeness will be more accurate in treatments showing a photo or video of each player than in treatments not showing players’ appearances.

Brief in-person interactions and thin-slice videos of only a few seconds may reveal dynamic information about players that static photographs cannot (Ambadar et al., Reference Ambadar, Schooler and Cohn2005; Harwood et al., Reference Harwood, Hall and Shinkfield1999; Pike et al., Reference Pike, Kemp, Towell and Phillips1997; Sato et al., Reference Sato, Kochiyama, Yoshikawa, Naito and Matsumura2004). This dynamic appearance information may help people make better predictions, but it could also present an unhelpful distraction. Dynamic faces may display ‘tells’, or involuntary facial cues, eye movements, blinking and brief micro-expressions, that can be used to assess the cooperative propensity of targets (Fetchenhauer et al., Reference Fetchenhauer, Groothuis and Pradel2010; Frank, Reference Frank1988; Frank et al., Reference Frank, Gilovich and Regan1993; Hirshleifer, Reference Hirshleifer and J.1987; Reed et al., 2012). Dynamic faces may also reveal emotional expressivity, measured by the frequency and intensity of emotional expressions. Emotional expressivity can be used to index players’ likelihood of cooperation, as more emotionally expressive faces tend to be more cooperative (Schug et al., Reference Schug, Matsumoto, Horita, Yamagishi and Bonnet2010). While expressive behaviour sampled in first impressions can improve judgmental accuracy (Ambady et al., Reference Ambady, Bernieri and Richeson2000; Ambady & Rosenthal, Reference Ambady and Rosenthal1993), it may not always be beneficial. Emotionally expressive faces are highly arousing and provocative stimuli, providing distraction that cannot be easily ignored (Palermo & Rhodes, Reference Palermo and Rhodes2007). If attention to faces is overly demanding of limited time or cognitive resources, the ability to make accurate behaviour predictions upon first impressions might be compromised. This possibility is consistent with distraction-conflict models of attention allocation (Baron, Reference Baron and Berkowitz1986; Durkin et al., Reference Durkin, Jollineau and Lyon2020). Videos and in-person interactions that provide longer exposure to dynamic face stimuli may exacerbate this distraction problem. For example, Sylwester et al. (Reference Sylwester, Lyons, Buchanan, Nettle and Roberts2012) asked raters to assess either thin-slice (1–5 s) or long (60–120 s) video clips of people playing a variation of the Prisoner's Dilemma (Prisoner's Dilemma) game, and to predict whether each player would choose ‘Split’ or ‘Take All’. Although they did not find that raters had above chance accuracy for long videos, they did find that accuracy was higher than expected by chance for the shorter thin slice videos. As the richer dynamic information from thin-slice videos may help form first and second impressions, we predict that (P4) guesses of Round 1 cooperativeness will be more accurate in the video treatment than in the photo treatment.

In repeated interactions, prior demonstrations of partners’ cooperative behaviour can help inform beliefs about their intentions to cooperate (Coricelli et al., Reference Coricelli, McCabe, Smith, G., N. and H.2000; McCabe & Smith, Reference McCabe and Smith2001). Even if first impressions are inaccurate, when new evidence of cooperative behaviour is revealed (e.g. after a round of game interaction), behaviour predictions based on informed second impressions may become more accurate (Andreoni & Petrie, Reference Andreoni and Petrie2008; Schniter & Shields, Reference Schniter and Shields2014, 2020).

Players’ willingness to pursue cooperation conditionally depends on their preferences for mutual cooperation or exploitation, and consideration of whether partners previously cooperated (Kiyonari et al., Reference Kiyonari, Tanida and Yamagishi2000). This leads to selective cooperation among conditional cooperators, enabling conditional cooperators to escape exploitation and the consequential competitive disadvantage they would otherwise incur in repeated interactions with non-cooperators. After round one, we expect predictions of players’ behaviour to consider both players’ and partners’ previous behaviour. Figure 1 outlines a conditional cooperation heuristic that we expect people to apply when predicting cooperative behaviour. This simple heuristic expects conditional cooperators to rely on the tit-for-tat strategy (Rapoport et al., Reference Rapoport, Chammah and Orwant1965) for selecting next round behaviours in the Prisoner's Dilemma, and for non-cooperators to consistently prefer non-cooperation. Tit-for-tat mutual cooperation does not explain the origins of the evolution of cooperation (Axelrod, Reference Axelrod1984; Howard, Reference Howard1988), but rather explains how, despite hazards from potential interactions with non-cooperators, conditional cooperation can be sustained given humans’ evolved capacity for reciprocal altruism among unrelated conspecifics (Trivers, Reference Trivers1971). To predict someone's likelihood to cooperate, people should be able to evaluate their history of cooperation and then apply this simple one-reason heuristic quickly, with little cognitive effort or demand for additional information. Selection is expected to have strongly favoured ‘fast and frugal’ heuristics such as the one we propose because of their efficiency, inferential speed and accuracy in decision-making situations constrained by limited information and available time (Gigerenzer & Goldstein, Reference Gigerenzer and Goldstein1996; Hertwig & Herzog, Reference Hertwig and Herzog2009; Todd, Reference Todd2001). In our experiment, round 2 guesses are made with knowledge of the players’ past round behaviours, while round 1 guesses are made with no past behaviours known. This leads us to predict that (P5) the guesses made about round 2 will be more accurate than guesses made about round 1.

Figure 1. Conditional cooperation heuristic for predicting players’ cooperative propensity in a repeated Prisoner's Dilemma game with unknown endgame.

Our paper proceeds as follows: in Section 2 we review background literature and compare our cooperative behaviour prediction study design to others. In Section 3 we provide methodological details, in Section 4 we present results, and in Section 5 we discuss the results, study limitations and extensions.

2. Background

A cheater and cooperator detection adaptation appears to have evolved for solving problems associated with social exchange and cooperation (Cosmides, Reference Cosmides1989; Cosmides & Tooby, Reference Cosmides and Tooby1989, 1992, 2005). Accurate detection and prediction of cooperators and defectors is crucial for avoiding the pitfalls of interacting with non-cooperators or missing opportunities with cooperators (Cosmides & Tooby, Reference Cosmides and Tooby2005; Frank, Reference Frank1988). Despite a small industry of research efforts to study cooperation prediction abilities, support for or against them has been unclear, in-part owing to a diversity of research designs.

A few studies find support for accurate game behaviour prediction (Brosig, Reference Brosig2002; Frank et al., Reference Frank, Gilovich and Regan1993; Reed et al., 2012); however, others report mixed results with only partial support, or no support (Bonnefon et al., Reference Bonnefon, Hopfensitz and De Neys2013, Reference Bonnefon, Hopfensitz and Neys2017; Efferson & Vogt, Reference Efferson and Vogt2013; Fetchenhauer & Dunning, Reference Fetchenhauer and Dunning2010; Jaeger et al., Reference Jaeger, Oud, Williams, Krumhuber, Fehr and Engelmann2022; Kiyonari, Reference Kiyonari2010; Manson et al., Reference Manson, Gervais and Kline2013; Sparks et al., Reference Sparks, Burleigh and Barclay2016; Sylwester et al., Reference Sylwester, Lyons, Buchanan, Nettle and Roberts2012; Tognetti et al., Reference Tognetti, Berticat, Raymond and Faurie2013; Verplaetse et al., Reference Verplaetse, Vanneste and Braeckman2007; Vogt et al., Reference Vogt, Efferson and Fehr2013). Several of these studies do not reward raters’ correct guesses (Sylwester et al., Reference Sylwester, Lyons, Buchanan, Nettle and Roberts2012; Tognetti et al., Reference Tognetti, Berticat, Raymond and Faurie2013; Verplaetse et al., Reference Verplaetse, Vanneste and Braeckman2007), which may negatively affect the accuracy of raters’ guesses. In our study, correct beliefs about each gender and guesses about individual players are incentivised with monetary rewards, which should motivate raters to make their best guesses (Smith, Reference Smith1976). Cooperation prediction studies have also been limited to predictions of players with no reputational history of prior game behaviour. Our study is unique in that we study not only Round 1 guesses from first impressions with no reputational history, but also Round 2 guesses of those same players from informed second impressions – where raters know players’ behavioural history.

Many behaviour prediction studies draw raters and targets from the same subject pool. In some cases raters were shown targets that they had had prior interactions with or went on to play subsequent games with (Brosig, Reference Brosig2002; DeSteno et al., Reference DeSteno, Breazeal, Frank, Pizarro, Baumann, Dickens and Lee2012; Frank et al., Reference Frank, Gilovich and Regan1993; Manson et al., Reference Manson, Gervais and Kline2013; Reed et al., Reference Reed, Zeglen and Schmidt2012; Sparks et al., Reference Sparks, Burleigh and Barclay2016). Our worldwide online sample of raters is not drawn from the same local communities as the players they guess about, nor from the same convenience samples as the players, nor from among the set of players themselves. While convenient, more insular designs invite the possibility that prediction results are confounded by raters’ prior familiarity with targets, their involvement in the subject pool or experiment session, or behavioural norms specific to their local community.

Some have given attention to uncovering what aspects of targets’ appearance might be helping people make behaviour predictions (DeSteno et al., Reference DeSteno, Breazeal, Frank, Pizarro, Baumann, Dickens and Lee2012; Jaeger et al., Reference Jaeger, Oud, Williams, Krumhuber, Fehr and Engelmann2022; Manson et al., Reference Manson, Gervais and Kline2013; Reed et al., Reference Reed, Zeglen and Schmidt2012; Tognetti et al., Reference Tognetti, Berticat, Raymond and Faurie2013), although none of these have examined how well people can otherwise predict gameplay in the absence of personal cues from photos, videos, and face-to-face interactions, for example, by asking the question, ‘in the absence of visual stimulus, could strangers’ gameplay be predicted with above-chance accuracy?’ Our study design allows us to answer this question. Of the game behaviour prediction studies that feature visual stimuli of players, many show images of the players under highly specific and unnatural conditions, such as where hair, clothes and colour are removed from faces or where faces are required to display emotionally neutral poses (Bonnefon et al., Reference Bonnefon, Hopfensitz and De Neys2013; Jaeger et al., Reference Jaeger, Oud, Williams, Krumhuber, Fehr and Engelmann2022). Other studies censor and manipulate the distributions of target characteristics to be equiprobable rather than varying naturally or representative of society's base rates (Oda et al., Reference Oda, Yamagata, Yabiku and Matsumoto-Oda2009; Olivola & Todorov, Reference Olivola and Todorov2010). Yet other studies show videotapes of players, but drawn specifically from a disparate setting than where the game decision are predicted (Brown et al., Reference Brown, Palameta and Moore2003; Fetchenhauer et al., Reference Fetchenhauer, Groothuis and Pradel2010). While many of these manipulations of visual images are ideal for increasing experimental control, for example to investigate the role of isolated player features (e.g. face shape or expressions) on rater predictions, they provide distinctly different approaches to studying behaviour prediction abilities that complicate a comparative interpretation of their results.

Our study does not feature photos and videos from contextually disparate or unnatural conditions, nor does it censor or manipulate distributions of target characteristics. While our design controls the experimental settings and methods of stimulus capture, we allow Prisoner's Dilemma participants to exhibit natural and ad libitum behaviour in the moments before the Prisoner's Dilemma game decision, when we capture their image.

3. Methods

Our study consists of two experimental procedures. In the first part, we use an experimental economic game and self-reported demographics to generate target stimuli consisting of thin-slice videos, facial photographs, identification numbers, gender labels and behavioural strategies from a participant sample of game players. In the second part of our study, we use an economic experiment to ask whether raters can predict players’ game behaviours based on beliefs about players, beliefs about male or female players, static and dynamic appearance, and behavioural history.

3.1. Stimuli from Prisoner's Dilemmas

First, we conducted a computerised laboratory procedure in an experimental economics laboratory using a ‘Split or Take All’ Prisoner's Dilemma game variant with an unknown end-game and anonymous unacquainted matched pairs. In the players’ instructions, we specified and explained a random-stopping rule to determine the chance of players continuing to another round: 41−n where n is the current round (e.g. the chance is 1/1, 1/4, 1/16, 1/64 for rounds 1–4, respectively). In those instructions, we clarify that players would interact for a minimum of two rounds, with the possibility of more rounds (see Appendix B for details).

Participants recruited to be ‘players’ in the Prisoner's Dilemma were randomly drawn from a subject pool of graduates and undergraduates at Chapman University. We used no deception and paid these players for the outcomes of their behaviour in the study. As such, all game decisions were incentivised by the economic consequences of the game. We ran 13 sessions, each taking approximately 60 min.

In this Prisoner's Dilemma each player chooses between ‘Split’ or ‘Take All’ strategies. Players were provided a payoff matrix explaining the consequences of both players’ choices (Table 1). If both players choose ‘Split’ they each get 5 dollars; if both choose ‘Take All’ they each get nothing. However, if one chooses ‘Split’ but not the other, the player choosing ‘Split’ gets nothing and the other player gets 10 dollars. In the classic Prisoner's Dilemma, non-cooperation strictly dominates cooperation, whereas here it weakly dominates cooperation: choosing ‘Take All’ can do at least as well, and sometimes better than choosing ‘Split’. One advantage of the Split or Take All variant is that the strategy labels used are intuitive because they directly describe the payoff goals.

Table 1. Split or Take All Prisoner's Dilemma game payoffs.

Note: Row, column player payoffs are in US dollars.

Ninety-four players aged 18–25 (51 men, 45 women) consented to be video recorded at intervals throughout the experimental procedure under standardised videographic conditions and for their recordings and experiment data to be made available for later research. Players were told that at no time would their or other players’ identities or video recordings be revealed to participants in their experiment session.

Videos of players were taken using computer display-mounted digital cameras in individual computer terminal cubicles, set at the same distance from uniform backgrounds. From the original video recordings capturing head-and-shoulder closeups with ad libitum behaviours and expressions in the 8 s directly preceding game decision making, we trimmed thin-slice videos 2–3 s in length without audio. Photographs showing the player were captured from the thin-slice video. For these photographs, we chose moments that best showed participants’ faces with screen-oriented gaze following conclusion of their statement.

3.2. Prisoner's Dilemma prediction experiment

We recruited 445 participants (Meanage=33.6, Standard deviationage = 12.0; 48.53% male, 48.98% female) using www.prolific.co. Participants were allowed from all countries and given up to 87 min to complete the experiment. We restricted recruitment to volunteers with normal or corrected-to-normal vision and English fluency and only allowed volunteers to participate in the study once. A total of 422 participants remained after excluding participants for violating requirements; specifically, we excluded (i) 11 for taking the survey on a smart phone despite prohibition against using small screen devices and (ii) 12 for completing the task in less than 480 s, a speed we considered to be humanly improbable. Table A1 reports the characteristics of these participants whom we refer to as raters.

All raters received instructions. To advance to the prediction study, raters had to complete, without error, a series of control questions verifying that a human responder is attentive to questions. Instructions and survey questions are available in the Online Appendix B.

Raters received the same instructions for the Prisoner's Dilemma that were provided to players in the first experimental procedure. Raters were informed that they would first make guesses about the Round 1 behaviours of the female and male players in the original study. For example, ‘On a scale ranging from 0% to 100% of the time, how often do you guess that females chose to ‘Split’ and ‘Take All’ in the first round of the original experiment’, with the requirement that these percentages must equal 100%. Raters answered identical questions about males. These guesses inform us of raters’ prior beliefs about female and male players. Next, raters made a series of guesses about the game behaviours of each player from the original study by selecting either the cooperative strategy (‘Split’) or the uncooperative strategy (‘Take All’) that they expected the player to have chosen. Each rater made these guesses about each of the 94 players. First, all guesses about Round 1 game behaviour were made. Next, with the history of each player and partner's Round 1 behaviour provided, raters made all guesses about Round 2 game behaviour. We used no deception and paid raters for the accuracy of their guesses in the study. As such, all guesses made were incentivised by the economic consequences of their accuracy using a quadratic scoring rule if the guess is within 1/6 of the actual value.

3.4. Treatment groups

We conducted a 4 × 1 between-subjects design with raters randomly assigned to the treatment cells. There are four treatments manipulating player information available for first and second impressions. We call these ‘None’ (n = 108), ‘Label’ (n = 101), ‘Photo’ (n = 108) and ‘Video’ (n = 105). Our study began April 2021 with ‘None’, ‘Photo’ and ‘Video’ treatments and added the ‘Label’ treatment August 2022. All treatments make player IDs available and manipulate availability of behavioural history within-subjects. No history is available for raters’ first-impression Round 1 guesses and the history of players’ and partners’ Round 1 choices is available for raters’ second-impression Round 2 guesses. The Label, Photo and Video treatments reveal gender. The Photo and Video treatments reveal static player appearance. Only the Video treatment reveals dynamic appearance. As such, this design incrementally manipulates the availability of information about gender, static appearance, dynamic appearance and contextualised behavioural history (see Figure 2), allowing us to systematically evaluate the general hypothesis that availability of more of this information for first and second impressions leads to better predictions. This design also allows us to test predictions about the role of raters’ prior beliefs (P1), beliefs about genders (P2), players’ appearance (P3), static vs. dynamic appearance (P4) and behavioural history (P5). We preregistered our treatments at aspredicted.org (#61202, #103594) before collecting their data. Internal review board approval was granted by Chapman University (#1718H016, #1314H065).

Figure 2. Schematic diagram showing incremental manipulation of gender, static and dynamic appearance, and behavioural history information available for first and second impressions in a cooperative behaviour prediction experiment.

3.4. Measurements and analyses

Statistical analysis was performed using Stata/SE 17.0. We measure beliefs about players’ cooperation propensity as continuous variables in the 0–100% range. We evaluate the accuracy of beliefs using ‘belief error’: the absolute difference between the belief and the actual player behaviour. We measure and evaluate raters’ predictions of players’ individual choices that we call ‘guesses’, as well as performance across all predictions in a round. For each individual choice we measure the rater's binary guess, either ‘Split’ or ‘Take All’, and if the guess is correct: 1 if yes, 0 if no.

To measure accuracy over many predictions, we use signal detection theory, which evaluates the raters’ ability to distinguish potential cooperation from defection (Green & Swets, Reference Green and Swets1966; Macmillan & Creelman, Reference Macmillan and Creelman2004). Signal detection theory critically distinguishes two theoretically independent constructs: accuracy and bias. In our prediction task, accuracy is the raters’ ability to discriminate cheaters who choose ‘Take All’ from cooperators who choose ‘Split’, while bias is the raters’ tendency to guess players who choose ‘Take All’ or ‘Split’, independent of their ability to discriminate cheaters from cooperators. These signal detection theory constructs are based on the cooperator detection rate (H) and the cheater detection rate (R). H measures the proportion of times the rater guesses correctly given that the players choose ‘Split’ and R measures the proportion of observations the rater guesses correctly given the players choose ‘Take All’. Using these rates, ‘accuracy’ is operationalised as [Z(H) −  Z(1 − R)], where a zero value indicates that the rater shows no demonstrable ability to distinguish cooperators from cheaters. That is, a zero value indicates guess correctness is neither better nor worse than chance. ‘Bias’ is operationalised as −0.5 [Z(H) +  Z(1 − R)], where negative values represent a bias towards guessing ‘Split’, and positive values represent a bias towards guessing ‘Take All’. The function Z(.) is the inverse of the standard normal cumulative distribution, which converts rates into Z-scores. We transform rates of zero to 1/100,000 and rates of one to 99,999/100,000, so that the Z-scores do not go to infinity. Two alternative measures of accuracy, ‘correctness’ and the ‘odds ratio’ are described in Appendix C.

For first-round guesses about unknown gender players in the mixed gender population, we calculate raters’ ‘belief about players’ cooperative propensity’ from an average of their beliefs about male and female players.

To assess whether raters with more accurate beliefs make more correct guesses, we create dummy variables for belief accuracy that code for what we call ‘sufficiently correct beliefs’. The dummy is 1 if the rater's belief about a gender is greater than or equal to 50% and players of that gender tended to be cooperative, or if the rater's belief about a gender is less than 50% and players of that gender tended to be non-cooperative. Otherwise, the dummy is 0. A sufficiently correct dummy helps us evaluate whether correct beliefs could contribute to more correct guesses. If raters tend to base their guesses on sufficiently correct beliefs, then average guess correctness should increase with sufficiently correct beliefs. We also consider an alternative measure of gender-based belief accuracy, the ‘absolute error of belief’, measured as the absolute value of the difference between the belief and average player cooperation in round 1.

To evaluate differences in measures over summary statistics, we use Dependent $Variable = \alpha _0 + \sum \;\alpha _1^k \,Treatment$ as the regression model and report the Wald test statistic for where the treatment dummies are equal. All significantly reported results are robust using the nonparametric Kruskal–Wallis test.

When evaluating the effects of treatment groups and controls on raters’ individual guesses, we use logit panel regression, which controls for dependencies of repeated observations of the same rater. Panels identify the raters and trials identify the players.

$$Dependent\;Variable = \alpha _0 + \sum \alpha _1^k Treatment + \sum \alpha _2Controls + \sum \alpha _3^k Treament \times Controls$$

When the dependent variable is bounded within the unit interval, as with beliefs, or when we can reject that the dependent variable is normally distributed using the Shapiro–Wilk test, as with accuracy, we use a generalised least squares regression.

When evaluating the accuracy change between the first and second rounds, we use the general least squares panel regression, which controls for dependencies of repeated observations of the same rater. Panels identify the raters, and trials identify the rounds. Accuracy measures the raters’ ability to discriminate cheaters from cooperators and is constructed using all 94 guesses made in the round.

$$Accuracy = \alpha _0 + \sum \alpha _1^k Treatment + \alpha _2SecondRound + \sum \alpha _3^k Treament \times SecondRound$$

4. Results

Among Prisoner's Dilemma players we can observe the endogenous emergence and natural distribution of cooperative behaviours among matched pairs and the effects of game interaction outcomes on subsequent game behaviour. Below we describe the results of our Prisoner's Dilemma prediction study, which elicited raters’ beliefs about male and female players’ cooperativeness in the Prisoner's Dilemma, followed by predictions about individual Prisoner's Dilemma players’ game behaviour based on first and second impressions. On average, raters completed the study procedure in 24.4 min and earned $4.56. Prediction response times per target by treatment are reported with rater demographics in Table A1. Signal detection measures including cooperator detection rate, cheater detection rate, accuracy and bias are reported by treatment in Table A2.

4.1. Stereotypes about Prisoner's Dilemma players’ cooperation rates

Raters’ beliefs about players indicate that they expected players to cooperate 54% of the time in the first round (Table 2). There were no significant differences in the belief about players between treatments (χ2(3) = 3.99, p = 0.262). Male and female raters’ beliefs about players did not differ significantly (χ2(1) = 0.10, p = 0.746). Male players were believed to be less cooperative (44.2%) than females (63.9%). Since we find no significant difference in beliefs over treatments, we combine treatments and find that gender-specific beliefs about male and female players were heterogeneous (Figure 3), significantly correlated (Pearson 0.503, p < 0.001), and significantly different (Wilcoxon matched-pairs signed-rank test, Z = 16.1, p < 0.001).

Table 2. Raters’ prior beliefs about players’ cooperativeness.

Note. Where beliefs are reported, values are mean percent of time (standard deviation in parentheses) that raters guess that each gender chooses ‘Split’ in Round 1 of the repeated Prisoner's Dilemma. Where players actual cooperativeness is reported, values are mean percent of time (standard deviation in parentheses) players choose ‘Split’.

Figure 3. Raters’ gender-specific beliefs about the proportion of cooperative male and female players in the first round of a repeated Prisoner's Dilemma game with unknown endgame.

To evaluate beliefs, we use the regression Belief error =  α 0 +  α 1Rater gender +  α 2Belief Gender +  α 3Rater Gender  × Belief Gender, where belief error is the difference between a gender-specific belief and the gender-specific Round 1 observed behaviour, each rater is the panel, and the two beliefs are the trials. These gender beliefs significantly underestimated actual male player cooperation (61.4%) and female player cooperation (86.0%) in the first round (males: χ2(1) = 153.16, p < 0.001; females: χ2(1) = 392.56, p < 0.001). Male raters believed males to be slightly more cooperative (46.3%) than female raters (42.2%), a significant difference (χ2(1) = 5.46, p < 0.019). Similarly, female raters believed females to be more cooperative (66.5%) than male raters (61.8%), a significant difference (χ2(1) = 7.44, p < 0.006).

4.2. First-impression guesses about Prisoner's Dilemma players’ Round 1 game behaviour

Upon exposure to stimulus describing and sometimes showing Prisoner's Dilemma players deciding how to play in Round 1 of a repeated Prisoner's Dilemma, raters made rapid first impressions and predictions of each of 94 players, averaging across treatments 1.2 (None), 1.4 (Label), 3.1 (Photo) and 8.3 (Video) seconds per player. Consistent with their beliefs, raters underestimated Round 1 cooperation in all treatments, predicting 58.7% cooperation, when it was 74.5% (Table 3, panel A, all χ2(1) > 159.29, all p < 0.001).

Table 3. Raters’ guesses about players’ cooperative behaviour.

Note: Values for guessed Split, correctness, and actual Split are percentages. Standard deviations are in parentheses. Difference reports the results of the Wald test that the treatment dummy coefficients in generalised linear model regression are equal: chi-squared with 3 degrees of freedom reported; *** p < 0.001, ** p < 0.01, * p < 0.05. These test results are robust using Kruskal–Wallis.

Below, we evaluate our research questions concerning the predicted effect of beliefs, labels, photos, and videos on Round 1 game behaviour guesses.

Where gender cannot be detected, are Round 1 guesses influenced by beliefs about cooperation propensity in the player population (P1)? Yes

In the None treatment, where the raters did not know the players’ gender, players are expected to cooperate 55.9% of the time according to raters’ beliefs. Raters guessed that 63.6% would cooperate in Round 1. The effect of belief on guesses is significant in the None treatment (χ2(1) = 189.75, p < 0.001) (Table 4, regression 1).

Table 4. First-round guesses and correctness controlling for the raters’ beliefs.

$Dependent\;Variable = \alpha _0 + \sum \alpha _1^k \, Treatment + \alpha _2\,Belief + \sum \alpha _3^k \, Treament \times Belief$

Z-Value in parentheses. *** p < 0.001, ** p < 0.01. We report the results of logit regression, where the rater is the panel and players are the trials. Regression (1) includes first-round data from all treatments. Regressions (2) and (3) include first-round data only from treatments where players’ gender is revealed: Label, Photo and Video. The variable Belief about players in regression (1) refers to the average of the rater's male and female gender-specific beliefs. Gender-specific beliefs in regression (2) refers to the applicable belief about male or female player given the player's self-described gender. ‘Sufficiently correct stereotype’ in regression (3) is a dummy variable that equals one if the rater's gender stereotype is ≥50% and players of that gender tended to be cooperative, or if the rater's gender stereotype is <50% and players of that gender tended to be non-cooperative.

Are Round 1 guesses influenced by gender-specific beliefs such that sufficiently correct beliefs predict correct guesses in treatments where players’ gender is labelled or seen? (P2) Yes

The effect of gender-specific beliefs on guesses is positively significant in the Label, Photo, and Video treatments where gender can be visually detected (all χ2(1) > 258.98, all p < 0.001) (Table 4, regression 2). The effect of gender-specific beliefs is significantly stronger for the Label treatment than the Photo treatment (χ2(1) = 25.42, p < 0.001), and the effect is significantly stronger for the Photo treatment than for the Video treatment (χ2(1) = 65.85, p < 0.001).

Guess correctness is influenced by belief accuracy (Table 4, regressions 3). For all treatments, sufficiently correct beliefs are significantly positively correlated with correct guesses (all χ2(1) > 74.78, all p < 0.001). These results remain robust when using the ‘absolute error of belief’ measure: errors are significantly negatively correlated with correct guesses in all treatments (allχ2(1) > 34.37, all p < 0.001).

Are Round 1 guesses more accurate in the treatments showing the player's appearance (P3)? Yes

We report accuracy by treatment controlling for the round in Table 5. Prediction accuracy is improved for treatments showing players’ appearance (χ2(1) = 6.39, p = 0.015). We test for robustness using alternative operationalisations of accuracy described in Appendix C. This result is robust to tests using correctness but not the odds-ratio (Table C1).

Table 5. Accuracy by treatment controlling for the round.

$Accuracy = \alpha _0 + \sum \alpha _1^k\, Treatment + \alpha _2\,SecondRound + \sum \alpha _3^k \, Treament \times SecondRound$

Z-Value in parentheses. *** p < 0.001, ** p < 0.01, * p < 0.05. All general least squares regressions use measures constructed over the round where the rater is the panel and rounds are the trials. All results are robust using ordinary least squares regression.

Are Round 1 guesses more accurate in the video treatment than in the photo treatment (P4)? No

Round 1 accuracy is not statistically more accurate in the Video treatment than in the Photo treatment (χ2(1) = 3.14, p = 0.076). This result is consistent with tests using correctness and the odds-ratio (Table C1).

4.3. Second-impression guesses of Prisoner's Dilemma players’ Round 2 game behaviour

Raters guessed 58.8% of players would cooperate in Round 2, quite close to their guess of 58.7% cooperation in Round 1 (Table 3, panel A). Players’ cooperative behaviour decreased from 74.5% in Round 1 to 53.2% in Round 2. Compared with Round 1 guesses, accuracy increased for Round 2 guesses (Table 3, panel A). Below we report results that help explain these performance improvements.

Are round 2 guesses more accurate than round 1 guesses (P5)? Yes

Across treatments, Round 2 guesses were significantly more accurate than in Round 1 for all treatments (all χ2(1) > 32.09, all p < 0.001). This result is robust to tests using correctness and odds-ratio (Table C1). Figure 4 illustrates that Round 2 guesses are more correct than expected by chance (accuracy > 0) across treatments (all p < 0.001). Next, we conduct post-hoc analysis to determine whether the artefactual conditions endogenously created by players’ Round 1 behavioural history affected raters’ Round 2 guess performance, and whether players’ facial description and appearance may have played a role.

Figure 4. Accuracy of first-round and second-round guesses by treatment. Accuracy is measured as [Z(H) −  Z(1 − R)], where Z(.) is the Z-score, H is the cooperator detection rate and R is the cheater detection rate. An accuracy value of zero is no better or worse than chance and indicates no demonstrable ability to distinguish cooperators from cheaters.

4.4. Post-hoc analyses of Round 2 guesses given beliefs, conditions with gender or appearance revealed, and behavioural history

Round 2 guess accuracy improves significantly across conditions (all χ2(1) > 32.09, all p < 0.001). However, Round 2 guess accuracy was significantly greater in conditions revealing players’ appearance (Photo and Video), than in conditions that did not (χ2(1) = 5.42, p = 0.019).

Raters’ Round 2 guesses vary across the players’ four possible behavioural histories: ‘Both Take All’, ‘Take All/Partner Split’, ‘Split/Partner Take All’ and ‘Both Split’ (Table 3, panel B). Compared with the Round 1 guesses, raters significantly increased their Round 2 guesses of cooperation for the ‘Both Split’ behavioural history condition, and significantly decreased their guesses of cooperation for behavioural history conditions where at least one partnered player chose ‘Take All’.

Round 2 guesses are affected by seeing gender labels or players’ appearance in the context of Round 1 behavioural history, as these clues help improve guess correctness about male players generally (Table A2), and guess correctness for all players in the behavioural conditions where one or both partners chose ‘Take All’ (Table A3). We find significant differences in correctness when raters had access to players’ appearances, but no significant differences between the Photo and Video treatments. When raters see a player's appearance in a ‘Take All/Partner Split’ interaction, they more aptly guess player behaviour in Round 2. Likewise, when raters see the player's appearance in a ‘Split/Partner Take All’ interaction, they more aptly guess Round 2 behaviour – resulting in more correctness than in conditions without the player's appearance (Table A3).

5. Discussion

These results provide supporting evidence for the mechanisms designed to rapidly predict others’ cooperativeness when forming first and second impressions. Below we discuss the importance of prior demographic beliefs, contextual clues and evidence of past behaviour for revealing behaviour prediction abilities.

Our results suggest that when the incentive structure of a game is easily understood, raters can make cooperation predictions easily and in rapid succession, taking about 3–4 s on average to form impressions, evaluate, and guess about each player. More often than not, these predictions are correct – even though the players are strangers and the raters initially have no direct behavioural evidence of past behaviours. The incentive structure we chose for our ‘Split or Take All’ Prisoner's Dilemma game appears to be widely understood – leading to common perspectives and expectations among players and raters; it is identical to that of games featured on television shows such as Friend or Foe, Golden Balls or Take It All which since have been analysed as a natural experiment of cooperation (Burton-Chellew & West, Reference Burton-Chellew and West2012; van den Assem et al., Reference van den Assem, van Dolder and Thaler2012). In Friend or Foe, Golden Balls or Take It All games, players choose ‘Split’ 53% of the time, and young adult males are less cooperative than young adult females (Burton-Chellew & West, Reference Burton-Chellew and West2012; van den Assem et al., Reference van den Assem, van Dolder and Thaler2012). Our raters expected males to be less cooperative, and for players to cooperate 54% of the time, almost identical to the game show average.

While we investigate the possibility that there are some reliably observable signals among players with propensity to cooperate, for example, visual clues of player gender that correspond to raters’ gender-specific beliefs, our results do not suggest cooperators are detectable ex-ante owing to visual greenbeard-like signals from facial expression or expressivity that might distinguish individuals as being Round 1 cooperators or non-cooperators. As our results suggest, accurate cooperation detection in Round 1 relies on guesses about a large set of players based on fairly accurate prior beliefs. As such, upon first impressions, first-round cooperators are detectable at a rate better than expected by chance, but with error. This agrees with others’ findings that participants correctly expect that most other people in experiments with them are cooperative (Andreoni & Miller, Reference Andreoni and Miller1993; McCabe et al., Reference McCabe, Smith and LePore2000), consistent with observed cooperation rate evidence (Andreoni & Miller, Reference Andreoni and Miller1993; Camerer & Weigelt, Reference Camerer and Weigelt1998; Hayashi et al., Reference Hayashi, Ostrom, Walker and Yamagishi1999; Kiyonari et al., Reference Kiyonari, Tanida and Yamagishi2000; Kurzban & Houser, Reference Kurzban and Houser2005; McKelvey & Palfrey, Reference McKelvey and Palfrey1992). A closer look at the decomposed Round 1 cooperator detection rate and Round 1 cheater detection rate indicates that raters correctly identify 59.8% of cooperators but only 44.8% of non-cooperators, with a bias value of −0.316 indicating a tendency towards predicting cooperation (Table A2). The better-than-chance correct guesses are consistent with raters’ applying their beliefs that most people are cooperators. Raters predicted that around 55 of the 94 players (~58.7%) would choose to cooperate in Round 1 and, indeed, most (70 of 94 or 74.5%) players chose to cooperate in Round 1. As our results demonstrate, the positive correlation between prior beliefs about Round 1 cooperation rates in the general population (54%), or for males (44.2%) and females (63.9%) specifically, and the observed Round 1 cooperation rates (61.4% males, 86.0% females, 74.5% all players) explains much of why this better-than-chance prediction of cooperative behaviour exists.

Interestingly, the effect of correct gender-specific beliefs on correct guesses of a player's Round 1 behaviour is strongest in the gender label treatment. For Round 1 guesses, there is no evidence that observable signs from players’ static or dynamic appearances improve cooperation detection beyond their contribution to informing raters of the player's gender. Our gender-label treatment allows us to carefully isolate the effect of male or female gender from other effects of visual appearance available to raters in photo and video treatments. While all our Prisoner's Dilemma players self-identified as either male or female, a small portion of our raters chose to not identify as male or female. Future studies will benefit from inquiry into the alternative gender identities and concepts that are becoming increasingly preferred by survey respondents and might better reveal gender influences if carefully measured (Snyder et al., Reference Snyder, Tabler and Gonzales2022).

The informational differences afforded by our treatments suggest that raters may not have equal reason to rely on gender-specific beliefs across treatments. Across conditions that reveal gender, the Label treatment provides raters less player information than the Photo treatment, which provides less player information than the Video treatment. As a result of these differences in available information, raters may trade off the value of gender clues for additional visual clues. An additional concern about differences across these treatments is that the appearance of static or dynamic faces may present an unhelpful distraction for raters who might be better off relying on accurate prior beliefs. The formation of first impressions from faces may be so automatic and non-conscious that they are relied upon even when objectively better information is available (Olivola & Todorov, Reference Olivola and Todorov2010; Rezlescu et al., Reference Rezlescu, Duchaine, Olivola and Chater2012) or when it is known that one should avoid being influenced by faces (Blair et al., Reference Blair, Judd and Fallman2004; Hassin & Trope, Reference Hassin and Trope2000; Palermo & Rhodes, Reference Palermo and Rhodes2007). While raters in our study appear to be trading off the influence of gender-specific beliefs for additional appearance information, the effect of more appearance information on Round 1 guess accuracy is unhelpful: the Photo treatment is somewhat less accurate than the Label treatment, and the Video treatment is no better off, consistent with the conflict-distraction model. As we discuss further below, the effect of appearance information on second impressions is positive, improving all measures of accuracy relative to those treatments with no player appearance revealed.

Across first- and second-round predictions, accuracy in the Video treatment is no better than in the Photo treatment. Attention to dynamic faces requires more time and attentional resources potentially distracting or interfering with processing capacity for tasks separate from face inspection (Lavie, Reference Lavie1995; Pessoa et al., Reference Pessoa, McKenna, Gutierrez and Ungerleider2002). The attentional costs and longer response times in our Video treatment may have contributed to a greater conflict-distraction effect, producing less guess correctness and accuracy than in the Photo treatment. Our research design did not compel standard response times across treatments to control for these costs. More research is needed to understand the reasons for response time variation and the role of response time costs.

Upon learning the details of players’ Round 1 Prisoner's Dilemma interactions, raters can form second impressions with the behavioural history information gleaned. From these second impressions, raters make better-than-chance predictions of players’ Round 2 Prisoner's Dilemma game behaviours across all treatments – improving their guess performance from Round 1 guesses. Our proposed behaviour prediction heuristic (Figure 1) may help explain how people use behavioural history information to ‘mind read’ the propensities of others, effectively predicting their cooperative behaviours in mixed-motive social dilemmas (Baron-Cohen, Reference Baron-Cohen1997; McCabe & Smith, Reference McCabe and Smith2001; Sylwester et al., Reference Sylwester, Lyons, Buchanan, Nettle and Roberts2012). Future research will be able to demonstrate the role of behavioural history on guess accuracy by experimentally manipulating behavioural history information availability for Round 2 guesses. For second impressions, player appearance also helps raters make more accurate guesses: guess accuracy is higher in photo and video treatments – a result which was not seen with Round 1 guesses. Round 2 guesses are also more correct under conditions where one partner chose ‘Take All’. Prior research suggests that more masculine male faces are associated with perceptions of aggressiveness and dominance (Geniole et al., Reference Geniole, Denson, Dixson, Carré and McCormick2015; Sell et al., Reference Sell, Cosmides, Tooby, Sznycer, von Rueden and Gurven2009; Zilioli et al., Reference Zilioli, Sell, Stirrat, Jagore, Vickerman and Watson2015), consistent with the idea that males who appear stronger and more masculine have greater potential bargaining power via coercive formidability and therefore can be expected to act more aggressively, reactively, and less cooperatively in social dilemma interactions (Daly & Wilson, Reference Daly and Wilson1988; Sell et al., Reference Sell, Hone and Pound2012). Given our effects of male faces on Round 2 guesses, it may be productive for future research to investigate further how variation in male cues, such as facial masculinity and formidability, may be predictive of cooperativeness in repeated games, especially in the context of game interactions with previously non-cooperative partners, where entitlement and reactive anger may be at play.

Raters demonstrate better-than-chance behaviour prediction abilities in three out of four treatments for Round 1 guesses, and in all the treatments for Round 2 guesses. Our results suggest that these prediction abilities respond to sparse clues, like gender and appearance, available in first and second impressions. As gender identity and photo or video appearance are influential parameters in self-presentation across a variety of human interaction media affecting investment, voting, legal decisions, hiring, mate selection and cooperative interaction (Snyder et al., Reference Snyder, Tabler and Gonzales2022; Todorov, Reference Todorov2017), our results provide important insight into key hazards and trade-offs involved with revealing or not revealing gender identity and static or dynamic appearance when first or second impressions form and new relationships develop.

Our study provides an explanation for why cooperation is so commonly observed among strangers in social dilemmas like the Prisoner's Dilemma despite incentives to be uncooperative: people can predict the cooperation propensities of most other people and likely use this ability to identify and maintain mutually beneficial cooperative relationships. Prior studies demonstrated that cheater detection abilities are particularly sensitive to rule violation information (Brown & Moore, Reference Brown and Moore2000; Cosmides, Reference Cosmides1989; Cosmides & Tooby, Reference Cosmides and Tooby1992; Fiddick & Erlich, Reference Fiddick and Erlich2010; Oda et al., Reference Oda, Hiraishi and Matsumoto-Oda2006). Our study demonstrates that cheater and cooperator detection is sensitive to sparse person and context information, adding another facet to our understanding of how cheater detection adaptations are designed. Our study also provides insight into accurate predictions of trust re-extension, an important but precarious and all-too-common problem in personal and business relationships (Robinson & Rousseau, Reference Robinson and Rousseau1994; Schniter & Sheremeta, Reference Schniter and Sheremeta2014).

The behavioural sciences have extensively studied the design of people's chosen behaviours in potentially cooperative strategic interactions. However, clean experimental tests and a clear understanding of people's expectations of others’ behaviours in unacquainted and repeated interactions have been missing. The evidence presented here suggests people can accurately predict the cooperativeness of strangers, helping explain the broad extent of human cooperativeness revealed by experimental and ethnographic studies. In conclusion, our study provides further support for the claim that an evolutionary–functional framework is a productive and promising approach to uncovering the nature of human cooperation and cooperative behaviour prediction.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/ehs.2023.30.

Acknowledgements

We thank members of the Economic Science Institute, the Center for Study of Human Nature, the California Workshop on Evolutionary Social Science, and the Experimental Science Association Annual North American meeting for their helpful comments and advice.

Author contributions

Both authors contributed equally to the study conception and design, data collection, statistical analyses, and writing.

Financial support

This work was supported by the Economic Science Institute at Chapman University.

Competing interest

Eric Schniter and Timothy Shields declare none.

Research transparency and reproducibility

Experiment stimuli along with complete details of the Prisoner's Dilemma game, procedure and stimulus development are openly available online at https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.4321821. The data that support the findings of this study are openly available at https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.7465288.

References

Ambadar, Z., Schooler, J. W., & Cohn, J. F. (2005). Deciphering the Enigmatic Face: The Importance of Facial Dynamics in Interpreting Subtle Facial Expressions. Psychological Science, 16(5), 403410. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0956-7976.2005.01548.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ambady, N., Bernieri, F. J., & Richeson, J. A. (2000). Toward a histology of social behavior: Judgmental accuracy from thin slices of the behavioral stream. In Advances in Experimental Social Psychology (Vol. 32, pp. 201271). Academic Press. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0065-2601(00)80006-4Google Scholar
Ambady, N., & Rosenthal, R. (1993). Half a minute: Predicting teacher evaluations from thin slices of nonverbal behavior and physical attractiveness. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 64(3), 431441. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.64.3.431CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ames, D. R., Weber, E. U., & Zou, X. (2012). Mind-reading in strategic interaction: The impact of perceived similarity on projection and stereotyping. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 117(1), 96110. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2011.07.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. H. (1993). Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoner's dilemma: Experimental evidence. The Economic Journal, 103(418), 570585. https://doi.org/10.2307/2234532CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Petrie, R. (2008). Beauty, gender and stereotypes: Evidence from laboratory experiments. Journal of Economic Psychology, 29(1), 7393. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2007.07.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books.Google Scholar
Balliet, D., & Van Lange, P. A. M. (2013). Trust, conflict, and cooperation: A meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 139(5), 10901112. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0030939CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Baron, R. S. (1986). Distraction-conflict theory: Progress and problems. In Berkowitz, L. (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 19, pp. 140). Academic Press. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0065-2601(08)60211-7Google Scholar
Baron-Cohen, S. (1997). Mindblindness: An essay on autism and theory of mind. MIT press.Google Scholar
Batty, M., & Taylor, M. J. (2003). Early processing of the six basic facial emotional expressions. Cognitive brain research, 17(3), 613–620.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Blair, I. V., Judd, C. M., & Fallman, J. L. (2004). The automaticity of race and Afrocentric facial features in social judgments. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 87(6), 763778. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.87.6.763CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bonnefon, J. F., Hopfensitz, A., & De Neys, W. (2013). The modular nature of trustworthiness detection. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 142(1), 143150. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0028930CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bonnefon, J. F., Hopfensitz, A., & De Neys, W. (2017). Can we detect cooperators by looking at their face?. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 26(3), 276281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brosig, J. (2002). Identifying cooperative behavior: Some experimental results in a prisoner's dilemma game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 47(3), 275290. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(01)00211-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, W. M., & Moore, C. (2000). Is prospective altruist-detection an evolved solution to the adaptive problem of subtle cheating in cooperative ventures? Supportive evidence using the Wason selection task. Evolution and Human Behavior, 21(1), 2537. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1090-5138(99)00018-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, W. M., Palameta, B., & Moore, C. (2003). Are there nonverbal cues to commitment? An exploratory study using the zero-acquaintance video presentation paradigm. Evolutionary Psychology, 1(1), 147470490300100100. https://doi.org/10.1177/147470490300100104CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruce, V., Burton, A. M., Hanna, E., Healey, P., Mason, O., Coombes, A., Fright, R., & Linney, A. (1993). Sex discrimination: How do we tell the difference between male and female faces? Perception, 22(2), 131152. https://doi.org/10.1068/p220131CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bruce, V., & Young, A. (2011). Face perception. Psychology Press. https://doi.org/10.4324/9780203721254Google Scholar
Burton-Chellew, M. N., & West, S. A. (2012). Correlates of cooperation in a one-shot high-stakes televised prisoners’ dilemma. PLOS ONE, 7(4), e33344. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0033344CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camera, G., & Casari, M. (2009). Cooperation among strangers under the shadow of the future. American Economic Review, 99(3), 9791005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C., & Weigelt, K. (1998). Experimental tests of a sequential equilibrium reputation model. Econometrica, 56, 136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coricelli, G., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. (2000). Theory-of-mind mechanism in personal exchange. In G., Hatano, N., Okada, & H., Tanabe (Eds.), Affective minds (pp. 249259). Elsevier Science.Google Scholar
Cosmides, L. (1989). The logic of social exchange: Has natural selection shaped how humans reason? Studies with the Wason selection task. Cognition, 31(3), 187276. https://doi.org/10.1016/0010-0277(89)90023-1CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (1989). Evolutionary psychology and the generation of culture, part II: Case study: A computational theory of social exchange. Ethology and Sociobiology, 10(1), 5197. https://doi.org/10.1016/0162-3095(89)90013-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (1992). Cognitive adaptations for social exchange. The Adapted Mind: Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture, 163228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (2005). Neurocognitive adaptations designed for social exchange. The Handbook of Evolutionary Psychology, 584627.Google Scholar
Daly, M., & Wilson, M. (1988). Homicide. Transaction.Google Scholar
Dawes, R. M., & Thaler, R. H. (1988). Anomalies: Cooperation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2(3), 187197. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.2.3.187CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawkins, R. (1976). The selfish gene. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
DeSteno, D., Breazeal, C., Frank, R. H., Pizarro, D., Baumann, J., Dickens, L., & Lee, J. J. (2012). Detecting the trustworthiness of novel partners in economic exchange. Psychological Science, 23(12), 15491556. https://doi.org/10.1177/0956797612448793CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dickhaut, J., Hubbard, J., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. (2008). Trust, reciprocity, and interpersonal history: Fool me once, shame on you, fool me twice, shame on me. Working paper, University of Minnesota.Google Scholar
Duffy, J., & Ochs, J. (2009). Cooperative behavior and the frequency of social interaction. Games and Economic Behavior, 66(2), 785812.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durkin, M. P., Jollineau, S. J., & Lyon, S. C. (2020). Sounds good to me: How communication mode and priming affect auditor performance. AUDITING: A Journal of Practice & Theory, 40(1), 117. https://doi.org/10.2308/AJPT-19-038CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eagly, A. H. (2009). The his and hers of prosocial behavior: An examination of the social psychology of gender. American Psychologist, 64(8), 644658. https://doi.org/10.1037/0003-066X.64.8.644CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Efferson, C., & Vogt, S. (2013). Viewing men's faces does not lead to accurate predictions of trustworthiness. Scientific Reports, 3(1), 1047. https://doi.org/10.1038/srep01047CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekman, P., Friesen, W. V., O'Sullivan, M., Chan, A., Diacoyanni-Tarlatzis, I., Heider, K., …, Tzavaras, A. (1987). Universals and cultural differences in the judgments of facial expressions of emotion. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 53(4), 712717. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.53.4.712CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Embrey, M., Fréchette, G. R., & Yuksel, S. (2018). Cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoner's dilemma. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133(1), 509551. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjx033CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fasolt, V., Holzleitner, I. J., Lee, A. J., O'Shea, K. J., & DeBruine, L. M. (2019). Contribution of shape and surface reflectance information to kinship detection in 3D face images. Journal of Vision, 19(12), 99. https://doi.org/10.1167/19.12.9CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fehr, E., & Henrich, J. (2003). Is strong reciprocity a maladaptation? On the evolutionary foundations of human altruism. In Hammerstein, P. (Ed.), Genetic and cultural evolution of cooperation (pp. 5582). MIT Press. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.382950CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fetchenhauer, D., & Dunning, D. (2010). Why so cynical?: Asymmetric feedback underlies misguided skepticism regarding the trustworthiness of others. Psychological Science, 21(2), 189193. https://doi.org/10.1177/0956797609358586CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fetchenhauer, D., Groothuis, T., & Pradel, J. (2010). Not only states but traits – Humans can identify permanent altruistic dispositions in 20 s. Evolution and Human Behavior, 31(2), 8086. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2009.06.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiddick, L., & Erlich, N. (2010). Giving it all away: Altruism and answers to the Wason selection task. Evolution and Human Behavior, 31(2), 131140. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2009.08.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fletcher-Watson, S., Findlay, J. M., Leekam, S. R., & Benson, V. (2008). Rapid detection of person information in a naturalistic scene. Perception, 37(4), 571583.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, R. H. (1988). Passions within reason: The strategic role of the emotions (pp. xiii, 304). W W Norton & Co.Google Scholar
Frank, R. H., Gilovich, T., & Regan, D. T. (1993). The evolution of one-shot cooperation: An experiment. Ethology and Sociobiology, 14(4), 247256. https://doi.org/10.1016/0162-3095(93)90020-ICrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geniole, S. N., Denson, T. F., Dixson, B. J., Carré, J. M., & McCormick, C. M. (2015). Evidence from meta-analyses of the facial width-to-height ratio as an evolved cue of threat. PLOS ONE, 10(7), e0132726. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0132726CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gigerenzer, G., & Goldstein, D. G. (1996). Reasoning the fast and frugal way: Models of bounded rationality. Psychological Review, 103(4), 650669. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.103.4.650CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Green, D. M., & Swets, John. A. (1966). Signal detection theory and psychophysics. Wiley & Sons. https://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/10.1086/405615Google Scholar
Green, M. J., & Phillips, M. L. (2004). Social threat perception and the evolution of paranoia. Neuroscience & Biobehavioral Reviews, 28(3), 333342. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.neubiorev.2004.03.006CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Harwood, N. K., Hall, L. J., & Shinkfield, A. J. (1999). Recognition of facial emotional expressions from moving and static displays by individuals with mental retardation. American Journal on Mental Retardation, 104(3), 270278. https://doi.org/10.1352/0895-8017(1999)104<0270:ROFEEF>2.0.CO;22.0.CO;2>CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hassin, R., & Trope, Y. (2000). Facing faces: Studies on the cognitive aspects of physiognomy. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 78(5), 837852. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.78.5.837CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hayashi, N., Ostrom, E., Walker, J., & Yamagishi, T. (1999). Reciprocity, trust, and the sense of control: A cross-societal studY. Rationality and Society, 11(1), 2746. https://doi.org/10.1177/104346399011001002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hertwig, R., & Herzog, S. M. (2009). Fast and frugal heuristics: Tools of social rationality. Social Cognition, 27(5), 661698. https://doi.org/10.1521/soco.2009.27.5.661CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, H., Bruce, V., & Akamatsu, S. (1995). Perceiving the sex and race of faces: The role of shape and colour. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences, 261(1362), 367373. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.1995.0161Google ScholarPubMed
Hirshleifer, J.. (1987). On the emotions as guarantors of threats and promises. In J., Dupré (Ed.), The latest on the best: Essays on evolution and optimality (pp. 307326)). The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Howard, J. V. (1988). Cooperation in the prisoner's dilemma. Theory and Decision, 24(3), 203213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaeger, B., Oud, B., Williams, T., Krumhuber, E. G., Fehr, E., & Engelmann, J. B. (2022). Can people detect the trustworthiness of strangers based on their facial appearance? Evolution and Human Behavior. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2022.04.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaeger, B., Sleegers, W. W. A., & Evans, A. M. (2020). Automated classification of demographics from face images: A tutorial and validation. Social and Personality Psychology Compass, 14(3), e12520. https://doi.org/10.1111/spc3.12520CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, H. S., Schniter, E., Smith, V. L., & Wilson, B. J. (2012). Risk and the evolution of human exchange. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 279(1740), 29302935. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2011.2614CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kaplan, H. S., Schniter, E., Smith, V. L., & Wilson, B. J. (2018). Experimental tests of the tolerated theft and risk-reduction theories of resource exchange. Nature Human Behaviour, 2(6), 383. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-018-0356-xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kiyonari, T. (2010). Detecting defectors when they have incentives to manipulate their impressions. Letters on Evolutionary Behavioral Science, 1(1), Article 1. https://doi.org/10.5178/lebs.2010.5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiyonari, T., Tanida, S., & Yamagishi, T. (2000). Social exchange and reciprocity: Confusion or a heuristic? Evolution and Human Behavior, 21(6), 411427. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1090-5138(00)00055-6CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kreps, D. M., Milgrom, P., Roberts, J., & Wilson, R. (1982). Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoners’ dilemma. Journal of Economic Theory, 27(2), 245252. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(82)90029-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurzban, R., & Houser, D. (2005). Experiments investigating cooperative types in humans: A complement to evolutionary theory and simulations. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 102(5), 18031807. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0408759102CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lavie, N. (1995). Perceptual load as a necessary condition for selective attention. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 21(3), 451468. https://doi.org/10.1037/0096-1523.21.3.451Google ScholarPubMed
Macmillan, N. A., & Creelman, C. D. (2004). Detection theory: A user's guide. Taylor & Francis.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manson, J. H., Gervais, M. M., & Kline, M. A. (2013). Defectors cannot be detected during'small talk’ with strangers. PLOS ONE, 8(12), e82531. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0082531CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mao, A., Dworkin, L., Suri, S., & Watts, D. J. (2017). Resilient cooperators stabilize long-run cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoner's dilemma. Nature Communications, 8(1), 13800. https://doi.org/10.1038/ncomms13800CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Martin, D. L., & Frayer, David. W. (Eds.). (2014). Troubled times: Violence and warfare in the past. Routledge. https://doi.org/10.4324/9781315078328Google Scholar
McCabe, K. A., Rassenti, S. J., & Smith, V. L. (1996). Game theory and reciprocity in some extensive form experimental games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 93(23), 1342113428. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.93.23.13421CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McCabe, K. A., Rigdon, M. L., & Smith, V. L. (2003). Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 52(2), 267275. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(03)00003-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCabe, K. A., & Smith, V. L. (2001). Goodwill accounting and the process of exchange. Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox (pp. 319340). The MIT Press.Google Scholar
McCabe, K. A., Smith, V. L., & LePore, M. (2000). Intentionality detection and ‘mindreading’: Why does game form matter? Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 97(8), 44044409. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.97.8.4404CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McKelvey, R. D., & Palfrey, T. R. (1992). An experimental study of the centipede game. Econometrica, 60(4), 803836. https://doi.org/10.2307/2951567CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Normann, H. T., & Wallace, B. (2012). The impact of the termination rule on cooperation in a prisoner's dilemma experiment. International Journal of Game Theory, 41(3), 707718. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-012-0341-yCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowak, M. A., & Sigmund, K. (2005). Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature, 437(7063), 12911298. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature04131CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Oda, R., Hiraishi, K., & Matsumoto-Oda, A. (2006). Does an altruist-detection cognitive mechanism function independently of a cheater-detection cognitive mechanism? Studies using Wason selection tasks. Evolution and Human Behavior, 27(5), 366380. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2006.03.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oda, R., Yamagata, N., Yabiku, Y., & Matsumoto-Oda, A. (2009). Altruism can be assessed correctly based on impression. Human Nature, 20(3), 331341. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-009-9070-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olivola, C. Y., & Todorov, A. (2010). Fooled by first impressions? Reexamining the diagnostic value of appearance-based inferences. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 46(2), 315324. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jesp.2009.12.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E., & Walker, J. (2003). Trust and reciprocity: Interdisciplinary lessons for experimental research. Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Palermo, R., & Rhodes, G. (2007). Are you always on my mind? A review of how face perception and attention interact. Neuropsychologia, 45(1), 7592. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.neuropsychologia.2006.04.025CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pessoa, L., McKenna, M., Gutierrez, E., & Ungerleider, L. G. (2002). Neural processing of emotional faces requires attention. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 99(17), 1145811463. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.172403899CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pike, G. E., Kemp, R. I., Towell, N. A., & Phillips, K. C. (1997). Recognizing moving faces: The relative contribution of motion and perspective view information. Visual Cognition, 4(4), 409438. https://doi.org/10.1080/713756769CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Price, M. E. (2006). Monitoring, reputation, and ‘greenbeard'reciprocity in a Shuar work team. Journal of Organizational Behavior: The International Journal of Industrial, Occupational and Organizational Psychology and Behavior, 27(2), 201219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, A., Chammah, A. M., & Orwant, C. J. (1965). Prisoner's dilemma: A study in conflict and cooperation. University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reed, L. I., Zeglen, K. N., & Schmidt, K. L. (2012). Facial expressions as honest signals of cooperative intent in a one-shot anonymous prisoner's dilemma game. Evolution and Human Behavior, 33(3), 200209. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2011.09.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rezlescu, C., Duchaine, B., Olivola, C. Y., & Chater, N. (2012). Unfakeable facial configurations affect strategic choices in trust games with or without information about past behavior. PLOS ONE, 7(3), e34293. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0034293CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Robinson, S. L., & Rousseau, D. M. (1994). Violating the psychological contract: Not the exception but the norm. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 15(3), 245259. https://doi.org/10.1002/job.4030150306CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sato, W., Kochiyama, T., Yoshikawa, S., Naito, E., & Matsumura, M. (2004). Enhanced neural activity in response to dynamic facial expressions of emotion: An fMRI study. Cognitive Brain Research, 20(1), 8191. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cogbrainres.2004.01.008CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schneider, M., & Shields, T. (2022). Motives for cooperation in the one-shot prisoner's dilemma. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 23(4), 438456. https://doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2022.2081974CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schniter, E., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2014). Predictable and predictive emotions: Explaining cheap signals and trust re-extension. Frontiers in Behavioral Neuroscience, 8. https://doi.org/10.3389/fnbeh.2014.00401CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schniter, E., & Shields, T. W. (2014). Ageism, honesty, and trust. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 51, 1929. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2014.03.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schniter, E., & Shields, T. W. (2020). Gender, stereotypes, and trust in communication. Human Nature, 31(3), 296321. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-020-09376-3CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schug, J., Matsumoto, D., Horita, Y., Yamagishi, T., & Bonnet, K. (2010). Emotional expressivity as a signal of cooperation. Evolution and Human Behavior, 31(2), 8794. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2009.09.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seabright, P. (2010). The company of strangers: A natural history of economic life (revised edn). Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sell, A., Cosmides, L., Tooby, J., Sznycer, D., von Rueden, C., & Gurven, M. (2009). Human adaptations for the visual assessment of strength and fighting ability from the body and face. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 276(1656), 575584. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2008.1177CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sell, A., Hone, L. S. E., & Pound, N. (2012). The importance of physical strength to human males. Human Nature, 23(1), 3044. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-012-9131-2CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Siegel, S., & Goldstein, D. A. (1959). Decision-making behavior in a two-choice uncertain outcome situation. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 57(1), 3742. https://doi.org/10.1037/h0045959CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siegel, S., Siegel, A., & Andrews, J. (1964). Choice, strategy, and utility. McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Snyder, J. A., Tabler, J., & Gonzales, C. M. (2022). Measuring sexual identity, gender identity, and biological sex in large social surveys: Implications for victimization research. Criminal Justice and Behavior, 49(9), 13761395. https://doi.org/10.1177/00938548221097034CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. L. (1976). Experimental economics: Induced value theory. The American Economic Review, 66(2), 274279.Google Scholar
Snyder, M. (1984). When belief creates reality. In Berkowitz, L. (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 18, pp. 247305). Academic Press. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0065-2601(08)60146-XGoogle Scholar
Sparks, A., Burleigh, T., & Barclay, P. (2016). We can see inside: Accurate prediction of prisoner's dilemma decisions in announced games following a face-to-face interaction. Evolution and Human Behavior, 37(3), 210216. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2015.11.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sylwester, K., Lyons, M., Buchanan, C., Nettle, D., & Roberts, G. (2012). The role of Theory of Mind in assessing cooperative intentions. Personality and Individual Differences, 52(2), 113117. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.paid.2011.09.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Todd, P. M. (2001). Fast and frugal heuristics for environmentally bounded minds. In Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox (pp. 5170). The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Todorov, A. (2017). Face value: The irresistible influence of first impressions. In Face value. Princeton University Press. https://doi.org/10.1515/9781400885725Google Scholar
Tognetti, A., Berticat, C., Raymond, M., & Faurie, C. (2013). Is cooperativeness readable in static facial features? An inter-cultural approach. Evolution and Human Behavior, 34(6), 427432. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2013.08.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trivers, R. L. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal altruism. The Quarterly Review of Biology, 46(1), 3557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van den Assem, M. J., van Dolder, D., & Thaler, R. H. (2012). Split or steal? Cooperative behavior when the stakes are large. Management Science, 58(1), 220. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1110.1413CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verplaetse, J., Vanneste, S., & Braeckman, J. (2007). You can judge a book by its cover: The sequel. A kernel of truth in predictive cheating detection. Evolution and Human Behavior, 28(4), 260271. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2007.04.006Google Scholar
Vogt, S., Efferson, C., & Fehr, E. (2013). Can we see inside? Predicting strategic behavior given limited information. Evolution and Human Behavior, 34(4), 258264. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2013.03.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vulkan, N. (2000). An economist's perspective on probability matching. Journal of Economic Surveys, 14(1), 101118. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6419.00106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wrangham, R. (2019). The goodness paradox: The strange relationship between virtue and violence in human evolution. Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Zilioli, S., Sell, A. N., Stirrat, M., Jagore, J., Vickerman, W., & Watson, N. V. (2015). Face of a fighter: Bizygomatic width as a cue of formidability. Aggressive Behavior, 41(4), 322330. https://doi.org/10.1002/ab.21544CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Figure 0

Figure 1. Conditional cooperation heuristic for predicting players’ cooperative propensity in a repeated Prisoner's Dilemma game with unknown endgame.

Figure 1

Table 1. Split or Take All Prisoner's Dilemma game payoffs.

Figure 2

Figure 2. Schematic diagram showing incremental manipulation of gender, static and dynamic appearance, and behavioural history information available for first and second impressions in a cooperative behaviour prediction experiment.

Figure 3

Table 2. Raters’ prior beliefs about players’ cooperativeness.

Figure 4

Figure 3. Raters’ gender-specific beliefs about the proportion of cooperative male and female players in the first round of a repeated Prisoner's Dilemma game with unknown endgame.

Figure 5

Table 3. Raters’ guesses about players’ cooperative behaviour.

Figure 6

Table 4. First-round guesses and correctness controlling for the raters’ beliefs.$Dependent\;Variable = \alpha _0 + \sum \alpha _1^k \, Treatment + \alpha _2\,Belief + \sum \alpha _3^k \, Treament \times Belief$

Figure 7

Table 5. Accuracy by treatment controlling for the round.$Accuracy = \alpha _0 + \sum \alpha _1^k\, Treatment + \alpha _2\,SecondRound + \sum \alpha _3^k \, Treament \times SecondRound$

Figure 8

Figure 4. Accuracy of first-round and second-round guesses by treatment. Accuracy is measured as [Z(H) −  Z(1 − R)], where Z(.) is the Z-score, H is the cooperator detection rate and R is the cheater detection rate. An accuracy value of zero is no better or worse than chance and indicates no demonstrable ability to distinguish cooperators from cheaters.

Supplementary material: File

Schniter and Shields supplementary material

Schniter and Shields supplementary material
Download Schniter and Shields supplementary material(File)
File 522.1 KB