Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-18T18:00:37.201Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Electoral incentives, party discipline, and legislative organization: manipulating legislative committees to win elections and maintain party unity

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 July 2011

Naofumi Fujimura*
Affiliation:
Graduate School of Law, Kobe University, Kobe, Hyogo, Japan
*

Abstract

Political parties are often faced with seemingly opposing goals when trying to secure members’ reelection and maintain party unity. On one hand, a party needs to fulfill members’ diverse electoral needs for their reelection, and on the other hand, the party must force members to vote in unison according to party lines for collective decisions. How does a party influence its members to take unified action while meeting their individual electoral needs? Through an analysis of the Japanese Diet, this study argues that parties attempt to achieve the reelection of their members and maintain party unity by manipulating legislative committee assignments and deliberations. In particular, the study demonstrates that a party shapes committees in a different way according to policy areas over which committees have jurisdiction. A party tends to accept its members’ requests for affiliation and allow their self-management in committees concerned with particularistic benefits so that they can deliver specific benefits to each electoral district. In addition, a party tends to assign members who have average policy positions in the party to committees concerned with general benefits to make policies that satisfy many constituencies.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © European Consortium for Political Research 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aldrich, J.H. (1995), Why Parties?: The Origin and Transformation of Political Parties in America, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baerwald, H.H. (1974), Japan's Parliament: An Introduction, London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bawn, K.Thies, M.F. (2003), ‘A comparative theory of electoral incentives: representing the unorganized under PR, plurality and mixed-member electoral systems’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 15(5): 532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowler, S., Farrell, D.M.Katz, R.S. (ed.) (1999), Party Discipline and Parliamentary Government, Columbus: Ohio State University Press.Google Scholar
Cain, B., Ferejohn, J.Fiorina, M. (1987), The Personal Vote: Constituency Service and Electoral Independence, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carey, J.M. (2007), ‘Comparing principals, political institutions, and party unity in legislative voting’, American Journal of Political Science 51(1): 92107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carroll, R.Kim, H.A. (2010), ‘Party government and the “Cohesive Power” of public plunder’, American Journal of Political Science 54(1): 3444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, G.W.McCubbins, M.D. (2004), ‘Theories of legislative organization’, APSA-CP 15(1): 912.Google Scholar
Cox, G.W.McCubbins, M.D. (2005), Setting the Agenda: Responsible Party Government in the U.S. House of Representatives, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, G.W.McCubbins, M.D. (2007), Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House, 2nd edn., Berkley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crisp, B.F., Escobar-Lemmon, M.C., Jones, B.S., Jones, M.P.Taylor-Robinson, M.M. (2009), ‘The electoral connection and legislative committees’, Journal of Legislative Studies 15(1): 3552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gamm, G.Huber, J. (2002), ‘Legislatures as political institutions: beyond the contemporary congress’, in I. Katznelson and H.V. Milner (eds), Political Science: State of the Discipline, New York: W W Norton, pp. 325327.Google Scholar
Gilligan, T.W.Krehbiel, K. (1990), ‘Organization of informative committees by a rational legislature’, American Journal of Political Science 34(2): 531564.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, S. (2004), ‘Electoral institutions and legislative behavior: explaining voting defection in the European Parliament’, World Politics 56(2): 194223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Inoguchi, T.Iwai, T. (1987), Zoku Giin no Kenkyu [Analysis of Zoku Legislator], Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.Google Scholar
Ito, M. (1988), ‘Kokkai no Mekanizumu to Kinou [The Mechanism and Function of the Deit]’, Nempo Seijigaku 38: 129147.Google Scholar
Iwai, T. (1988), Rippo Katei [Legislative Process], Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, K. (1991), Informational and Legislative Organization, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Machidori, S. (2005), ‘The 1990s reforms have transformed Japanese politics’, Japan Echo 32(3): 3843.Google Scholar
Masuyama, M. (2003), Gikai Seido to Nihon Seiji [Agenda Power in the Japanese Diet], Tokyo: Bokutaku Sha.Google Scholar
Matsumoto, S. (2007), ‘55 Nen Taisei Ka ni Okeru Iinkai Seido Saiko [Reconsidering Committee Systems under the 1955 Regime]’, Meijo Hogaku 57(1-2): 399446.Google Scholar
Matsumoto, S.Matsuo, A. (2011), ‘Kokkai Giin ha Naze Iinkai de Hatsugen Suru no ka [Why Do Diet Members Speak at Committee Meetings?]’, Japanese Journal of Electoral Studies 26(2): 84103.Google Scholar
Mochizuki, M.M. (1982), Managing and influencing the Japanese legislative process: the role of parties and the national diet. Ph.D. Dissertation, Harvard University.Google Scholar
Nakajima, M. (2007), Rippo Gaku [Study of Legislation], 2nd edn., Kyoto: Horitsu Bunka Sha.Google Scholar
Nihon Seikei Shimbun Sha. Kokkai Binran [Diet Handbook]. Tokyo, Each issue.Google Scholar
Oyama, R. (2003), Kokkai Gaku Nyumon [Introduction to Diet Studies], 2nd edn., Tokyo: Sansei Do.Google Scholar
Pekkanen, R., Nyblade, B.Krauss, E.S. (2006), ‘Electoral incentives in mixed-member systems: party, posts, and zombie politicians in Japan’, American Political Science Review 100(2): 183193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sato, S.Matsuzaki, T. (1986), Jiminto Seiken [Liberal Democratic Party Government], Tokyo: Chuo Koron Sha.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. (1978), The Giant Jigsaw Puzzle, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A.Weingast, B.R. (1981), ‘Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice’, Public Choice 37(3): 503509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K.A.Weingast, B.R. (ed.) (1994), Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Sone, Y.Iwai, T. (1988), ‘Seisaku Katei ni okeru Gikai no Yakuwari [The Role of the Diet in Policymaking]’, Nempo Seijigaku 38: 149175.Google Scholar
Stratmann, T.Baur, M. (2002), ‘Plurality rule, proportional representation, and the German Bundestag: how incentives to pork-barrel differ across electoral systems’, American Journal of Political Science 46(3): 506514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strøm, K. (1990), ‘A behavioral theory of competitive political parties’, American Political Science Review 34(2): 565598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tatebayashi, M. (2004), Giin Kodo no Seijikeizaigaku [The Logic of Legislative Activities], Tokyo: Yuhikaku.Google Scholar
Weingast, B.R.Marshall, W.J. (1988), ‘The industrial organization of congress; or why legislatures, like firms, are not organized as markets’, Journal of Political Economy 96(1): 132163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar